<<

The Role of Emission Allowance Allocation in ’s Cap and Trade Carbon Market: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Hancheng Daia, Yana Jinb, Xiaorui Liua a Peking University, , China; b College of William & Mary, USA

1 Background: China’s NDC and the new ETS

• China’s NDC reflects strong political will and rigorous enforcement

• By or before 2030, China will peak CO2 emissions, reduce CO2 per unit of gross domestic product (GDP) by 60%-65% from 2005 and increase the share of non-fossil fuels in primary energy consumption to 20%

• Although “intensity target”, this NDC implies substantial emission reduction efforts • by plausible projections with, .g., IAMs • Jiang 2018, Jiang et al 2019

• To achieve the NDC • National Emission Trading System (ETS) is chosen as a key market based instrument

2 Seven Pilots: Carbon Market Starting Day

Bei Jing November, 2013 Tian December, 2013 Hu April, 2014 Shang Hai November, 2013 Chong Qing June, 2014

Guang Dong Zhen December, 2013 June, 2013

3 Carbon Trading Price

Average Carbon Price of 7 Pilot Market ( 2014.4 – 2018.8 )

Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec Jun Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec 80

70

60 GuangDong 50 BeiJing 40 30 20

10 HuBei

4 The 2017 new ETS: “concerned” features and possible future directions

• Covering only the power generation • Covering multiple sectors industry • Rate based, output-based allocation of emission allowances • Still output based • Based on “sectoral emission intensity allocation, but becomes benchmarks * output” and update “mass based” dynamically • ETS participants are incentivized to influence allocation • The OBA allowances across • Not clear, overall emission cap of the sectors are predetermined ETS by an emission cap implied • Goulder et al., 2018; Pizer et al., 2018 by the NDC

5 The 2017 new ETS: “concerned” features and possible future directions

• What difference will be if China’s ETS covers multiple sectors and uses mass-based OBA? • Carbon price formation • Trading behavior in carbon market • Macroeconomic impacts

6 Background: Producer’s incentives

base case Grandfathering

Output-Based Allocation

If s updates based on each year’s output: rate-based OBA. Producer have incentive to change output therefore s If a planner can make “perfect” projection for the future, set the s, and producer takes it as given: mass-based OBA 7 What if China’s ETS covers multiple sectors and use mass-based OBA?

• We set up such an ETS and to examine its impacts and underlying mechanisms • Multi-sectoral recursive dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model

8 IMED model Peking University

9 Multi-sectoral recursive dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model

10 Scenarios in this study

Total carbon Sectoral emission Carbon Scenario name mission allowance emission trading constraints allocation BaU No emission cap Not allowed None CAP SHR07 A fixed carbon Grandfathering emission cap Not allowed Output-Based CAP SHRbau implied by China’s Allocation ET SHR07 NDC of reducing Grandfathering 65% GDP-CO2 Cross-sectoral ET SHRbau intensity by 2030 emission trading Output-Based (similar to future ETS) compared to 2005 Allocation

Data includes the input–output table, energy balance tables, carbon emission factors of different fossil fuels, energy prices of coal, oil and gas for the year of 2007. 11 Initial allowance allocation and emissions in 2030

When changing from Grandfathering to OBA, carbon allowances would:

• Increase for power generation, aviation and non-ETS sectors, • Decrease for non-metal, chemicals and metal smelting sectors.

12 OBA vs Grandfathering

Grandfathering Output-Based Allocation

• All participating sectors make significant abatement effort • Carbon price is more converged

13 “Inside” factors: autonomous technology improvement

Grandfathering Output-Based Allocation more difficult to abate, their marginal abatement costs would be more sensitive to allocation changes

• Bubble size is the percentage of allowance allocation

more difficult for sectors which autonomously become less energy intensive to further reduce extra emissions

Capital substitution rate (CSR): the ratio of capital input over energy input

in the production function 14 Intuition: OBA is based on projections of future, therefore the sectoral impacts are “closer” to sectoral original development paths

• Sectoral specific impacts are associated with their autonomous emission intensity reduction and technology improvement potentials • Detailed discussions in the paper • Findings in line with theories

• After allowing emission permit trading • ETS trade volume smaller under OBA • equilibrium conditions under OBA is not significantly different from Grandfathering

15 Reduced total trade volume

Grandfathering Output-Based Allocation

• Relatively dirtier sectors are buyers of permits • ETS trade volume smaller under OBA

16 Which are net subsidized by ETS?

Grandfathering Output-Based Allocation

• The accumulated trading revenue and the accumulated variance of value added are smaller under OBA versus Grandfathering • Avoiding massive buying or selling emission permits in OBA in Grandfathering

Bubble size is the share of traded emission volume over the total sectoral emission.

17 Sectoral economic output changes in 2030

• Fewer losses in sectoral output under OBA • ETS reduces output loss • Under ETS, losses under OBA and Grandfathering are not significantly different

Grandfathering Output-Based Allocation

18 Macro-economic impacts

• Fewer losses in GDP under OBA • ETS reduces GDP loss • Under ETS, losses under OBA and Grandfathering are not significantly different.

