CROSSED WIRES: WHY MOST GENERATIONAL WEALTH TRANSFERS FAIL Better Communication Is the Key to Wealth Preservation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

CROSSED WIRES: WHY MOST GENERATIONAL WEALTH TRANSFERS FAIL Better Communication Is the Key to Wealth Preservation | FAMILY CROSSED WIRES: WHY MOST GENERATIONAL WEALTH TRANSFERS FAIL Better communication is the key to wealth preservation By G. Scott Clemons, CFA BBH Chief Investment Strategist 1 | Women & Wealth Magazine n his landmark treatise, An Inquiry into the Nature The Causes of Failed Wealth Transfer and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, the Scottish economist Adam Smith observed how difficult it was for families to transition wealth from one Igeneration to the next. He noted, “In commercial countries, therefore, riches, in spite of the most vio- 25% lent regulations of law to prevent their dissipation, very seldom remain long in the same family.” The year was 1776, and in an effort to maintain social order, the British monarchy preferred that wealth 60% remain concentrated in the hands of relatively few aristocratic families, and therefore promulgated a 12% legal structure to encourage that stability of wealth. 3% Today, of course, the “most violent regulations of law” are designed to achieve the opposite outcome – to ensure that wealth does not remain in the same hands, at least not for long. Unless detailed plan- Breakdown of family communication and trust ning takes place at every step, wealth is taxed upon Inadequately prepared heirs its creation, distribution and ultimate dispensation. Failure to establish family mission Poor legal/tax/investment advice It is easy to attribute the failure of wealth transfer Source: The Williams Group to today’s ever-changing legal landscape and the complexities that it poses to families with substan- Williams attributed only 3% of the failed wealth tial wealth, whether in the form of financial assets, transitions to poor technical advice. There are real estate or a family business. But things were plenty of moving parts in tax and estate law, and seemingly no easier 240 years ago. Then, just as ambiguities abound as to their interpretation now, very few families succeeded in transitioning and implementation. And so the legal, insurance, wealth beyond a generation or two. It appears that, accounting and investing professions spend a in addition to mastering the legal and financial great deal of time and money on accreditation complexities of wealth transfers, other elements and continuing education in order to keep up with are at play that influence whether or not a family those changes and stay current on best practices. can preserve its wealth across multiple generations. Although change is certain to remain a constant when it comes to the right trust structures and A Failure to Communicate transition plans, the “how” of wealth transfer is a In 2002, Roy Williams of The Williams Group pub- relatively settled science – and one that advisors lished the results of a 25-year survey of 3,250 rarely get wrong. instances of generational wealth transfer. He con- cluded that 70% of those transitions failed, where Ninety-seven percent of the failures were attrib- failure was defined as involuntary loss of control utable to the family itself: due to a lack of a family of the assets. That finding underscores and even mission (12%), the inadequate preparation of heirs quantifies the observation that Smith made cen- (25%) or a breakdown of family communication turies ago, but Williams took the analysis a step and trust (60%). The common thread in each of further and explored the reasons for those failures. these causes of failure is a lack of communication. Therefore, better communication is the common Quarter 1 2016 | 2 | FAMILY Conversations about mission are an oppor- “tunity to align values with cure. Families typically spend more time planning and dad (or grandma and granddad) take? How a vacation or researching the purchase of a new did they succeed along the way, and to what do wealth, and appliance than they do discussing the legacy they they attribute that success? What would they have wish to leave to future generations and how best done differently? more often than to realize those wishes. We all need to speak more about the “why” of wealth – not just the “how” of We had the privilege a few years ago of visiting a not take the transferring it to our children. new client of Brown Brothers Harriman who was on the verge of selling a company for several hundred simple form of Providing Roots and Wings to Future million dollars and worried that his family of young Generations adult children would be influenced adversely by the storytelling. Wealth is power, and like any power, is easily sudden arrival of such wealth. We spent a snowy ” abused when easily obtained. A firearm in the afternoon with the family members, saying very hands of someone who doesn’t know how to use little, but listening to their stories about working in it is a terribly dangerous