The East Asian Model of Economic Development and Developing Countries." Journal of Developing Societies 18.4 (2002): 330-53
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Chinese Privatization: Between Plan and Market
CHINESE PRIVATIZATION: BETWEEN PLAN AND MARKET LAN CAO* I INTRODUCTION Since 1978, when China adopted its open-door policy and allowed its economy to be exposed to the international market, it has adhered to what Deng Xiaoping called "socialism with Chinese characteristics."1 As a result, it has produced an economy with one of the most rapid growth rates in the world by steadfastly embarking on a developmental strategy of gradual, market-oriented measures while simultaneously remaining nominally socialistic. As I discuss in this article, this strategy of reformthe mere adoption of a market economy while retaining a socialist ownership baseshould similarly be characterized as "privatization with Chinese characteristics,"2 even though it departs markedly from the more orthodox strategy most commonly associated with the term "privatization," at least as that term has been conventionally understood in the context of emerging market or transitional economies. The Russian experience of privatization, for example, represents the more dominant and more favored approach to privatizationcertainly from the point of view of the West and its advisersand is characterized by immediate privatization of the state sector, including the swift and unequivocal transfer of assets from the publicly owned state enterprises to private hands. On the other hand, "privatization with Chinese characteristics" emphasizes not the immediate privatization of the state sector but rather the retention of the state sector with the Copyright © 2001 by Lan Cao This article is also available at http://www.law.duke.edu/journals/63LCPCao. * Professor of Law, College of William and Mary Marshall-Wythe School of Law. At the time the article was written, the author was Professor of Law at Brooklyn Law School. -
Demographics, Wealth, and Global Imbalances in the Twenty-First Century
Demographics, Wealth, and Global Imbalances in the Twenty-First Century § Adrien Auclert∗ Hannes Malmbergy Frédéric Martenetz Matthew Rognlie August 2021 Abstract We use a sufficient statistic approach to quantify the general equilibrium effects of population aging on wealth accumulation, expected asset returns, and global im- balances. Combining population forecasts with household survey data from 25 coun- tries, we measure the compositional effect of aging: how a changing age distribution affects wealth-to-GDP, holding the age profiles of assets and labor income fixed. In a baseline overlapping generations model this statistic, in conjunction with cross- sectional information and two standard macro parameters, pins down general equi- librium outcomes. Since the compositional effect is positive, large, and heterogeneous across countries, our model predicts that population aging will increase wealth-to- GDP ratios, lower asset returns, and widen global imbalances through the twenty-first century. These conclusions extend to a richer model in which bequests, individual savings, and the tax-and-transfer system all respond to demographic change. ∗Stanford University, NBER and CEPR. Email: [email protected]. yUniversity of Minnesota. Email: [email protected]. zStanford University. Email: [email protected]. §Northwestern University and NBER. Email: [email protected]. For helpful comments, we thank Rishabh Aggarwal, Mark Aguiar, Anmol Bhandari, Olivier Blanchard, Maricristina De Nardi, Charles Goodhart, Nezih Guner, Fatih Guvenen, Daniel Harenberg, Martin Holm, Gregor Jarosch, Patrick Kehoe, Patrick Kiernan, Pete Klenow, Dirk Krueger, Kieran Larkin, Ellen McGrat- tan, Kurt Mitman, Ben Moll, Serdar Ozkan, Christina Patterson, Alessandra Peter, Jim Poterba, Jacob Rob- bins, Richard Rogerson, Ananth Seshadri, Isaac Sorkin, Kjetil Storesletten, Ludwig Straub, Amir Sufi, Chris Tonetti, David Weil, Arlene Wong, Owen Zidar and Nathan Zorzi. -
Global Wealth Inequality
EC11CH05_Zucman ARjats.cls August 7, 2019 12:27 Annual Review of Economics Global Wealth Inequality Gabriel Zucman1,2 1Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, California 94720, USA; email: [email protected] 2National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA Annu. Rev. Econ. 2019. 11:109–38 Keywords First published as a Review in Advance on inequality, wealth, tax havens May 13, 2019 The Annual Review of Economics is online at Abstract economics.annualreviews.org This article reviews the recent literature on the dynamics of global wealth https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics- Annu. Rev. Econ. 2019.11:109-138. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org inequality. I first reconcile available estimates of wealth inequality inthe 080218-025852 United States. Both surveys and tax data show that wealth inequality has in- Access provided by University of California - Berkeley on 08/26/19. For personal use only. Copyright © 2019 by Annual Reviews. creased dramatically since the 1980s, with a top 1% wealth share of approx- All rights reserved imately 40% in 2016 versus 25–30% in the 1980s. Second, I discuss the fast- JEL codes: D31, E21, H26 growing literature on wealth inequality across the world. Evidence points toward a rise in global wealth concentration: For China, Europe, and the United States combined, the top 1% wealth share has increased from 28% in 1980 to 33% today, while the bottom 75% share hovered around 10%. Recent studies, however, may underestimate the level and rise of inequal- ity, as financial globalization makes it increasingly hard to measure wealth at the top. -
