<<

Asset ownership and female empowerment: Evidence from a natural experiment in *

Sarah Khan1 and Stephan Klasen2 December, 2019

Abstract

In this study, we exploit a natural experiment, to investigate the size and nature of the gender asset gap in Pakistan. In 2010, there were massive floods in Pakistan, which affected nearly a fifth of the country, and caused a distinct deterioration in socio-economic conditions. Families in flood-effected regions faced a considerable decrease in inheritable property, potentially leading to a scarcity in family assets that could be passed on to the next generation. We use the 2010 floods as a wealth shock to study the impact of decreased household wealth, due to exposure to flooding, on marital asset ownership of women, and subsequently, on female empowerment outcomes. 2SLS estimation results show that retaining marital assets are associated with a higher status of women in rural Pakistan. Specifically, retaining a higher brideprice (bari) leads to an increase in the empowerment of women in the household. In a country with poor implementation of women’s property rights, marital assets might be the only property that women possess.

Keywords: Marital transfers; Decision-making; Domestic violence; Pakistan JEL Codes: C26; J12; J16; Q54

*Acknowledgements We gratefully acknowledge funding from Economic Development & Institutions (EDI). We would also like to thank participants at Sustainability and Development Conference 2019, 28th IAFFE Annual conference 2019, and WIDER Development Conference 2019 for helpful comments.

1,2Georg-August-Universit¨atG¨ottingen 1Email: [email protected] 2Email: [email protected] 1

I - Introduction

It has been recognized in the literature that women do not necessarily share in the wealth of men, even within the same household or family. There exist large inequalities in ownership of land and productive assets between men and women. Not only does this occur due to the lower likelihood of women bequeathing the land and assets in the first place, it is also often the case that the quality of their assets they possess is generally lower than those of men (Quisumbing and Maluccio, 2003). If the woman do known some assets, they often relinquishes the right to exercise the use of the asset itself (Udry, 1996; Udry et al, 1995; Deere and Doss, 2006). Evidence from developing countries does not provide support for the unitary or cooperative household bargaining models (Heath and Tan, 2014; Rangel, 2006. Moreover, there is growing evidence that the gender disparities in wealth is important (Breza, 2005; Fafchamps, 2002; Quisumbing, 2003; Deere, 2006, Ambrus et al, 2008; Doss, 2006). Women’s increased control of resources has been shown to improve their bargaining power in the household, leading to differential development outcomes. It has improved intergenerational transfers, child development and other indicators of women’s autonomy (Behrman, 2010; Pitt et al., 2006; de Brauw et al., 2014). Moreover, the burden of unequal access to land and resources is not only limited to the household. An estimated 2.5-4% lower total agricultural output are also attributed to the gender asset gap on the supply side (FAO, 2011). Therefore, the inequalities in land and wealth are constraints that cannot be ignored when aiming at forward-looking and equitable development.

In a patrilineal society like Pakistan, women are excluded from directly inheriting parental property. Even after the amendment of the Prevention of Anti-Women Practices Act in 2011, which gives women equal rights in inheriting agricultural land, and makes depriving women of inheriting property illegal and punishable with imprisonment, yet over 80 percent women report not receiving their legal share in inheritance (UN-Habitat, 2012). Moreover, women do not always retain their brideprice, as the assets received form the husband are often used up for consumption-smoothing. Thus, marital asset transfers plays the role of a pre-mortem inheritance, transferring a woman’s share of parental property to her marital family.

There is extensive literature from Africa and that has examined the role of women’s marital transfers on empowerment outcomes but few have studied the relationship in 2

Pakistan’s context. Our study supplements this literature by studying the effects of female marital and parental inheritance on women’s empowerment and gender norms in Pakistan. We exploit a natural experiment, to investigate the size and nature of the gender asset gap in Pakistan. In 2010, there were massive floods in Pakistan, which af- fected nearly a fifth of the country, and caused a distinct deterioration in socio-economic conditions for hundreds of thousands of families. The monsoon floods claimed the lives of over 1,700 people and directly affected more than 14 million people, with the destruc- tion of infrastructure and property, such as houses, roads, schools and health facilities was estimated to be close to USD 9.7 billion. Since this flooding was much worse in particular regions, this gives us a form of heterogeneity in the intensity of physical and financial devastation that was wrought upon our sample households. The damage was most pronounced in the districts of Muzaffargarh and D.G. Khan in the Punjab, Now- shera and Charsadda in KPK, and Shikarpur and Sukkar in Sindh, which we use as our sample districts (UNOCHA, 2010). We collect primary data from household that were affected by these floods, and compare their information to those households that did not experience large losses in assets and wealth, but are comparable otherwise. The data we collect primarily informs us about the constraints on women’s asset ownership and sec- ondarily help determine the role of female asset ownership and inheritance on women’s empowerment and household welfare in Pakistan. Families in flood-effected regions faced a considerable decrease in inheritable property, potentially leading to a scarcity in fam- ily assets that could be passed on to the next generation. More importantly, given this paucity, there could be a bias in the transfer of assets against the female members of the family. We exploit the impact of this exogenous decrease in female ownership of assets on spousal and female welfare in general, exploring the channel of reduced female bar- gaining power particularly. Individual level data is collected on information regarding marital and parental asset transfers, attitudes and practices, along with human capital outcomes. Further, information on female bargaining proxies, such as mobility, labour force participation, decision making power are also be collected.

