<<

RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY : EVIDENCE FROM HOUSEHOLDS’ BALANCE SHEETS Christopher D. Carroll, Karen E. Dynan, and Spencer D. Krane*

Abstract—This paper examines precautionary behavior by relating job- to bear new strategies to address problems in each of these loss risk to household net worth. We use existing best practice and some new strategies to deal with some problematic issues inherent in this categories. literature regarding proxying uncertainty, instrumentation, and incorporat- ing theoretical restrictions. We do not find precautionary variation in the wealth holdings of households with low permanent , but do find B. Proxying Uncertainty precautionary effects for moderate and higher-income households. When the dependent variable is total net worth, these findings are robust to Precautionary wealth is defined as the difference between several alternative specifications. But we do not find precautionary re- sponses in subaggregates of wealth that exclude home equity. the wealth that consumers would hold in the absence of uncertainty and the amount they hold when uncertainty is I. Introduction present (Kimball, 1990). However, the most appropriate empirical measure of uncertainty is not obvious. Many A. Overview previous studies have proxied uncertainty with either the any studies have noted the potential economic impor- variability of a household’s income (Carroll, 1994; Carroll Mtance of precautionary . Caballero (1990) and and Samwick, 1997, 1998) or the variability of its expen- Normandin (1994) have pointed out that it may be able to ditures (Dynan, 1993; Kuehlwein, 1991). But, as Lusardi explain certain stylized facts about aggregate (1997, 1998) and Guiso, Jappelli, and Terlizzese (1992) such as excess sensitivity to movements in income. Carroll have pointed out, variability measures may be poor uncer- (1992) and Carroll and Dunn (1997) have argued that tainty proxies because they can contain large controllable precautionary saving is an important driving force for elements. For example, a tenured college professor who, by consumption-led cycles. And simulations in Hub- choice, teaches or consults every other summer may have bard, Skinner, and Zeldes (1994) suggest that it could more variable annual income than a factory worker, but account for almost half of the aggregate . Yet does not face the uncertainty of being laid off during a the empirical evidence regarding precautionary saving is . Similarly, differences in the variability of quar- mixed: Kuehlwein (1991), Dynan (1993), Guiso, Jappelli, terly expenditures between households may simply reflect and Terlizzese (1992), and Starr-McCluer (1996) find little differences in preferences towards regular seasonal outlays or no precautionary saving, whereas Carroll (1994), Carroll such as vacations or school tuition. and Samwick (1997, 1998), Engen and Gruber (2001), and Our measure of uncertainty is the probability of job Lusardi (1997, 1998) find evidence of a statistically signif- loss—specifically, the estimated probability that a consumer icant and economically important precautionary motive. who currently is employed will be unemployed one year The coefficient of relative risk aversion estimated by hence.1 This represents a potential major interruption to Gourinchas and Parker (2002) also implies substantial pre- income over which households generally have little influ- cautionary wealth. ence, and thus should provide a much cleaner signal of the The mixed findings may reflect a number of inherent uncertainty faced by a household than variability of income difficulties in testing for precautionary saving. The prob- or expenditures. lems fall into three general categories: the method of proxy- Because no single source contains high-quality informa- ing uncertainty, the instrumental variables strategy, and the tion on household-level income, wealth, and job loss, we incorporation of restrictions and insights from theoretical models. This paper adds to the work on precautionary use a source of data on and unemploy- saving by building on best-practice techniques and bringing ment, the Current Population Survey (CPS), to estimate unemployment risk based on observable household charac- Received for publication September 11, 2001. Revision accepted for teristics. We use these results to predict job-loss risk for publication May 20, 2002. households in a data set with good information on income * The Johns Hopkins University and NBER; Federal Reserve Board; and and wealth, the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF). We Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, respectively. We are grateful to Dan Bergstresser, Peter Brady, Martin Browning, Eric then relate this predicted job-loss risk to household net Engen, Arthur Kennickell, Steve Lumpkin, Annamaria Lusardi, Martha worth in the SCF. Starr-McCluer, Valerie Ramey, and seminar participants at the American Economic Association Annual Meetings, the Johns Hopkins University, the NBER Summer Institute, Georgetown University, MIT, and the Fed- eral Reserve Bank of Chicago for helpful discussions. We also thank Dan 1 Lusardi (1998) and Engen and Gruber (2001) also consider measures Bergstresser, David Brown, and Byron Lutz for excellent research assis- of job loss: Lusardi finds significant precautionary wealth accumulation tance and Arthur Kennickell, Martha Starr-McCluer, and Gerhard Fries for using the household’s reported perception of job-loss risk; Engen and help with the SCF. The views expressed are those of the authors and not Gruber find that the effect of unemployment on precautionary necessarily those of the Federal Reserve System or its staff. wealth is significantly more pronounced at higher unemployment rates.

The Review of and Statistics, August 2003, 85(3): 586–604 © 2003 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology UNEMPLOYMENT RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY WEALTH 587

C. Instrumental Variables Strategy crease in unemployment risk, the precautionary balances of those who remain employed build up only gradually while Because uncertainty is measured with significant error, the wealth of households actually entering unemployment most studies instrument their uncertainty proxy using vari- falls sharply. This means that empirical tests may be af- ables such as occupation, , industry of employ- fected by recent job loss; even if all consumers had a ment, and demographic characteristics. Econometric identi- precautionary motive, a regression of wealth on job-loss risk fication requires that at least one instrument be related to the might find a negative coefficient if shocks that boost both dependent variable (wealth, in our case) solely through that actual unemployment and perceived risk occurred shortly instrument’s correlation with uncertainty; this instrument before the period of observation. The model also suggests a can then legitimately be excluded as an independent vari- simple sample restriction to avoid this problem, because it able in the second-stage regression of wealth on instru- unambiguously predicts a positive relationship between cur- mented uncertainty. rent unemployment risk and wealth among households that Finding an appropriate instrument to exclude is difficult. have not recently experienced a spell of unemployment. For example, suppose that more risk-averse consumers both In addition, the theoretical model provides guidance on hold more precautionary wealth and choose occupations 2 the functional form for our empirical specification. Many with lower job-loss risk. Then occupation may be a good past studies have dealt with the extreme skewness of the predictor of job-loss risk, but, if it is excluded from the wealth by using the logarithm rather than the second-stage regression, the coefficient estimate on the level of wealth as the dependent variable. This transforma- uncertainty proxy will be biased because of correlation tion requires dropping or making ad hoc adjustments to the between occupation-instrumented job-loss risk and the un- nonnegligible share of households with nonpositive wealth, measured risk aversion in the error term. Similar arguments and it imposes constant elasticities. However, our model can be made regarding excluding educational achievement shows that low or negative wealth may be consistent with or industry of work. And we find some empirical evidence 3 optimal behavior and that precautionary responses may vary that these concerns may be warranted. with wealth and income. As an alternative, we transform To avoid this identification problem, we include most wealth with the inverse hyperbolic sine function; this still variables that have in the past been used as excluded downweights large values, but can be applied to positive, instruments for uncertainty (for example, education, occu- zero, and negative numbers and does not impose constant pation, and industry) as independent controls in our econo- elasticities.5 metric model of precautionary wealth. This requires us to find some other instrument that is correlated with job-loss E. Results risk to exclude from the control variables. We use the region in which the household resides. The large variation in Our empirical results provide some support for the prop- regional economic conditions suggests that region will be osition that precautionary saving is important. We find that significantly correlated with job-loss risk. In addition, if we increases in unemployment risk do not cause households assume that, ex ante, most households do not choose where with low permanent income to boost their net worth signif- to live on the basis of regional differences in job-loss risk, icantly, but that a statistically significant and economically region should be uncorrelated with unobserved determi- sizable precautionary effect emerges for households at mod- nants of wealth.4 erate and higher levels of income. These results are robust to a number of changes in the specification, but not across subcomponents of wealth: We generally estimate a signifi- D. Insights from a Structural Model cant precautionary effect in broad measures of wealth, but not in narrower subaggregates that exclude home equity. We We first solve a theoretical model of precautionary sav- discuss a number of potential explanations for these find- ing. It shows that in the steady state, permanently high-risk ings, both within and outside of the context of precautionary households hold higher average precautionary wealth than saving. permanently low-risk households. But, following an in- II. A Model 2 In the 1989 Italian Survey of Household Income and Wealth, Lusardi (1997) finds that one-half of households mention job security as a reason In this section, we consider a stylized model of household for choosing their jobs. 3 A related problem occurs when proxying uncertainty with insurance behavior in order to provide a qualitative guide to the coverage: Risk-averse households may both save more and obtain more response of net worth to changes in employment risk and to insurance. Starr-McCluer addresses this problem by instrumenting health the dynamics of wealth for households that suffer spells of insurance coverage with the percentage of the local workforce employed by large firms. Engen and Gruber argue that because unemployment unemployment. To isolate precautionary responses, we con- insurance coverage is determined by state policy, it is probably largely sider a model in which there is no saving for retirement or exogenous to the individual household’s saving behavior. other nonprecautionary purposes. 4 Engen and Gruber provide a detailed discussion of issues concerning instrument validity. They also argue that regional variables likely satisfy exogeneity requirements. 5 We thank Martin Browning for suggesting this transformation. 588 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

A. The Household’s Problem Wt ϵ Xt Ϫ Ct. (6) We assume that the household’s problem at time t is to In the real world, many households’ net worth essentially is zero, and many others hold negative levels of wealth (see ϱ section IIIB below). If V ϭ 0, no optimizing household max ͩu͑C ͒ ϩ ͸ ␤ jϪtE ͓u͑C ͔͒ͪ (1) min t t j would hold Wt Յ 0, because of the possibility that Ctϩ1 ϭ C jϭtϩ1 0 and UЈ(Ctϩ1) ϭϱ(see Zeldes, 1989). Thus, in our Ͼ subject to model, Vmin 0 is necessary to characterize the . To generate a clustering of net worth around zero, our consumers face different interest rates for lending and Xtϩ1 ϭ Rtϩ1͑Xt Ϫ Ct͒ ϩ Ytϩ1, (2) borrowing: Consumers ending period t with positive wealth lend where Ct represents consumption, Xt is the total earn a return that applies to lenders, R , whereas those available to the household at time t, and Yt is income (which who borrow (end the period with Wt Ͻ 0) pay a higher rate, is assumed to be received at the beginning of the period). Rborrow. The Euler equations Ϫ1 ␤ is 1 plus the rate of time preference, and Rtϩ1 is 1 plus lend uЈ͑C ͒ ϭ ␤R E ͓uЈ͑C ϩ ͔͒, (7) the rate of return, rtϩ1. t t t 1 The function is of the constant relative risk aver- Ј͑ ͒ ϭ ␤ borrow ͓ Ј͑ ͔͒ sion (CRRA) form, u Ct R Et u Ctϩ1 (8)