The Generalized Theory of Distortions and Welfare
LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/generalizedtheorOObhag 7 working paper department of economics THE GENERALIZED THEORY OF DISTORTIONS AND WELFARE Jagdish N. Bhagwatl Number 39 May 1969 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 THE GENERALIZED THEORY OF DISTORTIONS AND WELFARE by Jagdish N. Bhagwati Number 39 May 1969 The views expressed in this paper are the author's sole responsibility, and do not reflect those of the Department of Economics, nor of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. : The Generalized Theory of Distortions and Welfare The theory of trade and welfare has recently developed independently in seven areas which have apparently little analytical relationship among themselves (a) Sub-Optimality of Laissez-faire Under Market Imperfections : It has been shown that, when market imperfections exist, laissez-faire (other- wise described as "a policy of unified exchange rates" [5]) will not be the optimal policy. Among the market imperfections for which the sub-optimality of laissez-faire has been demonstrated are four key types: (i) factor mar- 2 ket imperfection: a wage differential between sectors; (ii) product mar- 3 ket imperfection: a production externality; (iii) consumption imperfection: This paper is the result of thinking and research over a period of many years, originating in my 1958 paper on immiserizing growth [1] and developing considerably since my joint paper with Ramaswami in 1963 [2] on domestic distortions. Since 1965, T. N. Srinivasan and I have col- laborated on research in related matters, pertaining to the theory of optimal policy intervention when non-economic objectives are present [7]: a sub- ject pioneered by Max Corden's brilliant work [12]. -
Public Choice: Substance Depends Upon Process
Rural Development, Privatization and Public Choice: Substance Depends upon Process James Hite’ Abstract Whether or not privatization facilitates rural development depends upon what rural development means. In practice, rural development often is the result of a struggle between rent defenders and rent seekers. A positivist concept of rural development is proposed, and the institutions of public choice are examined to determine how they might influence privatization decisions. The conclusion is that whether or not privatization improves efficiencyof adjustmentin rural economies depends upon the specifics of political deals required to achieve a particular act of privatization. Key words: privatization, rural development, public choice, rent-seeking Introduction development itself. In attempting to do so, privatization, which is a topic worthy of Privatization is a term applied to a political considerable discussion on its own, receives process whereby local and even state governments somewhat secondary treatment. across the United States spin off certain services to private sector operatives. This term is also applied Summarized briefly, the argument advanced to the process by which the Thatcher government in in this paper is as follows: rural development can the United Kingdom devolved to private investors be thought of positivistically, as well as certain industries previously nationalized by Labor normatively. Positivistically, rural development is an governments, and it is the popular term applied to observable, potentially predictable process of the process of transforming Russia and its former adjustment on the part of rural economies to satellite nations into market economies (Vickers and Schumpeterian change in a market system. It is in Yarrow 1988; 1991). Ostensibly this paper is about the material interest of society that this process of privatization and rural development. -
Politics and Markets in East Asia: Is the Developmental State Compatible with Globalisation?
Politics and Markets in East Asia: Is the Developmental State Compatible with Globalisation? Mark Beeson A revised version of this paper will appear in Richard Stubbs and Geoffrey R.D. Underhill (eds.), Political Economy and the Changing Global Order, 3rd Edition, Ontario: Oxford University Press. Abstract: This paper details the emergence and role of the ‘Developmental State’ in East Asia and assesses whether it is compatible with processes assocated with ‘globalisation’. The paper argues that despite the fact that the power and authority of states generally has been undermined by globalisation, and more general governance problems in the region, much of Southeast Asia still needs an effective developmental state. One of the most remarkable and surprising aspects of international economic development in the post-World War II period has been the rise of East Asia. A region that observers like Karl Marx and Max Weber once regarded as synonymous with a form of incurable ‘Oriental’ backwardness rapidly transformed itself into the most dynamic economic region on the planet. Even the financial and political crises that hit parts of the region in the late 1990s failed either to stop the broadly based processes of economic expansion that had taken hold in East Asia, or to erase the very real gains that had been made there over the preceding thirty of forty years. The big question, of course, is how did much of East Asia manage to pull off such a feat? This is an especially important question at a time when some observers think that the sorts of ‘interventionist’ policies associated with East Asia’s most successful phase of development are no longer compatible with an increasingly integrated international political economy. -