The remainder of this study is constructed as follows. Section 2 overviews related re- search and existing data. Section 3 describes our unique household survey and the dataset. Section 4 presents the empirical results and section 5 presents the conclusion. 3

II- Female Asset ownership in Pakistan: Features of Dowry and Brideprice

To underscore the importance of investigating dowry practice in rural Pakistan, this section describes features of marital practice, as distinguished from those in India where the most of the literature is concentrated and may possibly alter the dowry effect.

Haq-e-Mehr, Brideprice, and Dowry

Islamic marriage contract under Pakistani marital laws have the following features. Mar- riages generally involve contracts, which are somewhat similar to pre-nuptial agreements. The marriage is only considered complete with a Nikahnama drawn out by a Muslim cleric. Before the marriage is officiated, a formal contract is drown up that notes the consent of the couple to marry, and specifies the exact amount of Haq-e-Mahr (dower) to be transferred from the groom to the bride. Both marital parties sign the Nikahnama issued by the union council and each party is supposed to keep a copy. The Islamic Nikahnamah only requires that the Haq-e-Mahr is mentioned in the contract, while Ja- hez (dowry) is not required to conclude the marriage contract. Haq-e-Mahr consists of two parts: Moajal (prompt) and Ghair Moajal (deferred). Moajal Haq-e-Mahr is an immediate transfer at the time of marriage from the groom’s to the bride’s side, while Ghair Moajal Haq-e-Mahr is a deferred transfer promised for payment at the time of divorce or death of the husband. These cannot be renegotiated after the marriage takes place and traditionally would be maintained by the wife. However, under loose property rights and a patriarchal society, the bride might lose control over the right of ownership of particular assets. Also, the deferred dower payment, for most cases of divorce or death of the husband, is never paid. As reported in the descriptive stastics (table 2), the total amount of Haq-e-Mahr is a very small and is merely symbolic gesture to fill out a section the marital contract (Makino, 2019). Besides Haq-e-Mahr, the brides also receives a further transfer from the husband in the from of a customary brideprice (we use the term bari for brideprice). Bari typically includes the same items as the dowry, furniture, jewelry, clothing, and household items, and this is a much more significant transfer than the Haq-e-Mahr specified in the Nikahmana (Makino, 2019).

Along with the practice of brideprice, the practice of dowry giving is also prevalent in Pakistan. In contrast to Haq-e-Mahr (dower), Jahez (dowry) does not originate from 4

Islamic law and is rather a cultural practice inherited from upper-caste Hindus in India, before the partition of the Indian subcontinent. In Muslim-majority Pakistan, the word jahez is used to describe dowry, the practice of the transfer of assets from the woman’s family to her marital home. Jahez can be classified into two categories: one comprises household items such as furniture, clothing, electronics, and utensils for the bride to set up a home, and the other comprising items of higher value, for instance jewelry, cash, and, depending on the bride’s family financial status, even vehicles and land (Waheed 2009). As the practice of dowry giving has its origins in predominantly Hindu parts of the Indian sub-continent, this traditional was not strictly observed in predominantly regions. This is evident from marriage practices of the KPK and Balochistan province, where the practice of brideprice is the norm (Makino, 2019). In the remaining two provinces of Punjab and Sindh, the practice of dowry has been observed in rich families as in Indian Punjab, since the late 19th and early 20th centuries (Waheed 2009). Under Islamic family laws, besides marital transfers from the husband, women are also entitled to receiving a parental inheritance. However, given the subordinate position of women, they rarely inherit any lucrative assets from their parents. Also, very few women are inclined to assert their legal right over their parental inheritance. Their status in their marital homes, especially in the early years, is heavily dependent on social support from male relatives. Women are therefore reluctant to forgo this tremendous social advantage for the sake of any economic gains they may accrue from asserting their claim to the family inheritance (Hussain, 1999).

Dowry, brideprice and household bargaining: Theory and evidence

The practice of dowry/bride-price is criticised in social media and commonly in the economics literature, due to the social and economic costs associated with it, especially those being unequally borne by the females in the relationship. However, within the economics literature that estimates the role of assets in female empowerment, such marital transfers are largely used as a proxy for the bargaining power. Especially within the non-cooperative bargaining literature, these are considered as non-labour income sources, which then enters the women’s individual utility function and plays a role in her empowerment (Doss, 2011; Quisumbing and de la Briere,2000 ; Ambrus et. al, 2008; Mbaye and Wagner, 2017 and Kaye et al., 2005). Other studies show that the practice might not necessarily have an empowering affect, if the marital transfer is not retained by the wife (Chan and Zhang, 1999). Moreover, bride-price also increases the risk of 5 early marriages (Corno and Voena, 2016; Ashraf et al., 2014). The association between marital transfers and female empowerment and wellbeing is still an open question and might well depends on the context.