C1Ϫ␥ describe the behavior of lenders and borrowers, respec- ͑ ͒ ϭ t tively. Because Rborrow Ͼ Rlend, there is a gap between the u Ct Ϫ ␥ , (3) 1 right-hand sides of equations (7) and (8), so that there will be a range of X for which consumers choose C ϭ X and where ␥ is the coefficient of relative risk aversion. Since this t t t W ϭ 0. utility function has a positive third derivative, a mean- t preserving spread in consumption uncertainty raises ex- pected marginal utility, so an increase in risk will cause a B. Parameterization household to reallocate resources from consumption today ␴2 ϭ␴2 ϭ The time period is one year. We set n v 0.01 and to a precautionary reserve that partially insures consumption g ϭ 0.03, consistent with evidence from the Panel Study on tomorrow against potential negative draws of income (see Income Dynamics (Carroll, 1992). We set ␤ϭ0.03 and ␥ϭ Kimball, 1990). 0.2. The baseline probability of job loss, ␳, is 0.02.7 We set The process generating household income, Yt,is Vmin ϭ 0.2, so that the social safety net ensures resources equal to 20% of normal income. Finally, we assume Rborrow ϭ ϭ P Yt Yt Vt, (4) 0.15 and Rlend ϭ 0.03, close, respectively, to the interest rate P ϭ P on many credit cards and the after- rate of return on Ytϩ1 GYt Ntϩ1. (5) Treasury bills. These parameter values ensure that house- P holds will not desire to accumulate without bound Yt is a permanent component, which is independent of Vt,a 6 and that the model has a steady state. transitory shock to income. Ntϩ1 is a serially uncorrelated shock log-normally distributed with variance ␴2, so log YP n t C. The Consumption Function is a random walk with drift g ϭ log G. Our focus is on Vt, which captures both relatively small year-to-year fluctua- The model is solved using standard numerical dynamic tions in wages and occasional large drops corresponding to stochastic programming techniques. The ratio of resources periods of unemployment. Specifically, we assume that with ϭ P to permanent income, xt Xt/Yt , is a sufficient statistic for probability ␳ the household is unemployed and V ϭ V , ϭ P t min the ratio of consumption to permanent income, ct Ct/Yt where Vmin captures, in a simple way, the safety net pro- (see Carroll, 2001). The solid line in figure 1 depicts the vided by formal and informal insurance markets. With relationship between x and c under our baseline parame- Ϫ␳ t t probability 1 the household is employed, in which case ters. Consumers with very low levels of resources—those to ␴2 Vt is log-normally distributed with variance v and mean the left of the 45 degree line where c ϭ x —will consume Ϫ␳ Ϫ␳ ϭ t t (1 Vmin)/(1 ). (This ensures EtVtϩ1 1, so that more than their current resources. These consumers have ␳ changes in affect the variance but not the expected suffered negative income shocks and are borrowing to of income.) smooth consumption through the rough patch; their behav- End-of-period wealth is defined as the difference between ior satisfies equation (8). Those to the right of the 45 degree resources and consumption, 7 We chose a probability lower than the actual unemployment rate to 6 P Consistent with Friedman (1957), Yt is the path around which earnings offset the fact that we have normalized unemployment spells to last one exhibit transitory fluctuations, as opposed to the discounted value of future year, as compared with an actual average length of several months (see, P cash flows. Vt affects cash flow, but not Yt . for example, Clark and Summers, 1979). UNEMPLOYMENT RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY WEALTH 589

FIGURE 1.—CONSUMPTION FUNCTIONS FOR ␳ϭ0.02 AND ␳ϭ0.04 FIGURE 2.—STEADY-STATE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH- TO-PERMANENT-INCOME RATIO FOR ␳ϭ0.02 AND ␳ϭ0.04

The solid line is the consumption policy rule for the baseline model when the probability of job loss is 2% per year. The dashed line is the policy rule when the probability of job loss is increased to 4% per year. The solid line is the cumulative distribution function (CDF) for the ergodic distribution of the end-of-period wealth-to-permanent-income ratio for a population of consumers behaving according to the baseline model with a probability of job loss of 2% per year. The dashed line is the CDF for the ergodic distribution with a job loss probability of 4% per year. line satisfy equation (7) and spend less than their current TABLE 1.—STEADY-STATE DISTRIBUTION OF resources, leaving some wealth both to finance planned WEALTH-TO-PERMANENT-INCOME RATIOS future consumption and to buffer future shocks. There also V ϭ 0.20 V ϭ 0.40 is a range—the segment that coincides with the 45 degree min min Unemployment Unemployment line—in which no choice of ct satisfies either Euler equation Rate: Rate: because of the gap between Rlend and Rborrow. In this range, the borrowing rate is high enough to prevent the consumer 2% 4% 2% 4% P from going into debt, and the lending rate low enough that Mean Wt/Yt of: All households 0.115 0.237 0.081 0.108 it is not worthwhile for the household to save. Hence, P Wt/Yt percentile: consumption is equal to current resources. 20th to 30th 0.026 0.109 0.003 0.009 The dashed curve in figure 1 shows the consumption 40th to 50th 0.093 0.218 0.056 0.085 60th to 70th 0.160 0.318 0.120 0.165 function that would be optimal if the probability of job loss 80th to 90th 0.258 0.452 0.209 0.274 were 4% annually, rather than our baseline assumption of ϭ Fraction of households with: 2%. With the exception of a portion where ct xt in both P Ͻ Wt/Yt 0 0.116 0.103 0.162 0.167 P ϭ regimes, the new consumption function lies below the old Wt/Yt 0 0.068 0.024 0.097 0.069 P Ͼ one, indicating that at most levels of wealth a consumer Wt/Yt 0 0.817 0.874 0.741 0.764 facing a 4% unemployment risk would consume less than 8 Change in mean W /YP ϭ ϭ one facing a 2% risk. For households consuming less than t t Vmin 0.20 Vmin 0.40 with unemp. rise from their current resources, the precautionary response shows up 2% to 4%: Absolute Percent Absolute Percent as increased saving, whereas for households consuming All households 0.122 106 0.027 33 more than their current resources, the precautionary re- P Wt/Yt percentile: sponse shows up as a reduction in borrowing. 20th to 30th 0.082 311 0.007 256 40th to 50th 0.125 135 0.028 51 60th to 70th 0.158 99 0.045 37 D. The Distribution of Net Worth 80th to 90th 0.195 76 0.065 31 How do these precautionary responses affect the observ- able variable in our data, the cross-sectional distribution of net worth? With no income uncertainty, the gap between permanent income under ␳ϭ0.02.9 At the mean of the borrow lend P R and R would cause households to hold wealth of distribution, Wt/Yt is 0.115—the level of wealth is roughly 1 ϫ exactly zero. With income uncertainty, on average, house- 13 months’ (0.115 12) worth of permanent income. holds carry some precautionary assets. The solid line in Because wealth would be zero if income were certain, this figure 2 and the first column of the top panel of table 1 show can be interpreted as the average level of precautionary the steady-state distribution of the ratio of net worth to balances associated with the income uncertainty in our

8 The entire shift in the consumption function reflects precautionary 9 We simulate the model for a large number of households for 10 p behavior, because we adjust the mean of the Vt so that the change in ␳ does periods—sufficient time for the W/Y distribution to stabilize. We refer to not affect the expected level of income. this stable or ergodic distribution as the steady-state distribution. 590 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS baseline parameterization. Precautionary balances rise to TABLE 2.—WEALTH-TO-PERMANENT-INCOME RATIOS FOR HOUSEHOLDS WITH about 3 months’ worth of income for households in the 80th DIFFERENT EMPLOYMENT HISTORIES to 90th percentile of the wealth-to-income distribution. Still, Unemployed in P many households hold very little wealth: Wt/Yt is just Not Unemp. Year Year Year 1 in Last 3 Years t t Ϫ 1 t Ϫ 2 0.026, or about 12 weeks’ income, for households in the 20th to 30th percentile. Indeed, as shown in the middle panel of Fraction of Յ households with: table 1, a noticeable proportion of households hold Wt 0 P Ͻ Wt/Yt 0 .063 .995 .975 .810 P ϭ as a result of recent negative shocks to income: Given the Wt/Yt 0 .074 .000 .015 .055 P Ͼ support to consumption provided by social insurance, even Wt/Yt 0 .863 .005 .010 .135 P Ϫ Ϫ Ϫ with a 15% borrowing rate, optimal behavior implies that Mean Wt/Yt .136 .390 .210 .094 about 12% of households are in debt; and the difference All calculations assume an unemployment rate of 2%. between borrowing and lending rates is large enough that almost 7% of households have wealth of exactly zero. The dashed line in figure 2 and the second column of insurance tends to be available only once a household has table 1 show the steady-state distribution of wealth when the nearly exhausted its own resources. As a result, the marginal probability of job loss is 4%. Reflecting the precautionary utility of saving is quite small for very low-income house- response, this distribution lies to the right of the base-case holds, so they do not raise saving much in response to an distribution. As shown in the first column in the bottom increase in uncertainty. panel, the increase in the average wealth ratio is 0.122— Finally, our model implies that shocks to income have 1 persistent effects on household balance sheets that could about 12 months’ worth of permanent income; this addi- tional precautionary saving represents a 106% increase in distort comparisons of precautionary wealth holdings based on the current status of households’ unemployment risk. As the average ratio of net worth to permanent income (column indicated by the consumption functions in figure 1, at any 2). As can be seen reading down the bottom panel, the given level of cash on hand, an increase in unemployment absolute change in W /YP increases with the ratio of wealth t t risk will raise precautionary saving (with the exception of to income. But, because the bottom part of the distribution some households where c ϭ x ). This raises the aggregate is at such a low level of net worth, even a small absolute t t wealth of households whose members remain employed shift represents a much larger percentage increase in W /YP t t because, on average, their income does not fall. However, as at the lower percentiles than it does at higher levels of seen in table 2, virtually all households whose members are wealth. unemployed in the year of observation (column 2) have Our specification of Vmin is an extremely simple form of negative net worth—not only have they spent their precau- social insurance that lacks real-world features such as tionary reserves, they have borrowed an amount that aver- means testing or other forms of progressivity. Such factors ages 39% of their permanent income. Furthermore, job loss might generate a systematic relationship between precau- leaves lasting scars: Two years after the fact, households tionary behavior, permanent income, and wealth that could that experienced a spell of unemployment (column 4) hold be important for empirical work. However, incorporating a substantially less wealth and are significantly more likely to more realistic specification that, for example, makes Vmin a have negative net worth than their counterparts who were decreasing function of wealth and income would greatly continuously employed over the past three years (column increase the computational complexity of the model. Still, 1)—even though both groups face the same current risk of we can provide some crude idea of the effects of such becoming unemployed. These results point out a complica- features by comparing the steady-state distributions of tion for empirical work: Outside the steady state, the effect wealth from simulations that use different values of Vmin.As of higher unemployment risk on aggregate wealth may be shown in the right-hand columns of table 1, raising Vmin to ambiguous because the balance between the decline in 40% (increasing the generosity of social insurance) lowers wealth for the unemployed and the rise in wealth for the P wealth holdings throughout the Wt/Yt distribution. Further- employed is unclear. more, as can be seen in the lower panel, the precautionary In sum, the model has several important implications for P response of Wt/Yt to an increase in unemployment risk is empirical work. A substantial fraction of optimizing house- substantially smaller (in both absolute and percentage holds may have low or negative net worth. For households terms) than under our base case Vmin. These results suggest with similar recent employment experience, those facing a p that making Vmin a decreasing function of Wt and Yt would greater probability of job loss should hold more wealth. tend to induce positive correlations between permanent However, a household may hold less net worth than a income and both the level of precautionary wealth and the household with the same or less unemployment risk if the precautionary response to a change in unemployment risk. first household has recently experienced a spell of unem- Indeed, such effects are generated by the more elaborate ployment. Finally, precautionary responses may vary with social insurance programs embedded in the model of Hub- wealth-to-permanent-income ratio and with household in- bard, Skinner, and Zeldes (1995). In this model, social come. Of course, the model is only meant to highlight UNEMPLOYMENT RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY WEALTH 591 certain considerations that are relevant for testing the rela- TABLE 3.—SCF SUMMARY STATISTICS tionship between wealth and unemployment risk. Other 1983 1989 1992 important empirical issues such as controlling for other Mean net worth $151,363 $143,393 $100,798 motives for saving and for differences in preferences are Median net worth $68,494 $67,545 $54,392 discussed in sections III and IV. Net worth, 95th percentile $590,320 $536,955 $360,119 Median ratio of net worth III. Data and Econometric Methodology to income 1.59 1.54 1.37 Percent with net worth of Our empirical goal is to estimate the relationship between less than 1 month’s p income 8.0% 10.1% 9.1% W/Y and unemployment risk, taking into account the sa- Percent with zero or lient features of the wealth distributions discussed in section negative net worth 3.7% 5.3% 5.8% II. We use a two-step procedure. The first step constructs Median net worth of zero- or negative-net- estimates of unemployment risk and permanent income for worth households Ϫ$1,338 Ϫ$1,450 Ϫ$2,475 each household. The second step estimates the relationship Number of households 1689 1025 1032 p between W/Y and unemployment risk, controlling for other Sample includes all households in the SCF area probability sample with heads between the ages of 20 and 65 who have been employed at the same job for at least three years. Sample excludes top and bottom factors that may influence wealth accumulation. 0.1 percentiles of wealth or income. All calculations were done on a weighted basis. Dollar amounts are expressed in 1992 dollars. A. Data Sources Like Starr-McCluer, Engen and Gruber, and Carroll and lation between wealth and the ex ante probability of unem- Samwick, we focus on the cross-sectional relationship be- ployment even in the presence of strong precautionary tween household wealth and uncertainty. We use wealth saving motives. Ideally, we would like to include explana- data from the Survey of Consumer Finances, which has the tory variables to control for earlier employment and income best available information on households’ balance sheets.10 disruptions. Unfortunately, the SCF does not record income However, the SCF has at most only about 4000 households or unemployment history or reasons why the respondent in each wave—too few to accurately estimate the probabil- may have switched jobs; the only question regarding em- ity of job loss for the regional breakdown that we use. ployment history simply asks “How many years have you Consequently, we estimate unemployment risk with data been employed at your current job?” Given the absence of from the much larger outgoing rotation groups of the Cur- direct controls, we implemented the simple indirect control rent Population Survey, using the quasi-panel structure to suggested by our model. That is, we excluded those who obtain records of individuals’ employment status taken one may have recently experienced unemployment from the year apart. Our analysis uses the 1983, 1989, and 1992 analysis by limiting our sample to households whose head waves of the SCF and corresponding CPS samples. We do had been working at the same job for at least three years. As not use data from more recent years because data before and we discussed earlier, our model unambiguously predicts a after the redesign of the CPS in 1994 are not completely positive relationship between current unemployment risk comparable. and wealth for such continuously employed households. The model in section II was limited to one type of Other more standard sample restrictions and other aspects financial and one type of unsecured liability. The real of the data are discussed in the appendix. Altogether, the world offers a large range of assets and liabilities. While SCF sample contains 1,689 households from the 1983 wave, some assets clearly are more costly than others to use as 1,025 households from the 1989 wave, and 1,032 house- buffers against adverse shocks to income, home equity lines holds from 1992 wave. The CPS samples corresponding to of credit and the ability to borrow against defined contribu- the three SCF waves contain 59,252 households, 60,026 tion plans allow even relatively illiquid assets to households, and 63,351 households, respectively. provide cash within a matter of weeks. Accordingly, our baseline empirical model focuses on households’ total net B. Wealth Transformation worth. Table 3 shows summary statistics for net worth, assets, The simulations in section IID indicate that, on average, and liabilities. The distribution of wealth is highly skewed at households that have recently experienced a spell of unem- the top end, with the net worth of the median household ployment or other major earnings disruption will have lower only about half the size of the average in each year. At the net worth than other households. Thus, because bad draws bottom end of the distribution, between 4% and 6% of to income are more likely among consumers with high households have zero or negative net worth, and between current unemployment risk, we could see a negative corre- 8% and 10% have net worth less than one month’s income. Clearly, some transformation of wealth is necessary in 10 Curtin, Juster, and Morgan (1989) compare the SCF wealth data with order to avoid undue influence from the very small number those from the PSID and the SIPP and conclude that “the unique design characteristics of the SCF give it the highest overall potential for wealth of extremely wealthy households. The distribution is suffi- analysis of the three data sets examined” (p. 58). ciently skewed that the potential solution provided by the 592 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