Issues and Challenges for Building a Developmental State
African Journal of International Affairs, Vol. 8, Nos. 1&2, 2005, pp. 23–43 © Council for the Development of Social Science Research in Africa, 2006 (ISSN 0850-7902) Reinventing the African State: Issues and Challenges for Building a Developmental State Kehinde Olayode* Abstract Academic discourse and development policy debates have grappled with the contentious issue of the state–market interactions in Africa’s development agenda and processes, particularly since the 1960s independence era. At the heart of this debate has been the contestation over the agency for development. The global wave of democratisation that swept through most parts of the developing world in the late 1980s and early 1990s revived this debate on the linkage between democracy, sustainable development, and state capacity in Africa (Leftwich 1996). The twenty-first century is witnessing a resurgence of confidence in a new type of activist state: democratic and developmental in character and content. The fundamental concern of this study is whether the exigencies of globalisation can be reconciled with democratisation and sustainable development. This provokes further questions such as: how can fragile democratic regimes improve their prospects for consolidation at a moment when the distributive impact of concurrent programmes of economic liberalisation and adjustment are highly contestable? Are the economic reforms prescribed by Bretton Woods Institutions (BWI) and bilateral donors compatible with democratisation and developmental processes? How can the state’s systematic loss of capacity to manage the economy be reconciled with demands for a more democratic polity? Finally, this paper examines the strategies for building the capacity of the African state as agent of development and partnership in the democratisation process. -
Unfree Labor, Capitalism and Contemporary Forms of Slavery
Unfree Labor, Capitalism and Contemporary Forms of Slavery Siobhán McGrath Graduate Faculty of Political and Social Science, New School University Economic Development & Global Governance and Independent Study: William Milberg Spring 2005 1. Introduction It is widely accepted that capitalism is characterized by “free” wage labor. But what is “free wage labor”? According to Marx a “free” laborer is “free in the double sense, that as a free man he can dispose of his labour power as his own commodity, and that on the other hand he has no other commodity for sale” – thus obliging the laborer to sell this labor power to an employer, who possesses the means of production. Yet, instances of “unfree labor” – where the worker cannot even “dispose of his labor power as his own commodity1” – abound under capitalism. The question posed by this paper is why. What factors can account for the existence of unfree labor? What role does it play in an economy? Why does it exist in certain forms? In terms of the broadest answers to the question of why unfree labor exists under capitalism, there appear to be various potential hypotheses. ¾ Unfree labor may be theorized as a “pre-capitalist” form of labor that has lingered on, a “vestige” of a formerly dominant mode of production. Similarly, it may be viewed as a “non-capitalist” form of labor that can come into existence under capitalism, but can never become the central form of labor. ¾ An alternate explanation of the relationship between unfree labor and capitalism is that it is part of a process of primary accumulation. -
Some Worries About the Coherence of Left-Libertarianism Mathias Risse
John F. Kennedy School of Government Harvard University Faculty Research Working Papers Series Can There be “Libertarianism without Inequality”? Some Worries About the Coherence of Left-Libertarianism Mathias Risse Nov 2003 RWP03-044 The views expressed in the KSG Faculty Research Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the John F. Kennedy School of Government or Harvard University. All works posted here are owned and copyrighted by the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only. Can There be “Libertarianism without Inequality”? Some Worries About the Coherence of Left-Libertarianism1 Mathias Risse John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University October 25, 2003 1. Left-libertarianism is not a new star on the sky of political philosophy, but it was through the recent publication of Peter Vallentyne and Hillel Steiner’s anthologies that it became clearly visible as a contemporary movement with distinct historical roots. “Left- libertarian theories of justice,” says Vallentyne, “hold that agents are full self-owners and that natural resources are owned in some egalitarian manner. Unlike most versions of egalitarianism, left-libertarianism endorses full self-ownership, and thus places specific limits on what others may do to one’s person without one’s permission. Unlike right- libertarianism, it holds that natural resources may be privately appropriated only with the permission of, or with a significant payment to, the members of society. Like right- libertarianism, left-libertarianism holds that the basic rights of individuals are ownership rights. Left-libertarianism is promising because it coherently underwrites both some demands of material equality and some limits on the permissible means of promoting this equality” (Vallentyne and Steiner (2000a), p 1; emphasis added). -
Of Miracles and Crises: (Re-)Interpretations of Growth and Decline in East and Southeast Asia