thing, whereas training the family business when they were young, sweep- and respect mitigate that danger dramatically. Sim- ing factory floors on Saturday afternoons, scraping ilarly, an automobile also represents a great deal of together money to take an annual family vacation power, which, if taken lightly, can be life-threaten- in an old VW van, and sharing together in the prog- ing. That’s why we teach teenagers to drive defen- ress and occasional setbacks of the business. By sively and safely, why we require licensing and why the end of the afternoon, we were all exhausted we require relicensing from time to time. from laughing at stories, and my colleagues and I left feeling confident that the family’s second gen- Driving a portfolio is no different. Unless we teach eration was well protected against the negative our children why the wealth exists, how to respect implications of wealth. Their challenge will be to and use it wisely and act as good stewards, all the do the same for their own children one day. best estate planning advice in the world won’t be enough to escape the old adage that families go If that seems soft and subjective, it is – but that from shirtsleeves to shirtsleeves in three genera- doesn’t make it any less important. What about tions. The first generation strives to build wealth, the 25% of failures in Williams’ study that were due the second enjoys the fruits of that labor, and the to inadequately prepared heirs? We all want our third has to start all over again with nothing. children to be “good with money,” which requires a balanced approach to earning, saving, spending, Families who transfer wealth successfully from investing and giving money away, but how is this generation to generation understand the family best accomplished? Families with wealth should mission. That needn’t be a formal document, but ensure that the next generation has a working at very least should be an ongoing conversation knowledge of the fundamentals of investing – not about why the wealth exists beyond the family’s necessarily to turn the children into investment needs and comfort. This is not an attempt to dictate professionals, but to make them informed consum- to future family members how they should think ers of the guidance they will receive from advisors. about wealth, what careers they should pursue or what they can and can’t do with the money. Man- When it comes to educating heirs, all children are aging from beyond the grave leads to resentment home-schooled. The examples that mom and dad at best – and absolute dysfunction at worst. This is, set are the best lessons for the next generation, instead, an attempt to provide future generations but advisors are a valuable resource in this effort with both roots and wings. as well. Beyond having the technical knowledge of asset allocation, portfolio construction, invest- Conversations about mission are an opportunity ment selection, trust structures, tax planning and to align values with wealth, and more often than so forth, advisors have the vicarious experience of not take the simple form of storytelling. What is the working with multiple families and seeing firsthand genesis story of the wealth? What risks did mom how wealth transitions succeed or fail. 3 | Women & Wealth Magazine Philanthropy plays a powerful role in this exercise. Many families rely on a trusted advisor from time to Not only does it provide a tangible expression of a time to facilitate family interaction. That may be the family’s mission and values, it also offers an oppor- formal role of an attorney or wealth planner, but tunity for the next generation to learn the techni- also may be the informal engagement of a minister, cals of wealth management through interaction neighbor, teacher or more distant family member. with advisors and real-time scenarios. Children who A third party who cares deeply about the family engage in their family’s philanthropic efforts learn can often provide an independent perspective, about how portfolios work, what form returns can provoke conversations that the family should have take, how to acknowledge and manage for risk and and simply offer a caring insight into family dynam- how to ensure that philanthropies are good stew- ics. Reliance on such an individual is not a sign of ards of the funds with which they are entrusted. weakness – if anything, it’s a sign of strength and This benefit is obvious when philanthropy takes the a demonstration of the seriousness with which the form of a family foundation, but even the far sim- family approaches the importance of open, honest pler exercise of making donations from a donor-ad- communication. vised fund creates an occasion for families to have these sorts of conversations together. Many families are tempted to ignore these issues. And yet ignorance – at least in this case – is not The largest cause of failure in Williams’ study was bliss.The benefits associated with taking the time a breakdown of family communication and trust, to define your wealth can not be overstated.