FIGURE 3.—DISTRIBUTIONS OF RESIDUALS AND DATA TRANSFORMATIONS tion for those with W Յ 0.12 However, discarding such households would reduce the size of our samples consider- ably. It also would limit our ability to explore the potentially important differences in precautionary behavior that may exist across the wealth and income distributions. The esti- mation technique also would need to allow for truncation or alternative data transformations. Furthermore, the log trans- formation assumes a constant elasticity of W/Yp with re- spect to changes in explanatory variables. In contrast, our simulations imply that at the low end of the distribution, small increases in dollar terms in precautionary wealth can represent extremely large increases in percentage terms. This suggests that average precautionary effects estimated using logs could give undue weight to responses at the lower end of the wealth distribution. As an alternative, we transform net worth with the inverse hyperbolic sine function, suggested by Burbidge, Magee, and Robb (1988). The inverse hyperbolic sine of z is

ln ͓␪z ϩ ͑␪2z2 ϩ 1͒1/ 2͔ ͓ ␪͔ ϭ g z, ␪ , (9)

where ␪ is an estimated damping parameter. Like the loga- rithm, g[ z, ␪] downweights large values of z. However, g[ z, ␪] has several advantages over the use of logs: it admits zero and negative values of z, estimates the degree to which large values are downweighted, and does not impose constant elasticities. The effect of a change in any indepen- /z ץ)(x ץ/[g[ z, ␪ץ) x ϭ ץ/z ץ dent variable x on z is given by g[ z, ␪]), where the first factor on the right-hand sideץ equals the regression coefficient on x—call it ␤x—and the x)(x/z) ϭ ץ/z ץ) ,second equals (␪2z2 ϩ 1)1/2. Thus 2 2 1/2 ␤xx(␪ ϩ 1/z ) , so that elasticities are decreasing func- tions of z. The middle panel of figure 3 shows g[ z, ␪] with z equal to our W/YP proxy and ␪ϭ3.87 (the value we estimate for the 1983 total sample in table 6). The bottom panel shows the residuals from a regression of g[W/Yp, ␪] on the model in section II—using the ratio of net worth to some variables used in the linear regression cited above. This proxy for permanent income as the dependent variable— distribution is much closer to normal than that for the linear does not work. The top panel of figure 3 plots a histogram model, although the tails still contain a little more mass than of the residuals from a linear regression of a W/Yp proxy on a normal distribution with the same variance. the explanatory variables used in the model estimated in table 6 for 1983 (base sample) along with a normal density C. The Likelihood Function with the same mean and variance as the residuals. The substantial mass in the tails and the skewness of the distri- According to our theoretical model, a household’s wealth bution indicates that the residuals are very far from nor- holdings are a function of its job-loss risk, its permanent mal.11 income (through the interaction with Vmin), the income- Most previous studies have transformed wealth by taking generating process, and factors determining rates of time logarithms. They also discard households with wealth below preference and risk aversion. A more complete model would some threshold (at least zero) or use a different transforma- 12 Some examples of transformations and restrictions found in the literature are Diamond and Hausman (1984): ln W using only W Ͼ 11 For exposition, we eliminated the eight largest positive residuals $4000; King and Dicks-Mireaux (1982): ln(W/Yp) using only W Ͼ before plotting this histogram, so the actual distribution is even more $2500; Starr-McCluer (1996): ln W if W Ͼ 0and0ifW Յ 0; Carroll skewed than the one presented in figure 3. and Samwick (1997, 1998): ln[W Ϫ min(W,0)ϩ 1]. UNEMPLOYMENT RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY WEALTH 593 also include life cycle factors. In terms of observable prox- the same population (see Angrist and Krueger, 1992). Be- ies, the simplest empirical model that we will estimate is cause both the CPS and the SCF area-probability samples are random draws from the noninstitutional U.S. population, ͓ p ␪͔ ϭ ␤ ϩ ␤ ͑ ͒ g Wj/Y j , 0 u Pr uj this procedure produces consistent estimates of the proba- (10) bility that a household in the SCF area sample will become ϩ ␤ ln Y p ϩ C ␤ ϩ ⑀ , y j j c j unemployed.13 u where j indexes households, g[ ] is the inverse hyperbolic For Zj , we are restricted to variables that are common to p both the CPS and SCF. Our first-stage equation therefore sine function, Wj is net worth, Yj is permanent income, Pr(u ) is the probability of the household head becoming contains regressors for occupation, industry, region, educa- j tion, age, age squared, age interacted with occupation and unemployed, and Cj is a row vector of control variables described below that are meant to capture other determi- with education, marital status, race, gender, and dummies nants of wealth. for head of household and the head interacted with age and 2 with gender. Assuming ⑀j ϳ N(0, ␴ ), the log-likelihood function of W /Yp is Note that we are exploiting the quasi-panel structure of j j the CPS to estimate the conditional probability of being ns unemployed in the future rather than simply the uncondi- ns 1 L͓␤, ␪, ␴2͔ ϭ K Ϫ ln ␴2 Ϫ ͸ ⑀2 tional probability of currently being unemployed. Pr(u ) can 2 2␴2 j j jϭ1 be thought of as a rational expectation of the odds of a currently employed household being unemployed one year 1 ns W 2 (11) 2 j u Ϫ ͸ lnͫ1 ϩ ␪ ͩ ͪ ͬ, from now conditional on Zj and is therefore an unbiased 2 Yp jϭ1 j estimate of this measure of unemployment risk. This risk is particularly relevant for the households in our SCF samples, where ns is the size of the SCF sample, K is the usual because they all are currently employed and have been so constant, and the last term derives from the Jacobian of for at least three years. Still, our proxy has clear shortcom- g[W/Yp, ␪]. Nonlinear maximization of equation (11) pro- ings. Importantly, because the CPS outgoing rotation groups duces estimates of the ␤’s, ␪, and ␴2. only provide snapshots of individuals at one-year intervals, we cannot observe spells of unemployment that are started D. First-Stage Regressions for Unemployment Risk and completed between interviews and we cannot calculate the length of an observed spell of unemployment. For currently employed individual j, we assume there ϭ u␣ ϩ␯ Ͼ exists a latent variable u*j Zj u j such that u*j 0if E. First-Stage Regressions for Permanent Income the person will be unemployed one year hence and u*j Յ 0 if the person will be employed. ␯j is a logistically distributed Because every household in the SCF reports income and u idiosyncratic shock that is uncorrelated with Zj , a row a wide range of other variables, our first-stage estimates for vector of observable characteristics for individual j at time permanent income can be done entirely within the SCFs. t. Thus, Pr(uj͉ej), the probability of a currently employed The log of permanent income is assumed to be a function of yS person becoming unemployed, is observable characteristics, Zj :