Grandfathering Output-Based Allocation 19 Discussion

• The proposed ETS is not a silver bullet for NDC • non-ETS sectors also need a clear carbon emission constraint (we did) • Other practical concerns • Only a few years remain before 2030, not sure if it is feasible to quickly expand the sectoral coverage in the national ETS • Beyond ETS, there are many other “planning-based” policies

20 Conclusion: the main OBA ETS scenario

• In 2030, the equilibrium emission permit price 95 USD/ton • NDC is achieved with modest welfare losses • losses of GDP and consumption would be 2% and 4% respectively. • Multi-sectoral coverage is the key determinant for equilibrium conditions • In the long run, to make the carbon pricing policy work • sectoral coverage (either by ETS or combining carbon tax) + clear cap + mass based OBA

21 Case studies of IMED|CGE Model: Economic impacts of carbon cap

Related articles: [1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8]22/35 Case studies of IMED|CGE Model: Market based instruments for carbon reduction

Related articles: [9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15,16]S

23/35 Case studies of IMED|CGE Model: Economic impacts of carbon reduction on SDGs

Related articles: [22, 23, 24, 25,26] 24/35 Case studies ofIMED|HEL Model

Related articles: [32, 33, 34, 35, 36, 37, 38, 39,40, 41] 25/35 26/38 Subscribe to our public blog on Wechat Thank you for your attention! Questions? DAI Assistant Professor · Doctoral Supervisor Peking University · China [email protected] University Homepage / Researchgate / Google scholar

Electric vehicles’ health and climate benefits in China and India 27/38 Bibliography

28/35 Reference i

[1] Hancheng Dai, Xie, Haibin Zhang, Zhongjue Yu, and Wentao Wang. “Effects of the US withdrawal from Paris Agreement on the carbon emission space and cost of China and India”. In: Frontiers in Energy 12.3 (2018), pp. 362–375. url: https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2Fs11708- 018-0574-y.

[2] Haibin Zhang, Hancheng Dai, Huaxia , and Wentao Wang. “US withdrawal from the Paris Agreement: Reasons, impacts, and China’s response”. In: Advances in Climate Change Research 8.4 (2017), pp. 220–225. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1674927817301028.

[3] Hancheng Dai, Haibin Zhang, and Wentao Wang. “The impacts of U.S. withdrawal from the Paris Agreement on the carbon emission space and mitigation cost of China, EU, and Japan under the constraints of the global carbon emission space”. In: Advances in Climate Change Research 8.4 (2017), pp. 226–234. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1674927817301016.

[4] , Hancheng Dai*, Yong Geng, Yang Xie, and Tian. “Impacts of export restructuring on national economy and CO2 emissions: A general equilibrium analysis for China”. In: Applied Energy 248 (2019), pp. 64–78. url: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0306261919306567.

[5] Xu Tian, Hancheng Dai, and Yong Geng. “Effect of household consumption changes on regional low-carbon development: A case study of Shanghai”. In: China Population, Resources and Environment 26.5 (2016), pp.55–63.

[6] Beibei Cheng, Hancheng Dai, Peng Wang, Yang Xie, Li , Daiqing , and Toshihiko Masui. “Impacts of low-carbon power policy on carbon mitigation in Guangdong Province, China”. In: Energy Policy 88 (2016), pp. 515–527. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0301421515301841.

[7] Hancheng Dai, Peggy Mischke, Xuxuan Xie, Yang Xie, and Toshihiko Masui. “Closing the gap? Top-down versus bottom-up projections of China’s regional energy

use and CO2 emissions”. In: Applied Energy 162 (2016), pp. 1355–1373. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0306261915008272.

[8] Hancheng Dai, Xuxuan Xie, Yang Xie, Jian Liu, and Toshihiko Masui. “Green growth: The economic impacts of large-scale renewable energy development in China”. In: Applied Energy 162 (2016). ESI 1% Highly Cited Paper in 2018-19, pp. 435–449. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0306261915012763.

[9] Peng Wang, Hancheng Dai, Songyan Ren, Daiqing Zhao, and Toshihiko Masui. “Achieving Copenhagen target through carbon emission trading: Economic impacts assessment in Guangdong Province of China”. In: Energy 79 (2015). ESI 1% Highly Cited Paper in 2015-16, pp. 212–227. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0360544214012638.

[10] Beibei Cheng, Hancheng Dai, Peng Wang, Daiqing Zhao, and Toshihiko Masui. “Impacts of carbon trading scheme on air pollutant emissions in Guangdong Province of China”. In: Energy for Sustainable Development 27 (2015), pp. 174–185. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0973082615000563.

[11] Rui Wu, Hancheng Dai, Yong Geng, Yang Xie, Toshihiko Masui, and Xu Tian. “Achieving China’s INDC through carbon cap-and-trade: Insights from Shanghai”. In: Applied Energy 184 (2016), pp. 1114–1122. url: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0306261916307863.