Recommended publications
  • Demographics, Wealth, and Global Imbalances in the Twenty-First Century
    Demographics, Wealth, and Global Imbalances in the Twenty-First Century § Adrien Auclert∗ Hannes Malmbergy Frédéric Martenetz Matthew Rognlie August 2021 Abstract We use a sufficient statistic approach to quantify the general equilibrium effects of population aging on wealth accumulation, expected asset returns, and global im- balances. Combining population forecasts with household survey data from 25 coun- tries, we measure the compositional effect of aging: how a changing age distribution affects wealth-to-GDP, holding the age profiles of assets and labor income fixed. In a baseline overlapping generations model this statistic, in conjunction with cross- sectional information and two standard macro parameters, pins down general equi- librium outcomes. Since the compositional effect is positive, large, and heterogeneous across countries, our model predicts that population aging will increase wealth-to- GDP ratios, lower asset returns, and widen global imbalances through the twenty-first century. These conclusions extend to a richer model in which bequests, individual savings, and the tax-and-transfer system all respond to demographic change. ∗Stanford University, NBER and CEPR. Email: [email protected]. yUniversity of Minnesota. Email: [email protected]. zStanford University. Email: [email protected]. §Northwestern University and NBER. Email: [email protected]. For helpful comments, we thank Rishabh Aggarwal, Mark Aguiar, Anmol Bhandari, Olivier Blanchard, Maricristina De Nardi, Charles Goodhart, Nezih Guner, Fatih Guvenen, Daniel Harenberg, Martin Holm, Gregor Jarosch, Patrick Kehoe, Patrick Kiernan, Pete Klenow, Dirk Krueger, Kieran Larkin, Ellen McGrat- tan, Kurt Mitman, Ben Moll, Serdar Ozkan, Christina Patterson, Alessandra Peter, Jim Poterba, Jacob Rob- bins, Richard Rogerson, Ananth Seshadri, Isaac Sorkin, Kjetil Storesletten, Ludwig Straub, Amir Sufi, Chris Tonetti, David Weil, Arlene Wong, Owen Zidar and Nathan Zorzi.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Wealth Inequality
    EC11CH05_Zucman ARjats.cls August 7, 2019 12:27 Annual Review of Economics Global Wealth Inequality Gabriel Zucman1,2 1Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, California 94720, USA; email: [email protected] 2National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA Annu. Rev. Econ. 2019. 11:109–38 Keywords First published as a Review in Advance on inequality, wealth, tax havens May 13, 2019 The Annual Review of Economics is online at Abstract economics.annualreviews.org This article reviews the recent literature on the dynamics of global wealth https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics- Annu. Rev. Econ. 2019.11:109-138. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org inequality. I first reconcile available estimates of wealth inequality inthe 080218-025852 United States. Both surveys and tax data show that wealth inequality has in- Access provided by University of California - Berkeley on 08/26/19. For personal use only. Copyright © 2019 by Annual Reviews. creased dramatically since the 1980s, with a top 1% wealth share of approx- All rights reserved imately 40% in 2016 versus 25–30% in the 1980s. Second, I discuss the fast- JEL codes: D31, E21, H26 growing literature on wealth inequality across the world. Evidence points toward a rise in global wealth concentration: For China, Europe, and the United States combined, the top 1% wealth share has increased from 28% in 1980 to 33% today, while the bottom 75% share hovered around 10%. Recent studies, however, may underestimate the level and rise of inequal- ity, as financial globalization makes it increasingly hard to measure wealth at the top.
    [Show full text]
  • A WILPF Guide to Feminist Political Economy
    A WILPF GUIDE TO FEMINIST POLITICAL ECONOMY Brief for WILPF members Table of Contents Advancing WILPF’s approach to peace . 2 Political economy as a tool . 4 A feminist twist to understanding political economy . 4 Feminist political economy in the context of neoliberal policies . 5 Gendered economy of investments . 7 Feminist political economy analysis - How does WILPF do it? . 9 What questions do we need to ask? . 10 Case study . 12 © 2018 Women’s International League for Peace and Freedom August 2018 A User Guide to Feminist Political Economy 2nd Edition 13 pp. Authors: Nela Porobic Isakovic Editors: Nela Porobic Isakovic, Nina Maria Hansen, Cover photo Madeleine Rees, Gorana Mlinarevic Brick wall painting of faces by Design: Nadia Joubert Oliver Cole (@oliver_photographer) www.wilpf.org on Unsplash.com 1 Advancing WILPF’s approach to peace HOW CAN FEMINIST UNDERSTANDING OF POLITICAL ECONOMY IN CONFLICT OR POST-CONFLICT CONTEXT HELP ADVANCE WILPF’S APPROACH TO PEACE? Political economy makes explicit linkages between political, economic and social factors. It is concerned with how politics can influence the economy. It looks at the access to, and distribution of wealth and power in order to understand why, by whom, and for whom certain decisions are taken, and how they affect societies – politically, economically and socially. It combines different sets of academic disciplines, most notably political science, economy and sociology, but also law, history and other disciplines. By using feminist political economy, WILPF seeks to understand the broader context of war and post-conflict recovery, and to deconstruct seemingly fixed and unchangeable economic, social, and political parameters.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Integration and International Business Cycle Co-Movement: Wealth Effects Vs
    Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 89 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2011/0089.pdf Financial Integration and International Business Cycle Co-movement: Wealth Effects vs. Balance Sheet Effects* J. Scott Davis Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas September 2011 Revised: August 2012 Abstract Different types of international financial integration have different effects on cross-country business cycle co-movement. International business cycle transmission through financial integration occurs through the wealth and balance sheet effects. The balance sheet effect leads to business cycle convergence, but the wealth effect leads to divergence. Using a cross- sectional regression, this paper shows that cross-border credit market integration (debt) has a positive effect on co-movement, implying that the balance sheet effect is the main conduit for international transmission through credit markets. However, cross-border capital market integration (equity) has a negative effect, implying that the wealth effect is the main channel for international transmission through capital markets. By distinguishing between wealth and balance sheet effects, this paper resolves many discrepancies between some key empirical and theoretical findings in the open economy macro literature, between different studies in the theoretical literature, and between empirical studies that use a cross-sectional regression and those employing panel data. JEL codes: E30, E44, F40, G15 * Scott Davis, Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, 2200 N. Pearl Street, Dallas, TX 75201. 214-922-5124. [email protected]. This paper previously circulated under the title “Financial Integration and International Business Cycle Co-movement: The Role of Balance Sheets.” I would like to thank Jean Imbs and participants at the Banque de France, CEPR conference on “The Financial Crisis: Lessons for International Macroeconomics” for many helpful comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Income Inequality and the Business Cycle: a Threshold Cointegration Approach ♣
    INCOME INEQUALITY AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE: A THRESHOLD COINTEGRATION APPROACH ♣ Gary A. Hoover University of Alabama Daniel C. Giedeman Grand Valley State University Sel Dibooglu♦ University of Missouri St Louis March 2009 Abstract: This paper investigates the impact of various socio-economic variables on various cohorts of the income distribution. We use asymmetric cointegration tests to show that unemployment and immigration shocks have real impacts on income inequality. In addition, using threshold test results we are able to show that positive and negative shocks to the economy do not have symmetric effects nor do the impacts of these shocks impact income quintiles uniformly. Keywords: Income inequality, Granger Causality, Asymmetric Cointegration JEL: I32, I39 ♣ The authors wish to thank Junsoo Lee and an anonymous referee for helpful comments. The usual caveats regarding remaining errors apply. ♦ Corresponding author: University of Missouri St Louis, Department of Economics, One University Blvd., St Louis, MO 63121, Email: [email protected], Phone: 314 516 5530; Fax: 314 516 5352 1. INTRODUCTION Beginning with the seminal work of Kuznets (1955) many researchers have endeavored to investigate the nature of the relationship between economic growth and income inequality. The Kuznets hypothesis posited that the functional relationship between inequality and economic development had an inverted “U” shape. Kuznets speculated that inequality would initially be positively correlated with economic development but that the relationship between economic growth and inequality would become negative at higher levels of development. Results supporting this hypothesis typically come from the use of cross-sectional country-specific data. Some recent researchers dispute the Kuznets hypothesis such as Bruno et al.
    [Show full text]
  • THE NEOLIBERAL THEORY of SOCIETY Simon Clarke
    THE NEOLIBERAL THEORY OF SOCIETY Simon Clarke The ideological foundations of neo-liberalism Neoliberalism presents itself as a doctrine based on the inexorable truths of modern economics. However, despite its scientific trappings, modern economics is not a scientific discipline but the rigorous elaboration of a very specific social theory, which has become so deeply embedded in western thought as to have established itself as no more than common sense, despite the fact that its fundamental assumptions are patently absurd. The foundations of modern economics, and of the ideology of neoliberalism, go back to Adam Smith and his great work, The Wealth of Nations. Over the past two centuries Smith’s arguments have been formalised and developed with greater analytical rigour, but the fundamental assumptions underpinning neoliberalism remain those proposed by Adam Smith. Adam Smith wrote The Wealth of Nations as a critique of the corrupt and self-aggrandising mercantilist state, which drew its revenues from taxing trade and licensing monopolies, which it sought to protect by maintaining an expensive military apparatus and waging costly wars. The theories which supported the state conceived of exchange as a ‘zero-sum game’, in which one party’s gain was the other party’s loss, so the maximum benefit from exchange was to be extracted by force and fraud. The fundamental idea of Smith’s critique was that the ‘wealth of the nation’ derived not from the accumulation of wealth by the state, at the expense of its citizens and foreign powers, but from the development of the division of labour. The division of labour developed as a result of the initiative and enterprise of private individuals and would develop the more rapidly the more such individuals were free to apply their enterprise and initiative and to reap the corresponding rewards.