u p ϭ yS␣ exp͑Z ␣ ͒ ln Y j Z j y. (13) ͑ ͉ ͒ ϭ j u Pr uj ej Ϫ ͑ u␣ ͒ . (12) 1 exp Z j u We use the fitted value from an OLS regression of observed ln Y on ZyS as our estimate of the log of permanent income, We estimate this probability using data from the CPS. The j j ln Yˆ p. We include in ZyS all of the ZuS along with the number dependent variable is an indicator that takes on a value of 1 j j j of children in the household, the number of earners, the log if individual j is employed in month t (based on the first of of any retirement income, and dummies to indicate home the two readings from the outgoing rotation group of the , retirement status, whether the head or spouse CPS) and unemployed in month t ϩ 12 (based on the hasadefined benefit pension, and whether the household second CPS reading), and takes on a value of 0 if individual has ever been turned down for credit or has had problems j is employed in both periods. yS servicing loans. We designate the variables that are in Zj For notational convenience, let Pr(u ) equal Pr(u ͉e ). To ៮ j j j but not in ZuS as ZuS. proxy for the probability of an employed SCF household j j Effectively, each household’s proxy for permanent in- head becoming unemployed, we calculate Pr(uˆ j) ϭ uS␣ Ϫ uS␣ ␣ come equals average income for all households with similar exp(Zj ˆ u)/[1 exp(Zj ˆ u)], where ˆ u is the CPS-based ␣ uS u characteristics. This approach has been widely used, begin- estimate of u and Zj are the values of Zj of the SCF household heads. This Pr(uˆ ) is then used in our SCF wealth j 13 We did not use data from the SCF’s nonrandom “list” samples; these regressions. Parameter consistency of such two-sample es- were designed to overrepresent wealthy households and thus cover a very timators requires that the samples be randomly drawn from different population than the area-probability samples. 594 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS ning with Friedman. Note, though, that such measures do TABLE 4.—FIRST-STAGE ESTIMATION FOR UNEMPLOYMENT RISK (CPS) AND not capture any unobservable individual-specific compo- GROUP INCOME (SCF) nents of permanent income. CPS Pr(uˆ ) SCFa ln Yˆ P 1983 1989 1992 1983 1989 1992 F. Control Variables F-tests (p-values): Occupation 0.007 0.134 0.008 0.684 0.361 0.847 The control variables Cj are meant to capture factors that Industry 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.009 0.111 0.084 may affect wealth through some channel other than changing Region 0.012 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.115 Education 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.417 0.742 0.016 unemployment risk or permanent income, such as life cycle White 0.003 0.001 0.007 0.667 0.061 0.463 considerations or rates of time preference and risk aversion. Female head 0.051 0.105 0.011 0.000 0.002 0.000 To identify the effect of uncertainty on wealth, some Age 0.168 0.798 0.980 0.000 0.000 0.016 Age ϫ occupation 0.011 0.107 0.097 0.008 0.059 0.759 instrument for the uncertainty proxy must be excluded from Age ϫ education 0.069 0.042 0.061 0.376 0.553 0.248 Cj. Many studies have excluded a variable such as occupa- Marital status 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.008 0.058 tion or industry in specifications similar to equation (10). Head 0.025 0.917 0.000 Head ϫ age 0.237 0.774 0.001 However, because such variables can be related to the Homeowner 0.000 0.000 0.000 expected life cycle profile of income or to discount rates or No. of children 0.055 0.593 0.788 risk aversion, they may be correlated with wealth through No. of earners 0.000 0.000 0.000 ˆ p Defined benefit coverage 0.000 0.000 0.009 some avenue other than their influence on Pr(uˆ j)orlnYj . Turned down for credit 0.331 0.076 0.897 Thus, we include them as control variables in equation (10). Problems servicing debt 0.113 0.920 0.033 Indeed, because we cannot rule out a priori that most Retired 0.161 0.274 0.001 yS log(retirement income) 0.000 0.129 0.071 variables in Zj might have some independent influence on wealth, we have included all but one of them in C . The Mean Pr(uˆ ) 0.027 0.019 0.022 j Std. dev. Pr(uˆ ) 0.021 0.015 0.017 exception is the Census subregion in which the household Adjusted R2 0.46 0.41 0.28 resides, which we believe is likely to be uncorrelated with No. of households 59,252 60,026 63,351 1688 1025 1032 income profiles or preference parameters related to saving. a Sample includes the self-employed. Furthermore, Blanchard and Katz’s (1992) finding of no per- manent differences in unemployment rates across regions sug- Instead of maximizing equation (11), we maximize the gests that most households do not choose ex ante to live in a constructed likelihood: particular region because of perceived permanent disparities in ns job-loss risk. Thus, regional variation in unemployment is ns 1 L͓␤, ␪, ␴2͔ ϭ K Ϫ ln ␴2 Ϫ ͸ e2 likely quite exogenous to an individual household and proba- 2 2␴2 j jϭ1 bly provides a cleaner signal of the effect of Pr(uj) on wealth u 14 ns 2 than a measure based solely on the other variables in Z j . 1 Wj Ϫ ͸ lnͫ1 ϩ ␪2ͩ ͪ ͬ, ˆ p 2 Y j (14) G. Other Estimation Issues jϭ1 u yS ϭ ͓ ˆ p ␪͔ Ϫ ␤ Ϫ ␤ ͑ ͒ As a result of the assumptions on Zj , Cj, and Zj , the ej g Wj/Yj , 0 u Pr uˆ j coefficient ␤ is identified from region, whereas ␤ is y u Ϫ ␤ ln Yˆ p Ϫ C ␤ . identified from both region and the nonlinear functional y j j c yS ϭ uS ഫ u៮ S form of equation (12). Because Zj Zj Zj ,a Clearly, using first-stage equations to estimate variables in sufficient condition for parameters consistency is for all of equation (14) introduces complications. A discussion of yS the variables in Zj to be uncorrelated with vj. This pre- parameter consistency and adjustments we make to sum- u៮ S sumes that the Zj have no predictive power for unemploy- mary statistics to (asymptotically) account for the first-stage uS ment risk independent of the Zj . If, in contrast, these estimation can be found in an earlier version of this paper.15 variables were correlated with Pr(uj), the estimate of ␤u still u៮ S would be consistent, because the Zj are included in Cj; the IV. Empirical Results ␤C for these variables, however, would be inconsistent, as p they would now capture both direct effects on Wj/Yj and the A. First-Stage Results effects of their predictive power for Pr(u ). j The first three columns of table 4 present results from the first-stage CPS logit equations for Pr(uˆ j). The p-values for 14 Relative regional unemployment risk does vary over time. In simple top-to-bottom orderings, the average change in the rankings of the nine Census subregions’ unemployment rates between adjacent survey years is 15 See Finance and Economics Discussion Series working paper 1999- about 13⁄4 positions. If regional effects were fixed, there would be no 15, available on the Federal Reserve Board’s Web site. The most important ¥ 2 ␴2 ϭ change; if positions were completely random, the average change in adjustments blow up the eˆ j /ns to consistent estimates of e plim 1 ¥ 2 ␴ rankings would be 4 ⁄2 positions. Thus, using three surveys covering 9 ej /ns. In the income-interaction model described below, this boosts e years should reduce the odds that we are just capturing regional fixed by about 25% in the 1983 and the pooled sample, and by between 50% effects on wealth. and 70% in the 1989 and 1992 runs. UNEMPLOYMENT RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY WEALTH 595

P P TABLE 5.—SCF SECOND-STAGE ESTIMATION RESULTS: g[W/Yˆ , ␪] ϭ␤0 ϩ␤u Pr(uˆ ) ϩ␤y ln Yˆ ϩ C␤c ϩ⑀ 1983 1989 1992 Including Excluding Including Excluding Including Excluding Self- Self- Self- Self- Self- Self- Employed Employed Employed Employed Employed Employed Pr(uˆ ) 0.52 0.23 Ϫ0.67 Ϫ1.03 0.03 Ϫ0.60 (0.50) (0.22) (Ϫ0.28) (Ϫ0.33) (0.01) (Ϫ0.23) ln Yˆ P 0.09 0.12 0.23 0.44 0.40 0.26 (1.24) (1.62) (1.89) (2.44) (1.55) (1.58) Number of earners Ϫ0.04 Ϫ0.05 Ϫ0.08 Ϫ0.11 Ϫ0.18 Ϫ0.11 (Ϫ2.24) (Ϫ2.58) (Ϫ2.05) (Ϫ1.94) (Ϫ2.19) (Ϫ1.99) Owns home 0.28 0.27 0.32 0.32 0.28 0.27 (9.00) (8.61) (5.80) (4.89) (3.46) (4.55) Defined benefit pension Ϫ0.06 Ϫ0.04 Ϫ0.10 Ϫ0.08 Ϫ0.08 Ϫ0.02 (Ϫ3.43) (Ϫ2.02) (Ϫ2.60) (Ϫ1.74) (Ϫ1.39) (Ϫ0.49) Turned down for credit Ϫ0.05 Ϫ0.07 Ϫ0.03 Ϫ0.10 Ϫ0.06 Ϫ0.07 (Ϫ2.78) (Ϫ3.15) (Ϫ0.74) (Ϫ2.14) (Ϫ1.18) (Ϫ1.72) ⌰ 4.56 4.56 3.86 3.30 3.31 3.26 Overidentify restr. p-value 0.38 0.57 0.32 0.54 0.83 0.44

W /Yˆ P 0.04 0.01 Ϫ0.05 Ϫ0.06 0.00 Ϫ0.02ץ j j ˆ P at median W/Y Ϫ Ϫ Ϫ ͒ ͑ ץ Pr uˆ j (0.50) (0.22) ( 0.28) ( 0.32) (0.01) ( 0.23) Number of households 1689 1441 1025 835 1032 880 Asymptotic t-statistics shown in parentheses.

F-tests of the joint significance of industry, region, educa- holds whose head is self-employed.16 We omit these house- tion, and race dummies (as groups) are all highly holds because their balance sheets can be heavily influenced statistically significant. The occupation dummies and female- by business holdings and because they may have different head variable provide power in estimating Pr(uˆ j) in 1983 attitudes toward risk. and 1992, but not in 1989. Finally, the age variable does not The results provide little evidence that households accu- explain Pr(uˆ j) in any year, but age interacted with occupa- mulate more wealth in response to an increased probability tion is highly significant in 1983 and marginally significant of becoming unemployed. In the total sample, the point in the other years, and age interacted with education is estimate of the coefficient on Pr(uˆ j) is positive in 1983, but significant at the 7% level or better in all three years. The it is close to zero in 1992 and is negative in 1989. In no year lower part of the table provides summary statistics for the is it statistically different from zero. To translate this result predicted probability of becoming unemployed. In order to into an economically and statistically meaningful estimate ␤ p obtain precise estimates of u, we need the variation in the of the effect of a change in Pr(uj)onWj/Yj , we must take Pr(uˆ j) to be large; fortunately, it is, with their standard account of the inverse hyperbolic sine transformation. From deviations running between 70% and 80% of the means. section IIIB, we have The second three columns of table 4 present results from p ␪ 2 1/ 2 ˆ ץ yS the first-stage income regressions. The Z explain close to Wj/Yj ˆWj j ϭ ͫͩ ͪ ϩ 1ͬ b , (15) p u ˆ ͒ ͑ ץ ,half of the variation in the log of reported income in 1983 Pr uˆ j Yj and between 30% and 40% in 1989 and 1992. Most of the explanatory variables are statistically significant. A notable where bu is the estimated coefficient on Pr(uˆ j). The table ץ p ץ exception is education in 1983 and 1989; but a simple presents (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) and asymptotic t-statistics that regression of income on education dummies alone produces correspond to a 1 percentage point increase in Pr(uˆ j) at the P significant coefficients, so that the insignificance in the median Wj/Yj . [Because Pr(uˆ j) averages between 2% and overall equation likely results from collinearity and not the 3 1 24% percent with a standard deviation of 12 to 2 percentage irrelevance of education to permanent income. points, a 1 percentage point increase in Pr(uˆ j) is a fairly large change in our metric of employment risk.] In the 1983 B. Second-Stage Results: The Basic Model sample including the self-employed, a 1 point increase in P 1 Pr(uj) increases Wj/Yj by 0.04, or about 2 month of income, The results for our second-stage equation are found in but with a t-statistic of 0.5, this effect is not statistically table 5; we show estimated coefficients and (asymptotic) significant. The effects for 1989 and 1992 also are small and t-statistics only for selected variables. The first column for each year presents results from the total area samples, and 16 The runs that exclude self-employed households also exclude them in the second shows estimates for samples that exclude house- the first-stage regressions. 596 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