[12] Hancheng Dai, Yang Xie, Jingyu Liu, and Toshihiko Masui. “Aligning renewable energy targets with carbon emissions trading to achieve China’s INDCs: A general equilibrium assessment”. In: Renewable & Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018), pp. 4121–4131. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S136403211731434X.

29/35 Reference ii

[13] Zhiqing Liu, Yong Geng, Hancheng Dai, Jeffrey Wilson, Yang Xie, Rui Wu, You, and Zhongjue Yu. “Regional impacts of launching national carbon emissions trading market: A case study of Shanghai”. In: Applied Energy 230 (2018), pp. 232–240. url: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S030626191831287X.

[14] Zhongjue Yu, Yong Geng, Hancheng Dai, Rui Wu, Zhiqing Liu, and Xu Tian. A general equilibrium analysis of the impacts of regional and sectoral emission quota allocation on carbon trading market. 2018. url: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0959652618313337.

[15] Huijuan Dong, Hancheng Dai, Tsuyoshi Fujita, Yong Geng, Yang Xie, Toshihiko Masui, and Zhe Liu. “Exploring impact of carbon tax on China’s industrial CO2 reductions and provincial disparities”. In: Renewable & Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017), pp. 596–603. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1364032117305488.

[16] Yang Xie, Hancheng Dai, and Huijuan Dong. “Impacts of SO2 taxations and renewable energy development on CO2 , NOx and SO2 emissions in Jing-Jin- region”. In: Journal of Cleaner Production 171 (2018), pp. 1386–1395. url:http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0959652617323508.

[17] Jiaoyan Xie, Hancheng Dai, Yang Xie, and Lixuan Hong. “Effect of carbon tax on the industrial competitiveness of Chongqing, China”. In: Energy for Sustainable Development 47 (2018), pp. 114–123. url: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0973082618304101.

[18] Xu Tian, Hancheng Dai, Yong Geng, Zhen , Toshihiko Masui, and Tsuyoshi Fujita. “The effects of carbon reduction on sectoral competitiveness in China: a case of Shanghai”. In: Applied Energy 197 (2017), pp. 270–278. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0306261917304221.

[19] Zhaoling Li, Hancheng Dai, Sun, Yang Xie, Zhu Liu, Peng Wang, and Helmut Yabar. “Exploring the impacts of regional unbalanced carbon tax on CO2 emissions and industrial competitiveness in Liaoning province of China”. In: Energy Policy 113 (2018). ESI 1% Highly Cited Paper in 2018-19, pp. 9–19. url: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0301421517307218.

[20] Zhixiong Weng, Hancheng Dai, Zhongyu Ma, Yang Xie, and Peng Wang. “A general equilibrium assessment of economic impacts of provincial unbalanced carbon intensity targets in China”. In: Resources, Conservation and Recycling 133 (2018), pp. 157–168. url: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0921344918300326.

[21] Yu , Hancheng Dai, Yong Geng, and Yang Xie. “Assessment of economic impacts of differentiated carbon reduction targets: a case study in Tianjin of China”. In: Journal of Cleaner Production 182 (2018), pp. 1048–1059. url:https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0959652618304025.

[22] Huijuan Dong, Hancheng Dai, Dong, Tsuyoshi Fujita, Yong Geng, Zbigniew Klimont, Tsuyoshi Inoue, Shintaro Bunya, Minoru Fujii, and Toshihiko Masui.

“Pursuing air pollutant co-benefits of CO2 mitigation in China: a provincial leveled analysis”. In: Applied Energy 144 (2015). ESI 1% Highly Cited Paper in 2015-16, pp. 165–174. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S030626191500197X.

[23] Mingquan Li, Hancheng Dai, Yang Xie, Ye Tao, Lars Bregnbaek, and Kaare Sandholt. “Water conservation from power generation in China: a provincial level scenario towards 2030”. In: Applied Energy 208 (2017), pp. 580–591. url: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0306261917313764.

[24] Qiong Su, Hancheng Dai*, Yun Lin, Yang Xie, Huan Chen, and R. Karthikeyan. “General equilibrium analysis of the cobenefits and trade-offs of carbon mitigation on local industrial water use and pollutants discharge in China”. In: Environmental Science & Technology 53 (3 2019), pp. 1715–1724. url: https://pubs.acs.org/doi/10.1021/acs.est.8b05763.

30/35 “Outside” factors affecting carbon price

△ = Output-Based Allocation - Grandfathering Relationships between carbon price change and:

allowance allocation technology improvement emission intensity capital substitution rate (CSR): the ratio of capital input over energy input in the production function 31 Fisher: OBA compared to grandfathering

Smaller output price increase and more output planners and participants are happy For the same emission target (cap) More emission intensity reduction Higher carbon permit price (higher MAC at equilibrium) Thus caveats of OBA: “efficiency loss”

32