There are two major theories in the literature on the effects of marital transfers on women’s empowerment. Gary Becker in “A Treatise on the Family” (1991) proposes two theories for the prevalence of dowry (1) the bequest model and (2) the price model. Becker (1991) proposed that dowry is as a pre-mortem bequest transferred from the bride’s parents, which she takes to her marital household. As a compensation for the lack of property rights, daughters receive a dowry as an early inheritance from their parents at the time of marriage, and then do not receive an actual inheritance when the parents’ assets are being distributed. In the Pakistani context, even though the inheritance laws state that daughters get half the share of their brothers in their parents’ bequeath. In practice, however, sisters give up their rights to their brothers and do not claim or inherit their family’s property despite those legal provisions. Thus, parents provide their daughters with dowry so that after marriage, they can maintain the same standard of living as in their natal family (Makino, 2019). The second model is in line with the price model where dowry is the price determined in the marriage market. According to Becker (1991), the person who gains in the marriage, one’s actual marital income is more than the equilibrium income, pays the price at the time of marriage. The quality of the bride or the groom determines the price (dowry) i.e. a higher quality bride (groom) would require a lower (higher) dowry, and vice versa. The quality of the bride and the groom is estimated by characteristics considered in the marriage market; socio-economic status, academic achievements, physical features age at marriage, income earning potential (Makino, 2019), and in the Pakistani context, the groom’s occupation (men employed in STEM are considered having higher earning prospects) and ”prestigious” family name (indicating wealthy feudal background).

There is a dearth of empirical literature on marital assets in Pakistan, mostly due to lack of data on intra-household asset allocation. Most of the existing studies in the South Asian context focus on India. Chan (2014) proposes that dowry has a heterogeneous nature and should be decomposed into it two components: A groomprice, which is not in the wife’s control, and a bequest dowry, which she is more likely to control. Using data from Karnataka, India, the author finds that only a bequest dowry enhances women’s status in the marital household. Jejeebhoy (2000) finds that dowry has empowering 6 effects in only northern parts of India. Dowry amount seems to be negatively associated with women’s decision-making power in the southern states. Bloch and Rao (2002) and Srinivasan and Bedi (2007), both using data from a few specific Indian villages, indicate that women with higher dowry amounts are less likely to suffer spousal abuse. Marital assets also seem to have heterogeneous effects on women’s status in other contexts: Zhang and Chan (1999) and Brown (2009) use East Asian datasets and show that dowries have positive effects on several measures of women’s welfare, while Suran et al. (2004), using data from rural , find a completely opposite effect. In sum, the relation between dowry and women’s welfare remains an open empirical question because its precise nature likely varies depending on the social context. The closest research article to our study is the recently published article by Makino (2019) looks at only Punjab province in Pakistan. We extend the analysis to other provinces, with varying cultural practices and we control for endogeneity of marriage payments

III - Data and Empirical strategy

As this study investigates the channels through which female inheritance might have an impact on female bargaining power within the household, the data collected focuses on asset ownership and its accessibility to women in the sample. We also examine other outcomes, like female education and skill formation, female labour force participa- tion, female entrepreneurial activities etc. that might imply an increasing empowerment amongst women. Finally, we additionally investigate heterogeneity of impact across a range of variable e.g. across households of different wealth levels, different religious beliefs, different types of inheritance etc.

To acquire information on all required variables and outcomes for each household, we conducted a survey within randomly selected villages in Pakistan, and created a dataset containing information on parental and marital inheritance and asset ownership, and on measures of gender norms and roles in the society. Moreover, information on parental background for both the husband and wife, and information on pre-marriage assets, transfers at marriage, inheritance, and indicators of women’s mobility and decision- making in the household were also collected for the selected households. The second part of the study uses the wealth shocks to examine the impact of a decrease in assets on the asset ownership of women. We study the impact of decreased household wealth, 7 due to exposure to flooding, on marital asset transfer, and subsequently, on female em- powerment outcomes. For information on flood damages, we utilize publically available data for flood intensity at UNOCHA and IFPRI. We used the flood information pro- vided by OSHA to select villages that had been worst-hit by flood. We also consulted our survey partners in Pakistan, the National Rural Support Programme (NRSP), on the selection of flooded villages, as they have been previously involved in projects related to flood rehabilitation in all provinces. Within each village, we selected 12 households to be interviewed at random. Sample breakdown: In total, 720 households were inter- viewed in six districts (2 districts per province). The survey teams visited ten villages in each districts that were affected by floods. Table 1 in the appendix shows the village list in our sample.

Eligible households in our survey are defined as those which were affected by the 2010 flood and have a married woman aged 15-65 currently residing in the household. On the basis of the sampling process explained above, we conducted questionnaire based structural interviews using ODK software on Android tablets. The questionnaire was carefully designed to comprehensively understand marriage practices in rural Punjab, Sindh, and KPK provinces of Pakistan. The questionnaire consists of three parts; the first contains questions on marital transfers received from the woman’s own family and her husband’s family, and the second has questions on the woman’s autonomy and decision-making, along with questions on domestic violence. The third part of the questionnaire contains a detailed section on financial losses due to natural disasters and other wealth shocks. Because the second part contains sensitive questions to assess the wife’s status in the marital household, we attempted to maintain the wife’s privacy as much as possible, for example, by requesting a separate interview room so that the wife could answer without feeling pressure from other family members present in the house. Table 3 presents the descriptive statistics for our dataset created from the sampled households.