P P P TABLE 6.—SCF SECOND-STAGE ESTIMATION RESULTS: g[W/Yˆ , ␪] ϭ␤0 ϩ␤u Pr(uˆ ) ϩ␤uy Pr(uˆ )lnYˆ ϩ␤y ln Yˆ ϩ C␤c ϩ⑀ 1983 1989 1992 Including Excluding Including Excluding Including Excluding Self- Self- Self- Self- Self- Self- Employed Employed Employed Employed Employed Employed Pr(uˆ ) Ϫ28.32 Ϫ26.75 Ϫ57.22 Ϫ66.09 Ϫ67.77 Ϫ50.46 (Ϫ2.53) (Ϫ2.24) (Ϫ1.99) (Ϫ1.92) (Ϫ1.99) (Ϫ1.69) Pr(uˆ )lnYˆ P 2.96 2.76 5.72 6.47 6.85 5.05 (2.58) (2.27) (1.98) (1.90) (1.99) (1.68) ln Yˆ P Ϫ0.03 0.01 0.09 0.25 0.17 0.11 (Ϫ0.37) (0.12) (0.62) (1.17) (0.66) (0.57)

W /Yˆ Pץ j j ϫ ˆ P :Y percentile ͒ ͑ ץ Pr uˆ j 10th 0.03 0.03 Ϫ0.01 Ϫ0.04 Ϫ0.01 Ϫ0.02 (0.95) (0.51) (Ϫ0.18) (Ϫ0.60) (Ϫ0.15) (Ϫ0.37) 30th 0.11 0.04 0.11 0.06 0.16 0.03 (1.84) (1.34) (0.74) (0.30) (0.75) (0.38) 50th 0.29 0.24 0.27 0.15 0.17 0.10 (2.14) (1.67) (1.18) (0.74) (1.17) (0.79) 70th 0.39 0.33 0.44 0.24 0.39 0.14 (2.34) (1.87) (1.40) (1.03) (1.46) (1.05) 90th 0.52 0.42 0.71 0.55 0.77 0.41 (2.47) (2.01) (1.61) (1.25) (1.67) (1.26) Overidentify restr. p-value 0.50 0.71 0.32 0.61 0.89 0.46 Asymptotic t-statistics shown in parentheses. not statistically different from zero. The samples excluding with overidentifying restrictions (OID) tests; the p-values the self-employed produce similar small and statistically shown in table 5 are not close to statistical significance, ץ p ץ insignificant estimates of bu and (Wj/Yj )/ Pr(uj). suggesting that region is a valid excluded instrument. Of The signs of the coefficients on the other independent course, this finding is subject to the usual caveat that these variables generally make sense and are reasonably stable tests may have low power. across SCF years and samples. With regard to those possibly p related to precautionary saving, we find Wj/Yj is decreasing C. Second-Stage Results: An Extended Model in the number of earners per household, consistent with the notion that two (or more) earners lower precautionary re- A possible explanation for the weak results in table 5 is serves because both earners are unlikely to become unem- that the empirical model is too stylized to fully characterize ployed at the same time.17 The coefficient on ln Yp is actual household behavior. As discussed earlier, means test- positive for all years and samples and is of at least marginal ing and progressivity in social insurance programs imply statistical significance in all but the 1983 sample including that, all else equal, higher-income households might exhibit the self-employed. These results are consistent with the a larger precautionary response to a change in unemploy- possibility that higher social insurance replacement rates ment risk. Furthermore, a forward-looking optimizing reduce precautionary wealth held by lower-income house- framework may not apply to all households. Instead, some holds. With regard to factors related to saving more gener- households may use a rule of thumb to determine consump- ally, homeowners have higher net worth than nonhomeown- tion (as in Campbell and Mankiw, 1989), simply setting ers relative to income, and having a defined benefit pension current consumption equal to some fraction of current plan has a negative effect on net worth, as predicted by a income and not reacting at all to changes in income risk. standard forward-looking model of consumer behavior. Such behavior could contribute to a positive relationship Identification of ␤y and, as a practical matter, of ␤u between permanent income and the observed precautionary requires that the error term be orthogonal to the excluded response of wealth to risk if high permanent income house- instruments, the regional dummies. In econometric terms, holds were less likely to be rule-of-thumb consumers. the key assumption is that, conditioned on the Cj, region is These considerations suggest that a second-stage equa- correlated with the dependent variable only via its correla- tion that allows the precautionary response to vary with ˆ P ϫ p tion with Pr(uˆ j) and ln Yj . We test this assumption formally permanent income—say by including a term Pr(uˆ j) ln Yˆ j as an independent variable—might give a more accurate ץ p ץ 17 Guiso and Jappelli (1994) found that households saved less if both representation of (Wj/Yj )/ Pr(uj). Table 6 presents this spouses worked. Summers and Carroll (1987) suggested that that the rise model. The estimates for the control variables in this in two-earner families may help to explain the secular decline in saving in the United States. See Browning and Lusardi (1996) for more discussion specification are not presented, as they are similar to those of this point. in table 5. UNEMPLOYMENT RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY WEALTH 597

Allowing for the interaction between unemployment risk D. Second-Stage Results: Pooled SCF Samples and income suggests a much different role of uncertainty: Our sample restrictions left us with between 1,025 and The estimated coefficients on Pr(uˆ j) are uniformly negative, P 1,689 households in the individual SCF samples. These and those on Pr(uˆ j)lnYˆ j uniformly positive, with both significantly different from zero at the 5% level for each samples may be too small to produce precise estimates. Yet wave’s full sample and statistically significant at the 10% the similarity across years in the sizes of the precautionary level or better in the samples excluding the self-employed. effects and the other coefficients suggests that we can gain p precision by pooling the data from the three different SCF Also, the coefficients and t-statistics on ln Yˆ j are much smaller than those in the base model. years in the second-stage wealth regressions. P Table 7 presents results based on the pooled data for the Letting buy be the estimated coefficient on Pr(uˆ j)lnYˆ j . Then in this extended model base model (left-hand columns) and the model with the P Pr(uˆ j)lnYˆ j term (right-hand columns). Although the coef- p ␪ˆ 2 1/ 2 ˆ ץ Wj/Yj Wj ficients on income, job-loss risk, and the C are fixed across ϭ ͫͩ ͪ ϩ 1ͬ ͑b ϩ b ln Yˆ p͒. (16) j p u uy j ˆ ͒ ͑ ץ Pr uˆ j Yj SCF years in the second-stage regression, we continue to estimate the first-stage regressions for Pr(uˆ ) and ln Yˆ P j j ץ p ˆ ץ The bottom portion of table 6 presents (Wj/Yj )/ Pr(uˆ j) and separately for each year to allow the relationships between (asymptotic) t-statistics corresponding to a 1 percentage these variables and household characteristics to vary with ˆ p point increase in Pr(uˆ j) for the percentile of Yj listed in the the different macroeconomic conditions that prevailed in 18 first column. For the three samples including the self- 1983, 1989, and 1992. We also add year dummies for 1989 ˆ p employed, at low levels of Yj we see only small and and 1992 to allow the average level of wealth to vary over statistically insignificant effects of unemployment risk on time with trend growth and other nation-wide factors. wealth. For example, in 1983, at the 10th income percentile, The model with no interaction between Pr(uˆ ) and Yˆ P a 1 percentage point increase in the probability of becoming j j now shows a small precautionary effect—for the sample unemployed is associated with a 0.03 increase in the ratio of that includes the self-employed, increasing job-loss risk by wealth to income, or slightly over a week’s worth of 1 percentage point raises the wealth-to-income ratio by 0.06 income, and has a t-statistic of less than 1. Thus, the results (0.7 months of income) at the median income. However, the are consistent with the hypothesis that low-income house- estimate is statistically significant at just the 20% level. In holds have little or no precautionary response. ˆ P However, the estimated precautionary responses become the model with the Pr(uˆ j)-Yj interaction, we still observe economically significant as Yˆ p rises. In the 1983 full sample, only small and statistically insignificant effects of job-loss j ˆ p at the median of the distribution a household responds to a risk on wealth at low levels of Yj , but find statistically and 1 percentage point increase in the probability of becoming economically significant influences at the 30th percentile of ˆ p 1 permanent income and higher. At the median income, a 1 unemployed by increasing Wj/Yj by 0.29, or about 32 months’ income. These effects are large enough to be percentage point increase in Pr(uˆ j) is associated with an economically important, but not so large as to be intuitively increase in precautionary balances of 0.17 times annual p income (2 months), and the t-statistic on this effect is over implausible. For the 50th percentile of Yˆ j and above, these -The estimated effects for the sample excluding the self .3 ץ p ץ 1983 estimates of (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) are statistically different ,employed are a bit smaller, but with the larger sample size ץ p ץ from zero at the 5% level. The (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) for the 1989 and 1992 SCFs are of very similar magnitude to those they still are highly statistically significant for the upper half in 1983, but are estimated much less precisely. In part, this of the income distribution.19 ץ p ˆ ץ might reflect the fact that the samples in those years are These estimates of (Wj/Yj )/ Pr(uˆ j) appear too large to about 40% smaller than the 1983 sample. Once again, none be caused solely by the loss of expected lifetime income of the OID tests reject the region exclusion restrictions. associated with an increase in job-loss risk, a factor that Ͼ ץ p ˆ ץ ץ p ץ The (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) estimates are somewhat smaller for would cause (Wj/Yj )/ Pr(uˆ j) 0 even in a certainty the samples that exclude self-employed households. This is equivalence world with no precautionary saving. The cer- consistent with the idea that self-employed households may tainty equivalence solution for consumption from the model be more vulnerable to income losses when business condi- in section II (with R ϭ␤)is tions go bad and the fact that they are less likely to be covered by unemployment insurance. The precautionary r r effects are somewhat less precisely estimated than in the C ϭ X ϩ Y . (17) t 1 ϩ r t r Ϫ g t total sample; again, this is in part a result of the smaller sample size. 19 Tests of the pooling restrictions are ambiguous. In ones ignoring the p fact that Pr(uj) and ln Yj are estimated, an F-test easily fails to reject that 18 Strictly speaking, we divided the data into 50 equal-size bins based on the ␤’s are constant across years while a likelihood ratio test (which ˆ p ˆ p ␴2 ␪ Yj and then calculated equation (16) using the median values of Yj and includes restrictions on e and ) easily rejects the pooling restrictions. ˆ p ˆ p Wj/Yj for the bin containing the listed Yj percentile. We did so to avoid However, both tests degenerate when adjusted for first-stage estimation; ␴2 undue influence from outlier values for Wj. this likely reflects approximation error in our estimates of e. 598 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE 7.—SCF SECOND-STAGE ESTIMATION RESULTS: 1983, 1989, 1992 POOLED DATA Model without Pr(uˆ ) ϫ ln Yˆ P Interaction Model with Pr(uˆ ) ϫ ln Yˆ P Interaction Including Self-Employed Excluding Self-Employed Including Self-Employed Excluding Self-Employed Pr(uˆ ) 0.95 0.74 Ϫ30.64 Ϫ27.15 (1.34) (1.00) (Ϫ3.34) (Ϫ2.80) Pr(uˆ ) ϫ ln Yˆ P 3.15 2.77 (3.45) (2.88) ln Yˆ P 0.07 0.13 0.00 0.05 (1.85) (2.83) (0.04) (1.02)

W /Yˆ Pץ j j ϫ ˆ P :Y percentile ͒ ͑ ץ Pr uˆ j 10th 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.00 (1.34) (1.00) (0.64) (0.26) 30th 0.03 0.02 0.06 0.05 (1.34) (1.00) (2.39) (1.76) 50th 0.06 0.04 0.17 0.12 (1.34) (1.00) (3.07) (2.40) 70th 0.08 0.05 0.30 0.21 (1.34) (1.00) (3.43) (2.75) 90th 0.09 0.07 0.43 0.36 (1.34) (1.00) (3.62) (2.93) Overidentify restr. p-value 0.31 0.59 0.34 0.57 Number of households 3746 3157 3746 3157 Asymptotic t-statistics shown in parentheses.