APV170.fm Page 137 Monday, September 16, 2002 3:07 PM Asia Pacific Viewpoint, Vol. 43, No. 2, August 2002 ISSN: 1360-7456, pp137–156 OfORIGINALBlackwell108APVAsia1360-7456©432August017Growth0Graphicraft The Cowley Pacific Accounting 2002and Publishing Limited, declineViewpointRoad, ARTICLE OxfordAssociation in Hong East OX4 Kongandmiracles of Southeast1JF Australia and 350 Asia and Main New Street, Zeland, Malden 2002 MA 02148, USA. and crises: (re-)interpretations of growth and decline in East and Southeast Asia Jonathan Rigg Abstract: In the last two decades of the 20th century Asia stumbled from miracle into crisis. The crisis not only had manifold social consequences but also demands a reconsideration of the multiple explanations offered for Asia’s miracle years. This paper examines these explanations in the light of the crisis and briefly discusses the ways in which scholars of different orientations have adapted and refined their views. In particular the paper looks back on the influential East Asian miracle report of the World Bank, how it was interpreted at the time of publication, and how the report did (or did not) reflect the dominant Washington consensus. The paper then offers a discussion of the post-Washington consensus concluding that the crisis has seen some convergence of the revisionist developmental state and neoliberal positions. However, this convergence should not be seen as a paradigm shift but rather as a reworking of existing positions in the light of debates that predated the economic crisis. Keywords: East and Southeast Asia, miracle, crisis, World Bank, Washington consensus, post-Washington consensus In the years running up to 1997, a select band of East and Southeast Asian countries experienced perhaps the most rapid and sustained period of economic growth in human history. -
Small Businesses and Private Entrepreneurship During Transition: the Case of the Czech Republic
Small Businesses and Private Entrepreneurship during Transition: The Case of the Czech Republic by Vladimír Benácˇek CERGE-EI, April 1994 Abstrakt Nesmírneˇ intenzívní a spontánní expanze soukromého malého a strˇedního podnikání v Cˇ eské republice v období 1990-93 probíhala soucˇasneˇ s neméneˇ dramatickými zmeˇnami v alternativní (stínové) ekonomice. To také vysveˇtluje, procˇ je rozmeˇr tohoto sektoru stále statisticky podhodnocován. Korˇeny nových podnikatelu˚ lze cˇasto sledovat hluboko až do usporˇádání bývalé totalitní spolecˇnosti - do výrazneˇ se konstituovaných skupin nomenklatury a "šíbru˚" tehdejší stínové ekonomiky. Šance zbývající cˇásti obyvatelstva byly pak pro vstup do trˇídy nových kapitalistu˚ výrazneˇ oslabeny z du˚vodu jejich nedostatecˇné vybavenosti kapitálem nejru˚zneˇjšího druhu. Makro a mikroekonomická politka byly významným faktorem, který rozvíjel, respektive tlumil produktivní orientaci podnikatelu˚ nebo ji prˇípadneˇ odkláneˇl do neproduktivních alternativ. Dosažitelnost kapitálu a institucionální podmínky ovlivnˇující fungování trhu˚ a chování podnikatelských subjektu˚zu˚stávají nadále hlavními faktory ovlivnˇujícími rozvoj celého hospodárˇství. V záveˇru práce se diskutují problémy soucˇasného podnikatelského klimatu a nastinˇují se neˇkteré alternativy hospodárˇské politiky. Abstract The impressive and spontaneous build-up of small and medium-sized private businesses in the Czech Republic between 1990-93 coincided with similarly dramatic changes in the "alternative" (shadow) economy. This is the reason why the size of the private sector is significantly statistically underestimated. The origins of the new private entrepreneurs can often be traced to communist times - to the group of nomenklatura and the group of illicit marketeers. The remaining part of society was partially handicapped in its entry into the new capitalist class because of its lower endowments of capital of various kinds. -
Does the Market React Differently to Chaebol Firms?
The Journal of Applied Business Research – September/October 2014 Volume 30, Number 5 Does The Market React Differently To Chaebol Firms? Heejin Park, Hanyang University, South Korea Jinsoo Kim, Hanyang University, South Korea Mihye Ha, Hanyang University, South Korea Sambock Park, Hanyang University, South Korea ABSTRACT Based on a sample of Korean firms listed on the KOSPI and KOSDAQ from 2001 to 2011, we examined whether the affiliation of a firm with a Chaebol group affects the sensitivity of stock prices to earnings surprises. We found that the market response to positive (negative) earnings surprises is more positive (negative) for Chaebol firms than for non-Chaebol firms. In addition, we investigated how intra-group transactions affect the ERCs of Chaebol firms by comparing with those of non-Chaebol firms. Our results show that the intra-group transactions of Chaebol firms are positively related to ERCs under both positive and negative earnings surprises. However, we did not find the same results from the analyses of non-Chaebol firms. Keywords: Chaebol Firms; Earnings Response Coefficient (ERC); Earnings Surprises; KOSPI; KOSDAQ 1. INTRODUCTION he aim of this study is to examine how differently the market reacts to earnings surprises of Chaebol firms compared to those of non-Chaebol firms. Although there is no official definition of Chaebol, T firms are perceived as Chaebol if they consist of a large group and operate in many different industries, maintain substantial business ties with other firms in their group, and are controlled by the largest shareholder as a whole. The definition used to identify Chaebol firms is that of a large business group established by the Korea Fair Trade Commission (KFTC) and a group of companies of which more than 30% of the shares are owned by the group’s controlling shareholders and its affiliated companies.