The top panel of table 2 presents the individual characteristics. The average person in our sample is 40 years of age, with less than one year of education in total. 32 percent of individuals are engaged in some form of employment. The average monthly earning are about Rs.8000 (USD 50). The average monthly household income is about Rs.26,000 (USD 170). The average household has about seven individuals currently residing in it. About 23 percent of women have a father with some schooling, while almost all 8 women have illiterate mothers. The bottom left panel of table 3 presents the general marital information. The average person is married at the age of 19, about the same as the country average of 19.5 years (Marphatia et al., 2017). Endogamy∗ is widely practiced in rural Pakistan; 64 percent are married to their first cousins, while the rest are married to someone in the community or distant family. About 30 percent of marriages are Watta-Satta arrangements† The bottom right panel of table 3 summarises the marital payments received by women in our sample, shown by province. Overall, the practice of brideprice is a more prevalent than dowry: about 67 percent women have received a brideprice, versus only 48 percent receiving a dowry. When broken down by provinces, dowry and brideprice have varying patterns. Women in KP are more likely to receive both dowry and brideprice than in other provinces. In the KP province, about 94 percent women have received a brideprices, versus 79 percent receiving a dowry. In Punjab, about half of the sample receives a dowry and a brideprice, with dowry being more prevalent. In Sindh, only 9 percent women have received a dowry, while about 60 percent have received a brideprice. The variables Total Dowry Rs. and Total Bari Rs. are the initial endowment of marital transfers received at the time of marriage, measured in Pakistani Rupees. This is calculated by summing up the Rupee value of all items received as a marital transfer. The initial endowment of both dowry and brideprice is about the same, Rs. 50,000 (USD 322), with Rs. 6000 more given as brideprice. The variables Dowry possession and Bari possession are ordinal measure of remaining dowry and brideprice, classified in five categories: possessing (1) all, (2) most, (3) half, (4) little, or (5) none of initial endowment of dowry and brideprice.

Lastly, data on parental inheritance for women cannot be used for measures of women’s assets, as only 16 women in our sample received some inheritance from their parents

∗Endogamous/consanguineous marriage is very common in Pakistan, both in rural and urban set- tings. The most preferred pattern of marriage is between first cousins. Other than marriage with close blood relatives, community marriages (Baradari), in which the bride and groom are from the same natal village, are also widely practiced. Previous qualitative studies show some evidence that consanguineous marriages are less likely to involve marital transfers. However, looking at quantitative evidence, there is no general consensus in the literature on the effects of endogamy on women’s status (Dyson and Moore 1983; Jejeebhoy and Sathar 2001; Rahman and Rao 2004). †Watta-Satta (bride exchange) involves a joint marriage in which a brother and a sister of one family marry a sister and a brother of another family. Watta-Satta may be more frequently observed among relatively poor families because bride exchange can be a way to find a groom without net marital expense (Eglar 1960). This practice has been criticised as it usurps women’s opinion in the choice of a marriage partner. Watta-Satta, can also have the same benefits as endogamy. It has been empirically shown that the likelihood of marital conflicts is lower in Watta-Satta marriages, as the two families can make mutual retaliatory threats (Jacoby and Mansuri 2010). 9 after their death, where 6 of them have given it up to their brothers. None of the male respondents have given up their share from their parental inheritance.

Measuring empowerment - Disempowerment Index

Following Alkire et al (2013), we generate a variant of the Women’s Empowerment in Agriculture Index (WEAI), using modified five dimensions of empowerment (5DE). The WEAI is extensively used for measuring women’s empowerment in the literature (Alkire et al. 2012; Malapit et al. 2014). The index has been designed to make comparisons across countries, contexts, and time. As agency and empowerment are experienced with different tasks and can be described and measured with different domains, Alkire (2005) suggests that most measures of agency and empowerment should be domain-specific. Since empowerment is multidimensional, five domains and ten indicators are used in computing the WEAI, which allows the index to be broken down and compared across different dimensions. The five domains of the WEAI are defined to reflect priorities of agricultural programs. These include (1) decisions about agricultural production, (2) access to and decision-making power about productive resources, (3) control of use of income, (4) leadership in the community, and (5) time allocation. Our choice of indicators used for disempowerment index calculation overlaps with the WEAI, although it has been updated to reflect women’s empowerment in the Pakistani context. The choice of domains, indicators and thresholds used for measuring disempowerment, and their grounding in the theoretical and empirical literature on gender and household decision-making is explained in detail in this section. The five domains of empowerment (5DE) in our analysis are measured using 18 indicators with their corresponding weights. These domains and indicators are described in table 3. The 5DE used in our analysis include:

1. Decisions regarding children

2. Decisions about fertility and birth control

3. Decisions on political participation and labour force participation

4. Decisions on household expenditures

5. Decisions on mobility 10

Children’s Outcomes: The first domain in the disempowerment index measures women’s decision-making ability regarding children’s outcomes. For the domain on inter-generational outcomes, we include five indicators on the woman’s ability to make decisions pertain- ing children in the household. These include (1) decision regarding children’s school attendance, (2) how children should be disciplined, (3) whether girls should be sent to school, (4) son’s marriage, and (5) daughter’s marriage. According to the literature on children’s outcomes , improved decision-making power of the mother has shown to have positive inter-generational effects. As women become more involved in household decision-making, they invest more in the education and health of children and are more gender-neutral (Atkin 2009; Bobonis 2009; Rubalcava, Teruel, and Thomas 2009; Duflo 2000; Duflo and Udry 2004; Lundberg, Pollack, and Wales 1997; Thomas 1990). Increase female bargaining power has been shown to be associated with a larger share of budget used on food and on children’s education and health (Quisumbing and Maluccio, 2003; Duflo and Udry, 2004; Doss, 2006; Robinson, 2012). Evidence also shows that income in the hands of women is associated with increased intergenerational welfare (Schultz, 2002; Rubalcava et al, 2009). Moreover, more empowered mothers are more likely to increase investment in girls, reducing future gender inequality (Duflo, 2003).

Fertility: The next domain measures empowerment of women in fertility decisions. The indicators for the fertility domain include decisions on (1) desired fertility, (2) contracep- tive use, and (3) type of contraceptive. Women’s empowerment have shows to have posi- tive affects on fertility choices. As the opportunity cost of time for women increases, it is expected that fertility rate drops and that income per capita, savings and asset accumu- lation increase (Schuler and Hashemi, 1994; Dupas and Robinson, 2009). Esteve-Volart (2004) also show that exclusion of females from the labour market imply lower female- to-male schooling ratios. In the Paksitani context, several research studies investigate use woman’s autonomy on fertility control and reproductive choices as an indicator for empowerment (Jejeebhoy 1995; Saleem and Bobak 2005, Khan and Awan 2011; Jejeeb- hoy and Sathar 2001; Sathar and Kazi 2000; Winkvist and Akhtar 2000). In Pakistan, reproductive choices may even be dictated by family members other than the husband. For instance, Sultana, Nazli, and Malik (1994) showed that in Karachi mother-in-laws have considerable influence over family planning decisions regarding young couples in the family.

Participation: Following Narayan (2002), we include a third participation domain, which 11 captures key aspects of inclusion and participation in (1) the labour force, and (2) polit- ical activities. It is measured at the individual level, because even if opportunities exist for women to exercise leadership within the community, an individual may not neces- sarily be able to take advantage of such opportunities—for example, if family members object to her participation in groups or in political activities (Ahmad & Khan 2016).

Household expenditure: The fourth domain measures women’s decision-making ability in household expenditures. The indicators included to measure empowermnet in ex- penditure include decisions regarding (1) major consumption expenditures, (2) daily household expenditures, (3) children’s education expenditures, (4) children’s clothing expenditures, and lastly (5) medical expenditures. There is extensive research from de- veloping countries, which shows that mothers/grandmothers allocated more resources to health and nutrition when they have decision-making power over household spend- ing (Hoddinott and Haddad 1995; Duflo and Udry 2004, Atkin 2009; Bobonis 2009; Rubalcava, Teruel, and Thomas 2009; Duflo 2000; Duflo and Udry 2004; Lundberg, Pollack, and Wales 1997; Thomas 1990). Better nutritional status of mothers is also associated with better child health ( Thomas and Strauss 1992; Galloway and Anderson 1994, Bhagowalia et al. 2012). Cross-country evidence also suggests that improvements in food security are often attributable to improvements in the status of women. Smith et al. (2003) show that gender equity alone can result in a 13 percent decrease in the number of malnourished children under the age of three. Similarly, Smith and Haddad (2000) find that the education of women alone explained 43 percent of the reduction of child malnutrition in selected developing countries during the period 1970–1995. Studies from Pakistan also find similar results between the status of women and expenditure on nutrition and health. Alderman and Garcia (1996) show that households with more educated mother have a lower incidence of undernourishment in children. Hou (2011) also finds that when Pakistani women have more decision-making power at home, bud- get shares shift toward their preferred goods, such as children’s clothing and education, while children, particularly girls, are more likely to be enrolled in school. Moreover, con- sistent with the theory that women spend more efficiently on food consumption, there is also evidence that households with more empowered women eat more non-grain food items and consume better calories from food items such as fruits and vegetables when women have decision-making power in the households (Hou, 2011).

Mobility: The last domain relates to mobility, the freedom of movement and the ability 12 to visit places alone. The indicator of mobility relates to the ability to be mobile without seeking permission from others, rather than accessibility to different places. To measure empowerment in mobility, the following questions are considered: (1) visit to own family, (2) visit to in-laws, and (3) visits to friends/neighbours. Mobility gives women increased access to a variety of resources. Many constraints to development, such as women’s lack of education, low labour force participation rates, and low rates of entrepreneurship, are linked to restrictions on women’s mobility (Ahmed & Khan 2016). Mason and Smith (2003) demonstrate that women’s freedom of movement may be more limited because of social context rather than individual characteristics. Malhotra, Schuler, and Boender (2002) also suggest that socio-cultural barriers limit women’s freedom of movement and access to resources in comparison to men. Sathar and Kazi (2000) also use mobility as an indicator in their analysis for rural Pakistan and find regional differences within Punjab, suggesting that women from northern parts of the province have greater ease of mobility than do those from the south.