ϭ ϭ Ϫ ϭ 1 Let g 0.02, r 0.05 [r/(r g) 1.67], and suppose changes is associated with just a 12% to 3% increase in p there is a 1% increase in the odds of a severe episode (see Wj/Yˆ j . Carrington, 1993) in which the breadwinner loses their job for one-half year and then finds a new job that permanently E. Identification Using Region pays 10% less. From equation (17), in a certainty equiva- lence world, Ct would fall and Wt would rise by 0.01 ϫ We noted earlier that region may be a better instrument to (0.5 ϩ 0.1) ϫ 1.67 ϭ 0.01 of income, well below our exclude from Cj in order to identify uncertainty than vari- estimate of 0.17 at the median Yˆ j. In other words, the ables most other papers have used, such as occupation, increase in job-loss probability would have to be maintained education, or industry, which a priori are more likely to for 17 years for our estimates to be in line with this depend on unobserved taste parameters that are also corre- pessimistic scenario from a model without precautionary lated with saving. This section considers the sensitivity of saving. our results to this assumption. Alternative estimates of ץ p ץ Our findings appear to tell roughly the same story as (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) are shown in the top panel of table 8, Carroll and Samwick (1997) and Engen and Gruber (2001), based on modifications to the pooled SCF interaction model but probably indicate larger precautionary effects than in (for the sample including the self-employed). For reference, Lusardi (1997). Our median household increases wealth by we repeat the base model results in column 1. p 17% of Yˆ j in response to a 1 percentage point—or roughly 1 Alternative Excluded Instruments: Columns 2, 3, and 4 a 2 standard deviation—increase in Pr(uˆ j). Carroll and Samwick (1997) estimate a 4% increase in wealth (relative present results using occupation, education, or industry as to permanent income) in response to a 1 percentage point the excluded instrument.20 When excluding occupation or 21 ץ p ץ increase in the variance of transitory income; but given that education, (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) is reduced substantially. The they estimate this variance to be between 2% and 10%, they estimates when excluding industry are essentially the same are probably considering a smaller increase in uncertainty as in the base model, suggesting that the effect of job-loss than we are. Engen and Gruber estimate that a 10% increase in the income replaced by unemployment insurance—about 20 The variable in question is the only excluded instrument (we include 1 a standard deviation change in the UI replacement rate (see region in Cj). 2 21 Correlation between the excluded instrument and risk aversion prob- Gruber, 1997)—lowers the ratio of net financial assets to ably would bias down estimated precautionary effects (of course, the bias income by 16%. In contrast, using the Italian Survey of cannot be signed directly in a multivariate model). For example, suppose Household Income and Wealth, Lusardi finds that, roughly occupation is the excluded instrument and people with high risk aversion both choose an occupation with low unemployment risk and hold higher speaking, a 1 standard deviation increase in the variance of precautionary balances; this would make a negative contribution to the respondents’ subjective expectations of nominal income correlation between wealth and Pr(u). UNEMPLOYMENT RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY WEALTH 599

TABLE 8.—IDENTIFICATION ISSUES AND SENSITIVITY CHECKS Alternative Excluded Instruments No Excluded Base Model Occupation Education Industry Instrument

P ץ p ץ (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j)byYˆ percentile: 10th 0.01 Ϫ0.02 Ϫ0.03 0.01 Ϫ0.00 (0.64) (Ϫ1.34) (Ϫ2.69) (1.01) (Ϫ0.40) 30th 0.06 Ϫ0.00 Ϫ0.03 0.06 0.03 (2.39) (Ϫ0.11) (Ϫ1.02) (3.52) (1.01) 50th 0.17 0.03 Ϫ0.00 0.17 0.09 (3.07) (0.60) (Ϫ0.06) (4.38) (1.64) 70th 0.30 0.09 0.05 0.29 0.17 (3.43) (1.09) (0.59) (4.65) (2.05) 90th 0.43 0.15 0.13 0.41 0.26 (3.62) (1.45) (1.09) (4.66) (2.33) Overidentify restr. p-value 0.34 0.04 0.29 0.06 0.22 Exclusion p-value 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 n.a.

Reduced Alternative Pr(uˆ ) Instruments Including Unemployed Base Model for ln Yˆ P a1 a2 and Job Changers

P ץ p ץ (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j)byYˆ percentile: 10th 0.01 0.02 Ϫ0.01 Ϫ0.00 0.01 (0.64) (0.97) (Ϫ1.24) (Ϫ0.70) (1.52) 30th 0.06 0.09 Ϫ0.01 0.00 0.03 (2.39) (2.39) (Ϫ0.61) (0.04) (2.78) 50th 0.17 0.17 Ϫ0.00 0.01 0.11 (3.07) (2.86) (Ϫ0.05) (0.49) (3.19) 70th 0.30 0.30 0.02 0.02 0.14 (3.43) (3.05) (0.39) (0.79) (3.31) 90th 0.43 0.44 0.04 0.04 0.18 (3.62) (3.15) (0.72) (0.99) (3.33) Overidentify restr. p-value 0.34 0.14 0.15 0.11 0.01 Exclusion p-value 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Asymptotic t-statistics shown in parentheses. All estimates based on pooled 1983, 1989, and 1992 data. risk on wealth is the same whether that risk comes from Because we estimate the first-stage equations independently living in a region that is temporarily undergoing a recession for each SCF year, our instrument set in the pooled model yS or from working in an industry where job-loss risk is effectively is the Zj interacted with SCF year dummies. In currently high. If, ex ante, we believe that region is a contrast, the coefficients on the Cj are restricted to be the preferable instrument, this suggests that we may also want same across SCF years. Thus, we can test if the excluded to have more confidence in the findings of studies that use instruments should enter Cj without causing a singularity industry as an instrument to identify precautionary behavior. between Cj and the instrument set. The bottom row of the The OID tests reject the exclusion restrictions on occu- top panel of table 8 presents p-values for Lagrange multi- pation and industry at (close to) the 5% level, but do not plier tests of the exclusion of the appropriate instrument reject education. These rejections indicate that our specifi- from Cj. These are soundly rejected in all specifications, cation is not one where OID tests are powerless. Indeed, the including with our preferred regional exclusion. fact that region passes the test suggests that it is a valid The last column presents estimates of the pooled interac- instrument; and the rejection of industry indicates that tion model after adding region to the Cj. Here, abstracting despite similar point estimates, industry probably is a worse from functional form, all of the identification of the effect of instrument than region. Still, the failure to reject education, unemployment risk comes from the changes across years in p ץ which a priori seems likely to be endogenous with regard to regional job-loss risk variation. The estimates of (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ ) in this specification are smaller than those in baseץ unobserved traits determining saving, suggests that the OID 22 j tests may not have as much power as we might like. p our model. Nonetheless, by the 50th percentile of Yˆ j ,a1 percentage point increase in Pr(uˆ j) is still associated with a Including Region As a Control: If an excluded variable 0.09 increase in W /Yˆ p, with the effect statistically signifi- is really proxying for some nonprecautionary factors affect- j j cant at the 10% level. The effect rises in economic and ing wealth, then it should be included as a control variable. statistical importance at higher levels of permanent income. These results indicate that even if the fixed-region effects 22 Alternatively, the problem may be that education is highly collinear with the included control variables, as suggested by the first-stage regres- reflect nonprecautionary factors, significant precautionary ˆ P sions for ln Yj . motives exist, albeit somewhat weaker than those in the 600 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

Ϫ u Ϫ base model. However, given that Cj includes income, in- who were employed in month t 12 (using Zj from t dustry, occupation, education, demographics, and other fac- 12); an unconditional alternative (a2) can be formed based tors, we think it unlikely that region is picking up nonprec- on the period-t employment status of all individuals (using u a1 a2 autionary effects. Furthermore, because of the short time Zj from t). For the SCF regressions, Pr (uˆ j) and Pr (uˆ j) ␤a1 ␤a2 span of our data, persistence in regional business conditions are calculated using the first-stage coefficients, u and u . might mean that collinearity between fixed-region effects The third and fourth columns of the bottom panel of table a ץ p ץ p ˆ ץ and Pr(uˆ j) could be reducing the estimate of (Wj/Yj )/ 8 show the resulting (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr (uˆ j); these are minuscule ץ Pr(uˆ j). And to the extent that fixed-region effects are compared to those estimated using our preferred Pr(uˆ j) and ץ p ץ reducing (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) because they are correlated with are statistically insignificant. In retrospect, however, these risk, they should be added back to any calculation of results are not surprising; they probably reflect biases in a1 a2 precautionary behavior. Pr (uˆ j) and Pr (uˆ j) when applied to the SCF. All household heads in our SCF samples are currently employed and have F. Other Sensitivity Checks been so for at least three years. Such households likely are much less of an unemployment risk than the households ␤a1 ␤a2 The bottom panel of table 8 presents a number of other used to estimate u and u , because these latter groups sensitivity checks on our results. All estimates are based on include individuals who actually are experiencing unem- ϫ ˆ p the model including the Pr(uˆ j) ln Yj interaction, the ployment in period t. This lower risk is most likely recog- samples including the self-employed, and the data pooled nized by currently employed households, so that our SCF- across SCF years, and with region excluded from Cj. sample households will hold lower precautionary balances a1 than a household whose true unemployment risk is Pr (uˆ j) a2 Reduced Instrument Set: Potential omitted regressor or Pr (uˆ j). This would bias down the precautionary ef- biases might be affecting the extended model. In the model fects.23 u៮ S with no interaction, because all of the Zj [which are not used to estimate Pr(uˆ j)] are included in Cj, the consistency Including Unemployed Households and Those at Their u៮ S of bu is unaffected by the possibility that the Zj might help Current Jobs for Less than Three Years: The potential a1 a2 predict Pr(uj). But for this to be true for buy in the interac- biases in the estimates using Pr (uˆ j) and Pr (uˆ j) highlight tion model, we would need to add the hundreds of cross the importance of for the relationship between u៮ S yS products of the Zj and Zj to Cj. This clearly is impractical. employment status and unemployment risk. The theoretical u៮ S As a parsimonious check, we excluded the Zj from the model highlighted another issue related to employment ˆ p ϫ first-stage estimate of ln Yj : Because the resulting Pr(uˆ j) status—the importance of accounting for reductions in pre- ˆ p u៮ S ln Yj no longer includes any variation due to Zj , buy should cautionary balances that may have been caused by recent u៮ S be less influenced by the (potential) appearance of the Zj spells of unemployment. ⑀ u៮ S cross products in j. Furthermore, a number of the Zj , such We controlled for this influence in our empirical work by as the credit measures, are not usually used in permanent removing the currently unemployed and those who have income proxies; this exercise thus also tests the sensitivity may have recently been unemployed from our sample. To of our results against a more traditional set of instruments quantify the effect of this stratification, we reestimated the ˆ for ln Yj. As can be seen in the second column, moving to interaction pooled model augmenting the baseline sample this reduced instrument set has little qualitative effect on with households whose heads currently were unemployed ץ p ˆ ץ (Wj/Yj )/ Pr(uˆ j). This suggests that omitting the cross (152 observations) or had been employed at their current job u៮ S products of the Zj from Cj does not bias our results; we can ៮ for less than three years (1339 observations). Pr(uˆ j) for the uS uS a2 guess that leaving out cross products of the Zj and the Zj unemployed was estimated using Pr (uˆ j), and dummy vari- probably does not greatly influence the results, either. And ables were added to identify the new groups. All else equal, the results indicate that the inclusion of nonstandard instru- the unemployed and job-switchers hold 0.07 and 0.03 less ments in Zys likely does not greatly affect our analysis. p j Wj/Yˆ j , respectively, than other households, with the differ- ences statistically significant. As shown in the lower right- Alternative Measures of Unemployment Risk: Our mea- hand column, the augmented sample produces coefficients sure for Pr(u ͉e ), Pr(uˆ ), is calculated using the odds based ϫ P j j j on Pr(uˆ j) and Pr(uˆ j) ln Yˆ j that are about one-third the u on current information (the Zj for period t) that an individ- ual who is employed in period t will be unemployed in 23 a1 a2 Although Pr (uˆ j) and Pr (uˆ j) are fairly highly correlated with Pr(uˆ j), period t ϩ 12. This measure might be inappropriate if they contain important differences. Because Pr(uˆ j) is a consistent estimate ϩ households’actualexpectationswereformedinalessforward- of period-(t 1) Pr(uj) for people employed in period t, we can examine potential biases in the alternatives by running the regressions Pr(uˆ j) ϭ looking manner. The most obvious alternatives consider the a a ϩ b Pr (uˆ j) using only currently employed individuals and testing a ϭ odds that people with similar characteristics are currently 0 and b ϭ 1. For each alternative and year, we easily rejected the null hypotheses. And with only one exception, b was smaller than one unemployed: A conditional alternative (a1) can be con- a (averaging 0.82 for a1 and 0.29 for a2), and the mean of Pr(uˆ j) Ϫ Pr (uˆ j) structed by rerunning equation (12) with the dependent a was negative (averaging Ϫ0.005 for a1 and Ϫ0.45 for a2); thus, the Pr (uˆ j) variable marking the period-t employment status of people may overstate the level and variation in Pr(uj) for the currently employed. UNEMPLOYMENT RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY WEALTH 601