    [Show full text]
  • Feminist Economics and the New Development Paradigm
    B+1515 Feminist economics and the new development paradigm Women around the world work longer hours, participate less in labour markets than men, receive lower incomes and are more involved in unpaid work. Feminist economics demands a new development paradigm that is not based on +1515 economic growth and whose indicator is not the average GDP which conceals the half of the economy that is non- BB monetary. The classic model ignores essential activities that take place outside markets, such as maintaining a household, voluntary work, child rearing, caring for the elderly and a large part of food production and crop maintenance. The evolutive economist Hazel Henderson says quered. To cope with this new situation, society must Elsa Duhagon that human behaviour ranges from conflict and organise itself around a family model different from competition at one end of the scale to cooperation the traditional one of “man as provider” and “woman The economic and financial crisis has shown once and exchange at the other. She points out that only as housewife”. Today many families are headed by again that we need an economic analysis that takes market economics functions at the competition end women or by men and women where both have paid gender inequalities into account and that adjusts and that all the other social sciences are interested jobs. For this reason, Grynspan proposes programs some of the basic assumptions of classical econom- in cooperation and exchange, and consequently the of reconciliation between work and family in a way ics. To the current economic conception, growth theory of games is more and more the model to be that involves reconciling men and women, with this equals economic development and the Gross Do- applied.2 She adds, “In fact, new economics and even relation now being seen as one of co-responsibility in mestic Product (GDP) is the most used indicator to the mainstream of economic theory are beginning to the family and one that transcends the private sphere measure the “wealth” generated.
    [Show full text]
  • Lifecycle Patterns of Saving and Wealth Accumulation
    Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. Lifecycle Patterns of Saving and Wealth Accumulation Laura Feiveson and John Sabelhaus 2019-010 Please cite this paper as: Feiveson, Laura, and John Sabelhaus (2019). \Lifecycle Patterns of Saving and Wealth Accumulation," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2019-010. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2019.010r1. NOTE: Staff working papers in the Finance and Economics Discussion Series (FEDS) are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. The analysis and conclusions set forth are those of the authors and do not indicate concurrence by other members of the research staff or the Board of Governors. References in publications to the Finance and Economics Discussion Series (other than acknowledgement) should be cleared with the author(s) to protect the tentative character of these papers. Lifecycle Patterns of Saving and Wealth Accumulation Laura Feiveson John Sabelhaus July 2019 Abstract Empirical analysis of U.S. income, saving and wealth dynamics is constrained by a lack of high- quality and comprehensive household-level panel data. This paper uses a pseudo-panel approach, tracking types of agents by birth cohort and across time through a series of cross-section snapshots synthesized with macro aggregates. The key micro source data is the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF), which captures the top of the wealth distribution by sampling from administrative records. The SCF has the detailed balance sheet components, incomes, and interfamily transfers needed to use both sides of the intertemporal budget constraint and thus solve for saving and consumption.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization and Poverty: the Engine of Economic Growth and Development
    GLOBALIZATION AND POVERTY: THE ENGINE OF ECONOMIC GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT Doug Bandow, Ph.D. Today's world is a place of exploding opportunities. Technological change is transforming the world. Even in the midst of intermittent economic crisis, people in the West live better than at any point of human history. Yet tragedy abounds in this world of plenty. Hundreds of millions of people live in miserable poverty. Malnutrition and even starvation stalk many lands. The opportunities that people in the West take for granted are absent from much of the world. Jesus said that “The poor you will always have with you,” which means that the obligation to assist those in need is also constant.1 The obligation is not only to those among the community of faith. “Let us do good to all people,” the Apostle Paul wrote the Galatian church.2 Industrialized states have tried different strategies to spur economic growth around the world. Communism, socialism, and other state-led development systems have been a bust—disastrously so. Foreign aid has done more to retard than speed growth. Well-intentioned efforts like the Peace Corps have had little permanent or systematic effect. Without doubt, many such international efforts have been well-intentioned. However, good intentions are not enough. Suppose a brother or sister is in need, wrote James. “If one of you says to him, ‘Go, I wish you well; keep warm and well fed,’ but does nothing about his physical needs, what good is it?”3 Similarly, what good are government “aid” programs which do not in fact help? What is working, in contrast, is the process of globalization.