Coding Disempowerment Indicators:

The disempowerment index requires an empowerment cut-off for each indicator. The indicators’ empowerment cut-offs are noted as zi, so that person i is considered empow- ered if their achievement in that indicator xi is below the cut-off, that is, if xi < zi. The cut-offs of each indicator are coded as binary measures of whether the woman can make decisions in each indicator (1) by herself and (2) together with her spouse.

After identifying the indicators and their corresponding cut-offs, the weights for each indicator in the disempowerment index need to be assigned. The five dimensions of the disempowerment index are equally weighted, so that each of them receives a 1/5 weight. The indicators within each dimension are weighted according to their importance in the Pd Pakistani context. Finally, the indicator i weight as wi, with i=1 wi = 1

Each person is then assigned a disempowerment score according to their empowerment in the component indicators. The disempowerment score of each person is calculated by taking a weighted sum of the number of empowerment measures, so that the disempow- erment score for each person lies between 0 and 1. The score increases as the number of disempowerment measures of the person increases and reaches its maximum of 1 when the person is disempowered in all decision-making component indicators. A person, who is completely empowered in all indicator, receives a score equal to 0. 13

Formally:

Ci = W1I1i + W2iI2i + ...... WdiIdi where:

• Ii = 1 if a person is disempowered in indicator i, 0 otherwise.

• Ci(k) is the empowerment score of individual i,

Pd • wi is the weight attached to indicator i with i=1 Wi = 1

Identifying the Disempowered: Following Alkire et al (2013), a cutoff of 0.40 is used to identify the disempowered. Cutoff is the share of weighted disempowerment an indi- vidual must have to be considered disempowered and is denoted by (k). We define the disempowerment cut-off as the share of (weighted) empowerment a person must have in order to be considered disempowered, which is denoted by k. In this way, some- one is considered disempowered if their empowerment score is equal or greater than the disempowerment cut-off. That is, a woman is disempowered if Ci > k. For those whose empowerment score is above the cut-off, this is replaced by 1. For those whose disempowerment score is below the cut-off, this is replaced by 0. That is:

Ci > k, then Ci(k) = 1 , and Ci ≤ k, then Ci(k) = 0

Empirical Strategy

Our basic model for establishing the impact of marital assets ownership on empowerment outcomes is:

P (Disempowerment)ivd = β0 + β1(Marital Asset possession)ivd + βxXivd + Vd + εi

Our outcomes variable, (Disempowerment)ivd, defined at the individual level, is a di- chotomous variable created using the disempowerment index cut-off i.e. if disempower- ment score Ci is more than 0.40, the individual is assigned a value of 1 as being disempow- ered, and vice versa. Another set of outcome variables are measures of incidence of do- mestic violence and attitudes towards domestic violence. (Marital Asset possession)ivd is our main measure of marital assets ownership. This is an ordinal measure of how much 14 of a woman’s lifetime marital assets she still possesses (including all dowry and bride- price payments). District-specific time-invariant unobserved heterogeneity is taken into account by including district fixed effects Vd. Several observable characteristics at indi- vidual and household levels are included in the vector Xivd. Individual characteristics include age, education level, monthly income, work status, and spouse’s characteristics. Household level controls would include variables on size, structure and wealth status of the household. We also include additional marital information which would affect women’s empowerment e.g. endogamy, initial endowment of marital assets, and age at marriage, information on the marital contract.

Endogeneity issues - Flood shock as an instrument for loss in marital assets:

There are several issues with the measurement of marital assets that could bias the estimates on the effects on women’s empowerment. First, the lack of data and poor quality of asset measurements: marital assets in the South Asian context include of among other items, cash, jewelry, electrical goods, furniture, clothing, household items, and livestock. Assessing the monetary value of such items at the time of marriage becomes a challenge. Also, recall issues about the actual value or quantity of marital assets received could add to the bias in measurement. Respondents might have forgotten the exact dowry or might be unaware of the exact amount in the first place. Secondly, endogeneity of marital assets would prevent from making causal inference regarding the effects of dowry on women’s empowerment. The amount of dowry may affect the variables that are expected to affect the amount of dowry in the future. For example, according to the price model, the groom’s higher education level increases the amount of dowry. Similar to the endogeneity argument in the relationship between the level of education and labour market outcomes, the groom’s parents may also increase human capital investment in their son to increase the future amount of dowry they receive (Makino, 2019). In order to control of endogeneity of marital assets, we use the 2010 flood as an instrument for a wealth shock.