TABLE 9.—HOUSING WEALTH CONSIDERATIONS Alternative Wealth Measures That Exclude Housing Alternative Pr(uˆ ) Net Worth Excluding Excluding Net Financial Excluding House-Price Loan-Term Base Model Assets Residence Effects Effects Pr(uˆ ) Ϫ30.64 0.14 Ϫ9.23 Ϫ24.46 Ϫ22.49 (Ϫ3.34) (0.10) (Ϫ1.53) (Ϫ2.83) (Ϫ2.62) Pr(uˆ ) ϫ ln Yˆ P 3.15 Ϫ0.02 6.04 2.46 2.24 (3.45) (Ϫ0.15) (0.90) (2.87) (2.64) ln Yˆ P 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.03 (0.04) (1.65) (0.18) (0.56) (0.84)

ϫ ˆ P ͒ ͑ ץ P͒ ˆ ͑ץ Wj/Y j / Pr uˆ j Y percentile: 10th 0.01 Ϫ0.00 Ϫ0.01 Ϫ0.00 Ϫ0.01 (0.64) (Ϫ0.63) (Ϫ0.79) (Ϫ0.17) (Ϫ0.50) 30th 0.06 Ϫ0.00 Ϫ0.00 0.03 0.02 (2.39) (Ϫ0.68) (Ϫ0.00) (1.38) (0.91) 50th 0.17 Ϫ0.00 0.01 0.10 0.08 (3.07) (Ϫ0.64) (0.44) (2.03) (1.58) 70th 0.30 Ϫ0.00 0.03 0.20 0.16 (3.43) (Ϫ0.58) (0.72) (2.43) (2.02) 90th 0.43 Ϫ0.01 0.06 0.29 0.24 (3.62) (Ϫ0.51) (0.94) (2.66) (2.28) Overidentify restr. p-value 0.34 0.18 0.11 0.18 0.19 Exclusion p-value 0.01 0.06 0.21 0.00 0.00 Asymptotic t-statistics shown in parentheses. All estimates based on pooled 1983, 1989, and 1992 data.

ץ ץ p ץ size of those in our base case. (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) remains an Pr(uˆ j) are larger than in the NFA model, but still statisti- p 24 increasing function of Yˆ j , with effects similar to the baseline cally insignificant at all income levels. p results at low Yˆ j , but between one-half and one-third These results point to home equity as a driving force smaller at the 50th percentile of the income distribution and behind the relationship between total net worth and employ- higher. The t-statistics on all the precautionary measures are ment risk presented in table 7. Our theoretical model, and similar to those in our base case. Together, these results most other theoretical analyses, yield little guidance as to support the view that precautionary motives can be masked what may be causing this finding, because they focus on a to some degree by households that are more likely to have net-worth measure comprising only one type of liquid asset recently experienced bad draws in the income or employ- and one type of unsecured liability. Still, it seems counter- ment lottery. Furthermore, the OID test now rejects the intuitive that the precautionary response would be depen- region exclusion restriction. This suggests that some wealth- dent on one of the seemingly least liquid of all household related behavior of the households added to our sample may assets. be correlated with regional employment prospects; for ex- ample, in high-job-loss regions household heads may be Are the Results Spurious? Our results could be spuri- more likely to have recently switched jobs and to have ous—by chance, regions with high house prices may have drawn down precautionary reserves. had higher unemployment rates during the periods we examine, generating a positive correlation between Pr(uˆ j) G. Liquid Assets, Housing Wealth, and Precautionary and net-worth measures that include housing. Indeed, when Saving we reran the logistic regression (12) for Pr(uˆ j) replacing Engen and Gruber argue that households probably allo- regional dummies with the levels (Hr) and three-year cate precautionary balances to assets that can be liquidated growth rates (Gr) of regional median house prices (both in at little cost. The second column of table 9 shows results 1992 dollars), the levels entered with positive and statisti- when we define wealth as their liquid net financial assets cally significant coefficients for 1983 and 1992. Still, house (NFA) grouping of checking and accounts, certifi- prices are not the whole regional story: Likelihood ratio cates of deposit, , bonds, and mutual funds less tests soundly reject the restrictions on the regional effects unsecured liabilities. The results change markedly: The imposed by these regressions in 1989 and 1992. ץ p ץ (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) are now close to zero at all income levels and are no longer statistically significant. We also reesti- 24 Using different data and methods, Carroll and Samwick (1997) also mated the model using a wealth variable that just excludes found that the relationship between total net worth and uncertainty was stronger than the relationship between uncertainty and some subaggre- the equity in a households’ principal residence from our gates of the balance sheet—namely, very liquid assets and nonhousing, p ץ original measure of net worth (column 3). The (Wj/Yˆ j )/ nonbusiness wealth. 602 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