    [Show full text]
  • The Dynamics of Capital Accumulation in the Us: Simulations After Piketty
    THE DYNAMICS OF CAPITAL ACCUMULATION IN THE US: SIMULATIONS AFTER PIKETTY By Philippe De Donder and John E. Roemer April 2015 Revised June 2016 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1998R COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY Box 208281 New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8281 http://cowles.econ.yale.edu/ The Dynamics of Capital Accumulation in the US: Simulations after Piketty1 Philippe De Donder2 and John E. Roemer3 June 21, 2016 1We thank two anonymous referees, as well as participants to the 2016 “Dy- namics of Inequalities and their Perceptions”(DynIPer) Marseille conference, and especially Jess Benhabib, for their comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies. 2Corresponding author. Toulouse School of Economics (CNRS and IDEI). Ad- dress: 21 allee de Brienne, 31015 Toulouse Cedex 6, France. Phone: (+33) 5 61 18 86 30. Email: [email protected] 3Yale University. PO Box 208301, New Haven CT 06520, USA. Email: [email protected] Abstract We develop a dynamic model where a competitive firm produces a single good from labor and capital, with market clearing rates of return. Individuals are heterogeneous in skills, with an endowment in capital/wealth increasing in skill. Individuals aspire to a standard consumption level, with a constant marginal propensity to consume out of income above this level. We define a steady state of this model as an equilibrium where factor returns and wealth shares remain constant. We calibrate the model to the US economy and obtain that a steady state exists. We then study three variants of the model: one with a higher rate of return for large capitals than for smaller ones, one with social mobility, and one with a capital levy financing a lump sum transfer.
    [Show full text]
  • The Malaise of Globalization in East Asia: Income Inequality, Perceived State Capacity, and Anti-Establishment Attitudes
    The Malaise of Globalization in East Asia: Income Inequality, Perceived State Capacity, and Anti-Establishment Attitudes Mark Weatherall, Min-Hua Huang, and Taehee Whang This paper examines how inequality produced by globalization undermines the confidence of citizens that the government can resolve their problems, incubating growing anti-establishment sentiment. Applying the latest data from Asian Barom- eter Survey (ABS), the authors found that anti-establishment attitudes can be best explained by citizens’ perceptions of a lack of state capacity and the state’s per- sistently weak political performance. Analysis using multilevel modeling suggests that income inequality and weak economic growth further aggravate anti-estab- lishment tendencies. This phenomenon, however, is most apparent in the coun- tries of East Asia. Countries in Southeast Asia are generally less affected because they continue to enjoy rapid economic growth due to latecomer advantage in the global economy. Key Words: globalization, inequality, perceived state capacity, anti-establishment n his 2005 bestseller, The World Is Flat: A Brief History of the Twenty-First ICentury, New York Times columnist Thomas L. Friedman made a compelling case for globalization, arguing that the development of web technologies was creating a level playing field for commerce, enabling developing societies to effectively compete with established economies in the West for the first time. Since the 1990s, global inequality has indeed declined – a comprehensive study under the auspices of the World Bank estimated that the global Gini Index in *Mark Weatherall([email protected]) is a Postdoctoral Fellow of the Center for East Asia Democratic Studies at National Taiwan University, Taipei, Taiwan.
    [Show full text]
  • Wealth Inequality and the Price of Anarchy
    Wealth Inequality and the Price of Anarchy Kurtuluş Gemici Department of Sociology, National University of Singapore, Singapore [email protected] Elias Koutsoupias Department of Computer Science, University of Oxford, United Kingdom [email protected] Barnabé Monnot Engineering Systems & Design, Singapore University of Technology and Design, Singapore [email protected] Christos H. Papadimitriou Department of Computer Science, Columbia University, United States of America [email protected] Georgios Piliouras Engineering Systems & Design, Singapore University of Technology and Design, Singapore [email protected] Abstract The price of anarchy quantifies the degradation of social welfare in games due to the lack of a centralized authority that can enforce the optimal outcome. It is known that, in certain games, such effects can be ameliorated via tolls or taxes. This leads to a natural, but largely unexplored, question: what is the effect of such transfers on social inequality? We study this question in nonatomic congestion games, arguably one of the most thoroughly studied settings from the perspective of the price of anarchy. We introduce a new model that incorporates the income distribution of the population and captures the income elasticity of travel time (i.e., how does loss of time translate to lost income). This allows us to argue about the equality of wealth distribution both before and after employing a mechanism. We establish that, under reasonable assumptions, tolls always increase inequality in symmetric congestion games under any reasonable metric of inequality such as the Gini index. We introduce the inequity index, a novel measure for quantifying the magnitude of these forces towards a more unbalanced wealth distribution and show it has good normative properties (robustness to scaling of income, no-regret learning).
    [Show full text]