Our instrumental variable of flooding is defined as at the village level (measured in feet of water flooding a sample village), given that there it is highly unlikely that two houses in the same village suffered disproportionally from the same flood. The villages are chosen based on the incidence of flood in July 2010, giving us an exogenous variation in the loss of assets as a result. This is neat natural experiment that can help up exogenously 15 identify the changes in the financial and physical assets of our sample households. At the same time, our instrument flood level has no direct impact on a woman’s empowerment in her marital household. The exogenous variation in loss in assets due to the flood shock serves as an instrument in a two stage least squares estimation, where the first stage establishes the effect of the flood on marital assets, and the second stage then examines the impact of assets on empowerment outcomes. To alleviate concerns related to the effect of this flood on other covariate at the household and community level, we include them within the estimation as well.

Due to the possible endogeneity of marital assets with the empowerment outcomes, we also treat the marriage assets as endogenous covariation and instrument by the floods itself. Hence, The first stage establishes whether the instrument is effective in predicting the loss in assets after the flood.

(Marital Asset possession)ivd = β0 + β1(F lood depth)vd + βxXivd + Vd + εi

This therefore estimates the impact of floods on marital assets for individual i living in village v of district d.(F lood depth)vd is the flooding depth level in village v in district d. The final impact is then established on empowerment outcomes, i.e. the second stage establishes the impact of the change in assets only as a result of the flood, on the empowerment of women:

P (Disempowerment) = β + β (Marital Asset possession) + β X + V + ε ivd 0 1 b ivd x ivd d i

The instrumental variables estimation is replicated with incidence and attitudes towards domestic violence as dependant variables. P (Spousal Abuse)ivd includes several mea- sures of domestic violence: physical abuse (“if spouse has, in the last year, ever being physically violence, i.e. kicked, slapped, threatened with a weapon.”), emotional abuse (“whether husband has, in the last year, ever verbally abused, stopped from meeting friends/family, or denied money for household expenses”), and lastly, questions about attitudes towards domestic violence (“is it justified to beat a woman if she neglects her family, talks back at her husband, ignores her household duties, or leaves the house with- out informing the husband.”)

P (Spousal Abuse) = β + β (Marital Asset possession) + β X + V + ε ivd 0 1 b ivd x ivd d i 16

The domestic violence variables are dichotomous, if the response to any one of the physical abuse, emotional abuse, and attitudes question is a “yes”, the domestic violence measures are then coded as 1. Individual, household, and marital information controls from the disempowerment regression are also added to the domestic violence estimation.

IV - Results

Table 4 presents the main results for the second stage of the instrumental variable regressions on the effects of marital assets on disempowerment of women in our sample. Column 1 and 2 show the second stage regressions for dowry, while column 3 and 4 show the second-stage regressions for bari (brideprice). The disempowerment variables are binary measures of empowerment, with column 1 and 3 showing decision-making by self, and column 2 and 4 showing decision-making together with husband. The discussion on the covariates and the variables of interest is presented under.

Individual controls include age of the respondent, years of schooling, work status, house- hold income, and household size. As age increases, women are more likely to make deci- sions on their own, and less likely to make decisions together with their spouse, although the coefficients are too small to draw conclusions on the economic effect. This is in line with previous findings from South Asian countries, which shows that age can influence a woman’s relative status within the household. Alkire et al. (2013) in their study for Bangladesh find a larger percentage of women empowered in the age group 26–55 years, reflecting disempowerment for younger and elderly women. For Pakistan, Khan & Awan (2011) and Ahmad & Khan (2016) find similar results, where women aged 40–44 years have greater economic decision-making power than younger women. Similarly, Mason and Smith (2003) analyze women’s empowerment among married women within the do- mestic sphere in Pakistan and find that age is positively and significantly correlated with economic decision making, input in family size decisions, and the freedom of movement. Turning to years of schooling, as it improves skills and employability, higher education of women should theoretically translate into higher empowerment. However, the empow- ering effect of education is not so evident in the South Asian context. Aslam, Kingdon, and S¨oderbom’s (2008) find a negligible effect of education on economic outcomes of . This is due to the cultural attitudes against women’s participation in paid work outside of the home. The authors suggest that while education plays an 17 important role in choices of occupation for men, the effect only begins at higher levels of education for women, that is, after about ten years of schooling. Quisumbing et al. (2013) also do not find a conclusive relationship between education levels and empow- erment in their analysis of the WEAI for Bangladesh. Our analysis also does not find any significant empowerment effects of women’s education. Both the coefficient and the significance level are too small. The edudation level in our sample is very low in the first place (less than a year of schooling on average). Both household income and household size, do not seem to improve women’s empowerment. Other studies on Pakistan have shown that women living in joint families (larger household size) are less empowered (Ahmad & Khan 2016). Sengupta and Johnson (2006) find similar effects of living in a large joint family on selected indicators of women’s empowerment for India. Even in urbanised regions, women living in join families are less autonomous than women who do not live with their in-laws. The household income variable is a pooled measure of incomes of all earning members of the household. However, women’s labour force par- ticipation does seem to improve their decision-making in the household. Labour force participation improves decision-making by self by 6 to 8 percentage points and with partner by 1 to 4 percentage points (although coefficients are imprecise). In rural Pak- istan, few women have economic opportunities outside of agriculture, which is also the case for our sample. Previous studies have shown that women from lower income rural households, who usually work in the farms, have lower restrictions on their mobility, and therefore more engaged in production decision-making in the household. This is in contrast with women from wealthier families who do not work in the fields due to class- based segregation and are also expected to observe stricter gender segregation norms i.e purdah (Ahmed & Khan, 2016).