To quantify this potential effect, we attempted to strip the in response to a rise in unemployment risk. Either case influence of regional house price variation out of Pr(uˆ j)by would show up as a positive relationship between home replacing the coefficient on each regional dummy, ␤r, with equity and uncertainty. ␤r Ϫ␤HHr Ϫ␤GGr (␤H and ␤G are the logit coefficients H on Hr and Gr) and using the resulting adjusted Pr (uˆ j)in Potential Influences from the Credit Supply Side of Mort- our pooled model. The results, shown in the fourth column gage Markets. Supply-side considerations may also influ- of table 9, continue to indicate significant precautionary ence the link between housing wealth and unemployment behavior, although somewhat weaker than in the base risk. For example, lenders may require a lower loan-to- ץ p model. At the 30th percentile of the Yˆ j distribution, (Wj/ value ratio for homeowners facing high job-loss risk. Alter- ץ p Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) is about half the size of the base case, and its natively, higher-risk households might choose a lower loan- t-statistic drops to 1.4; the values for higher percentiles are to-value ratio because lenders might otherwise impose 35% to 40% smaller than in the base case, but continue to higher interest rates, stricter mortgage insurance require- be statistically significant. These results suggest that our ments, or higher origination charges. Either set of circum- findings may be inflated somewhat by spurious correlation stances would boost the housing wealth held by higher-risk between house prices and regional unemployment, but they households. Of course, if higher-risk households did not feel probably are not driven solely by such effects. a precautionary need to maintain higher total wealth, they could offset the extra home equity by adjusting some other Why Precautionary Wealth May Be Reflected in Housing: item on their balance sheet, such as credit card debt. Our There are a number of reasons why consumers may hold base-case estimates indicate that they do not do so; instead, precautionary wealth in housing even though it is illiquid. any loan-term effects from the supply side are at most only One example is Laibson’s (1997) model of consumers with partially offset, so that total net worth still rises with hyperbolic time discount factors; such individuals will want unemployment risk. That said, especially stringent require- to hold a buffer against income risk in the long run, but they ments on loan-to-value ratios could lead a higher-risk are so impatient that they must force themselves to save by household to hold more total wealth than would be pre- committing assets to instruments that are costly to liquidate. dicted by our simple theoretical model. In that case, the Or, as Carroll and Samwick (1998) argue, illiquid assets precautionary effects estimated in our base model would may not be undesirable buffers if a household’s chief con- reflect not only the conventional type of precautionary cern is a high cost but low probability event such as job loss. behavior, but also a separate supply-side channel through For such scenarios the transaction costs to tap an illiquid which unemployment risk affects net worth. asset are small in expected-value terms. The expected port- We attempted to purge the effect of loan terms to gauge folio costs associated with holding housing wealth as a how important these channels might be. We first gathered buffer against job loss also may not be large because state data on loan-to-value ratios and initial fees and charges laws generally permit a household to keep its primary levied by major mortgage lenders delineated by Census residence in the case of bankruptcy. subregion.25 We then removed these variables’ influence It may also simply be the case that housing wealth is from our unemployment risk measure by estimating the more liquid than commonly supposed. For example, home CPS logistic regression (12) using the lending terms instead LT equity lines of credit have made it quite easy for consumers of the regional dummies, creating an adjusted Pr (uj)by to tap their housing wealth at rates well below those on subtracting the lending-term effects from the regional credit cards. One problem with this explanation, however, is dummy coefficients in the original Pr(uj) regression, and LT that when we repeated the table 9 sensitivity checks for each rerunning the pooled model using Pr (uj) calculated in the SCF year separately (not shown), we found that housing SCF sample. As shown in the right-hand column of table 9, ץ p ץ wealth was a driving factor even in 1983, when home equity (Wj/Yˆ j )/ Pr(uˆ j) remains an increasing function of perma- lending was much less prevalent than today. nent income, with the estimates economically significant for There also are less direct routes for precautionary bal- higher portions of the income distribution. However, the ances to show up in housing wealth. Dunn (1998) shows effects are only about half as large as in our base case and that an increase in the probability of unemployment can only marginally statistically significant at the 50th percen- cause consumers to delay purchasing a new home. This may tile of Yˆ p. Note that the difference between these results and reflect precautionary motives that make them unwilling to those in the base case likely is an upper bound on a separate incur the nontrivial reduction in net worth associated with supply-side link between housing wealth and unemploy- paying mortgage points and commissions (see ment risk. This is because the loan-term-purging exercise Carroll and Dunn, 1997). If a large portion of these costs 25 were to be paid out of equity in an existing house, then Because we have credit variables in Cj and limit our sample to homeowners deferring purchases would be left with rela- household heads who have held the same job for the past three years, we probably have controlled for some of the important sources of individual- tively more housing equity than those who upgraded. Sim- specific heterogeneity in lending terms. The concern is whether our ilarly, a household may forgo taking out a home equity loan regional dummies are capturing region-specific supply-side lending factors. UNEMPLOYMENT RISK AND PRECAUTIONARY WEALTH 603 removes both the voluntary reallocation of wealth (includ- Burbidge, John B., Lonnie Magee, and A. Leslie Robb, “Alternative ing precautionary balances) toward housing and any addi- Transformations to Handle Extreme Values of the Dependent Variable,” Journal of the American Statistical Association 83 tional pure supply-side boost to net worth. Accordingly, the (March 1988), 123–127. purged results can serve as a lower bound on desired Caballero, Ricardo J., “Consumption Puzzles and Precautionary Saving,” precautionary behavior—which still is of economic and Journal of 25 (January 1990), 113–136. Campbell, John Y., and N. Gregory Mankiw, “Consumption, Income, and statistical significance for many households in the income Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence” (pp. distribution. 185–216), in Olivier Jean Blanchard and Stanley Fischer (Eds.), NBER Annual 1989 (Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 1989). V. Conclusion Carrington, William J., “Wage Losses for Displaced Workers: Is It Really the Firm that Matters?” Journal of Resources 28 (Summer This paper estimates the strength of the precautionary 1993), 435–462. saving motive by relating the uncertainty associated with Carroll, Christopher D., “The Buffer-Stock Theory of Saving: Some the risk of becoming unemployed to the cross-sectional Macroeconomic Evidence,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activ- ity 2 (1992), 61–156. distribution of household net worth. In doing so, we try to “How Does Future Income Affect Current Consumption?” Quar- use best-practice techniques in choosing our uncertainty terly Journal of Economics 109 (February 1994), 111–148. proxy, instrumental variables strategy, and an empirical “Buffer Stock Saving: Some Theory.” Department of Economics, Johns Hopkins University, manuscript (2001). specification that incorporates restrictions from a theoretical Carroll, Christopher D., and Wendy E. Dunn, “Unemployment Expecta- model. First, we consider the ex ante probability that a tions, Jumping (S, s) Triggers, and Household Balance Sheets,” in household head becomes unemployed, because it may be a Benjamin S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg (Eds.), NBER Macro- economics Annual 1997 (Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 1997). better measure of risk than the income or consumption Carroll, Christopher D., and Andrew Samwick, “The Nature of Precau- variation proxies used in many previous papers. Second, we tionary Wealth,” Journal of Monetary Economics 40 (September avoid relying on instruments that may be correlated with 1997), 41–71. “How Important is Precautionary Saving?” Review of Economics idiosyncratic tastes to identify variation in unemployment and Statistics 80 (August 1998), 410–419. risk by using a variable—the region in which a household Clark, Kim B., and Lawrence H. Summers, “Labor Market Dynamics and resides—that presumably is uncorrelated with unobserved Unemployment: A Reconsideration,” Brookings Papers on Eco- determinants of wealth. Finally, we use the inverse hyper- nomic Activity 1 (1979), 13–60. Curtin, Richard T., F. Thomas Juster, and James N. Morgan, “Survey bolic sine function to transform the wealth data, eliminating Estimates of Wealth: An Assessment of Quality,” in Robert E. the need to exclude households with nonpositive net worth Lipsey and Helen Stone Tice (Eds.), The Measurement of Saving, or to assume constant elasticities in the response of wealth Investment, and Wealth (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989). to driving variables. In turn, this likely aids us in distin- Diamond, P. A., and J. A. Hausman, “Individual Retirement and Savings guishing how precautionary behavior might vary with Behavior,” Journal of Public Economics 23 (1984), 81–114. household wealth and income. Dunn, Wendy E., “Unemployment Risk, Precautionary Saving and Dura- ble Purchase Decisions,” Federal Reserve Board Finance Our empirical results suggest that households in the and Economics Discussion Series working paper no. 1998-49 lowest permanent income groups do not engage in precau- (November 1998). tionary saving, but as income rises, precautionary behavior Dynan, Karen E., “How Prudent Are Consumers?” Journal of 101 (December 1993), 1104–1113. becomes significant in both economic and statistical terms. Engen, Eric M., and Jonathan Gruber, “Unemployment Insurance and Our findings hold for samples that include and that exclude Precautionary Saving,” Journal of Monetary Economics 47 (June the self-employed. However, the precautionary response 2001), 545–579. does not show up for subaggregates of the household Friedman, Milton, A Theory of the Consumption Function (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1957). balance sheet that exclude housing wealth. While there are Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier, and Jonathan A. Parker, “Consumption over a number of reasons for precautionary saving behavior to be the Life Cycle,” Econometrica 70 (January 2002), 47–91. reflected in housing wealth—either directly through the Gruber, Jonathan, “The Consumption Smoothing Benefits of Unemploy- ment Insurance,” American Economic Review 87 (March 1997), potential to tap housing equity when needed or indirectly 192–205. through the effect of delayed purchases of new homes—this Guiso, Luigi, and Tullio Jappelli, “Risk Sharing and Precautionary Sav- dependence deserves closer scrutiny, because housing is ing” (pp. 246–270), in Albert Ando, Luigi Guiso, and Ignazio Visco (Eds.), Saving and the Accumulation of Wealth (Cambridge, U.K.: generally considered one of the least liquid assets that a Cambridge University Press, 1994). family can hold. Guiso, Luigi, Tullio Jappelli, and Daniele Terlizzese, “Earnings Uncer- tainty and Precautionary Saving,” Journal of Monetary Economics 30 (November 1992), 307–337. REFERENCES Hubbard, R. Glenn, Jonathan Skinner, and Stephen P. Zeldes, “The Angrist, Joshua D., and Alan B. Krueger, “The Effect of Age at School Importance of Precautionary Motives in Explaining Individual and Entry on Educational Attainment: An Application of Instrumental Aggregate Saving,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Variables with Moments from Two Samples,” Journal of the Public Policy 40 (June 1994), 59–126. American Statistical Association 87 (June 1992), 328–336. “Precautionary Saving and Social Insurance,” Journal of Political Blanchard, Olivier, and Lawrence Katz, “Regional Evolutions,” Brookings Economy 103 (April 1995), 360–399. Papers on Economic Activity 1 (1992), 1–61. King, M. A., and L.-D. L. Dicks-Mireaux, “Asset Holdings and the Browning, Martin, and Annamaria Lusardi, “Household Saving: Micro Life-Cycle,” The Economic Journal 92 (June 1982), 247–267. Theories and Micro Facts,” Journal of Economic Literature 34 Kimball, Miles S., “Precautionary Saving in the Small and in the Large,” (December 1996), 1797–1855. Econometrica 58 (January 1990), 53–73. 604 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

Kuehlwein, Michael, “A Test for the Presence of Precautionary Saving,” 1.c Non-public-use data Economics Letters 37 (December 1991), 471–475. Laibson, David I., “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting,” Quarterly The 1989 public-use data set has limited information on region and Journal of Economics 112 (May 1997), 443–478. industry, and neither the 1989 nor the 1992 public-use data set has Lusardi, Annamaria, “Precautionary Saving and Subjective Earnings Vari- indicators for the area probability sample. The SCF staff helped us by ance,” Economic Letters 57 (December 1997), 319–326. running our regressions on their internal data sets, which have this detail. “On the Importance of Precautionary Saving,” American Eco- nomic Review 88 (May 1998), 448–453. 1.d Sample selection Normandin, Michel, “Precautionary Saving: An Explanation for the Ex- cess Sensitivity of Aggregate Consumption,” Journal of Business In addition to the restrictions discussed in the text, we exclude house- and Economics Statistics 12 (April 1994), 205–219. holds whose heads are younger than 20 or older than 65, since employ- Starr-McCluer, Martha, “Health Insurance and Precautionary Saving,” ment risk likely is irrelevant for them. To remove some obviously extreme American Economic Review 86 (March 1996), 285–295. outliers, we also dropped households in the lowest and highest 0.1 Summers, Lawrence H., and Christopher D. Carroll, “Why is U.S. Na- percentiles of wealth and income. tional Saving So Low?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2 (1987), 607–636. 2. Current Population Survey Welch, Finis R., “dm11: Matching the Current Population Survey,” Stata Technical Bulletin Reprints 2 (1993), 4–5. 2.a Linking CPS observations Zeldes, Stephen P., “Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: De- viations from Certainty Equivalence,” Quarterly Journal of Eco- The CPS interviews a household for four consecutive months, rotates it out nomics 104 (May 1989), 275–298. of the sample for eight months, and then rotates it back for four more months. We used the outgoing rotation groups (the fourth and eighth interviews) to create two readings on employment and demographics taken one year apart. APPENDIX To match records, we used programs provided by Welch (1993).

Data Sources and Methods 2.b Sample selection

1. Survey of Consumer Finances SCF interviewing took place over periods of 6 to 8 months. To avoid potential problems with seasonality in employment and unemployment, 1.a Definitions of selected variables our baseline Pr(uj)reflects information from households whose fourth interview fell sometime during the twelve months preceding the end of the Net worth: Sum of financial assets, real estate, noncorporate business SCF sampling periods. The backward-looking alternative Pr(uj) uses equity, and vehicles, less mortgage and consumer debt. Real estate, households whose eighth interview fell in that twelve-month period; the , vehicles, mutual funds, and equities are valued at respondents’ unconditional Pr(uj) uses households whose fourth or eighth interviews assessments of their market value; other assets are valued at face value. fell in the period. To avoid the considerable reduction in sample size Net worth includes the value of defined contribution pension plans, but associated with limiting the CPS sample to household heads, we included excludes the value of defined benefit pension plans and durable goods dummies in the CPS regressions for whether the record was for the head other than vehicles. of household (and interacted with age, race, and gender). Persons not in Net financial assets: The value of all checking accounts, savings the labor force at the time of the fourth or eighth interview were excluded accounts, certificates of deposit, stocks, bonds, and mutual funds minus from the sample, and we applied the same age restrictions as for the SCF. the value of all unsecured liabilities. 2.c Employment status Income: Total before-tax household income for the calendar year preceding the SCF interview. (The SCF does not record households’ tax Usual CPS definitions of employed, unemployed, and self-employed payments or liabilities.) were used. Self-employment: Dummy for whether respondent was self- employed, as opposed to being employee of a private business or gov- 2.d Demographic variables ernment (1983 wave) or working for someone else (1989, 1992 waves). These variables were defined to be consistent with those constructed Occupation: Dummies for (1) managerial and professional, (2) tech- for the SCF. In our base Pr(uj), they reflect the profile of an individual as nical, sales, and support, (3) services, (4) precision, craft, and repair, (5) of their fourth interview. The backward alternative also uses demographic operators and laborers, and (6) farming, forestry, and fisheries. information from the fourth interview, which occurred sometime preced- Industry: Dummies for (1) agricultural, (2) mining and construction, ing the SCF sampling window. The unconditional alternative uses data (3) manufacturing, (4) wholesale and retail trade, (5) FIRE and business from either the fourth or eighth interview during the 12 month window. services, (6) other private services, and (7) public administration. 3. Housing Data Region: Dummies for the nine Census subregions. 3.a House prices Education: Dummies for (1) no high school degree, (2) high school degree only, (3) some college, and (4) college degree. We calculated state-level median home prices in 1980 using the 1980 Census. We then created state-level time series by extrapolating the 1980 Defined benefit pension: Dummy for whether respondent or spouse is prices using state-level indices of the change in the price of existing homes enrolled in a plan with some form of defined benefit features. from Freddie Mac. Finally, we averaged the state series together, weight- ing by population, to obtain time series of home prices by region. Retirement status: Dummy for household head reported being partly or fully retired. 3.b Loan terms

1.b Deflation We used loan-to-price ratios and initial fees and charges collected by the Federal Housing Finance Board and covering conventional home Net worth and other nominal variables were divided by the deflator for mortgages issued by major mortgage lenders. The data are recorded at the personal consumption expenditures from the National Income and Product state level; we used state population as weights to aggregate them to the Accounts. nine Census subregions.