Next, we include a set of covariates about the respondent’s marriage, which could impact her decision-making ability in her marital household. The marital information includes having a say in her own marriage arrangement, whether the woman has read her Nikah- nama (marriage certificate) and also currently possesses it, the amount of Haq-e-Mahr specified in her Nikahnama, conditions imposed on husband in the Nikahnama (right to divorce and paying dower), age at marriage, endogamy (marriage to first cousin, relative, or someone in the community), and finally initial endowment of dowry and brideprice (measured in Rupees). The variable Opinion marriage inquires whether the respondent was asked their opinion regarding her marital arrangements. Having a say in arranging 18 own marriage does not seem to improve empowerment. The variable lacks precision due to very few women responding in the affirmative. The variables Read Nikahnama and Have Nikahnama are indicators of whether the woman has read her own marriage cer- tificate, and whether she possesses it. Even though the law requires that each marriage party reads and signs their own marriage certificate, and also retain one copy, more often than not, the guardian of the bride (male family member) signs the marriage certificate for her. Even though a copy is made for the bride, it is usually left behind with the marriage registrars (usually a mosque cleric) Having read their own Nikahnama (or it being read to her in case of illiteracy), increases her decision-making power with spouse, but decreases the decision-making power by self. Possession of nikahnama does not have a significant effect on decision-making. Only 36 percent of respondent in our sample are in possession of their marriage certificate. The variable Haq-e-Mahr amount, measured in Rupees, is the mandatory dower that has to be stated in the marriage contract. The effect of the amount of Haq-e-Mahr received has no significant effect on the woman’s empowerment. This is not surprising for our sample, as the average amount Haq-e-Mahr is only Rs. 6000. As discussed earlier, the payment for Haq-e-Mahr is only symbolic and only added to the marriage contract as it is mandatory to fill the form field (Oldenburg, 2002) . Next, the variable Condition on husband is a proxy for right to divorce, where the marriage contract stipulates a fine on the husband in case he leaves the wife or divorces her. The effect is not significant, as very few women report having conditions imposed on the spouse. Regarding age at marriage, previous research has shown that the larger the age gap with the spouse, the lower is the empowerment of the younger spouse (Zhang and Chan, 1999). Age at marriage also does not seem to influence em- powerment. The imprecise estimates are likely driven by lack of variation in the age at marriage measure. Most women are married by 19 in our sample.

Next, we include controls for endogomy, i.e. how her relation to the husband effects her household decision-making. The coefficients on endogamy give intuitive results; women married to either first cousin, or relative, or someone in the community are more likely to involved in making decisions in the household. Women married to first cousins are 25 percentage points more likely to be involved in decision-making with their spouse. Those married to a relative other than a first cousin are 12 percentage points more likely to make decisions on their own, and 18 percentage points more like to make decisions with their spouse. Women married within the community (Baradari) are also 22 percentage 19 points more likely to make decisions with their spouse. Marriage to an unrelated person does not seem to give any significant effects on empowerment. Overall, endogamy does seem to improve women’s autonomy within her marital home. This gives support to the qualitative literature on endogamy, which find that endogamy protects women from isolation from their natal families after marriage. The close tie between the marital and natal families is likely to protect women from mistreatment and enhance their status in the marital household (Dyson and Moore, 1983). Next, the variables Initial endowment - Dowry and Initial endowment - Bari are a monetary measures of marital assets/payments received when the woman first got married. We construct this measure by adding up the monetary value of all assets received at the time of marriage. A higher initial amount of dowry leads is slightly higher disempowerment , i.e. a thousand Rupees increase in dowry decreases decisions made independently by 0.1 percentage points. The effect of initial Bari endowment is imprecise. The direction of this result is puzzling and we have only speculate on the mechanisms.

The Instrument : Flood shock and Marital Asset ownership.

The main variables of interest are Dowry possession and Bari possession, which are the ordinal measures of assets currently in possession of the woman. As shown in table 4, asset ownership does not effect decision-making by self, but it does improve decision- making together with spouse. A higher dowry and bari ownership is associated with an increase in empowerment by 72 percent points. The effect size is rather large, which is expected due to the complier effect captured by an instrumental variable However, the direction of the effects on decision-making by self (columns 1 and 3) is opposite of that of decision-making with spouse. That is, the more bari a woman possesses, her decision- making goes down by 34 percentage points, significant at only 10 percent. This is not a surprising result in the context of Pakistan, as very few women are making decisions on their own, even if they score high on decision-making with the spouse and have a better socio-economic background. In a patriarchal setup like rural Pakistan, the main decision-maker is always a male member of the household, either the woman’s father- in-law, spouse, brother-in-law, or her son. Even at high levels of income and education, the woman is highly unlikely to be the main decision-maker in the household. Moreover, in a joint-family setup, there is also hierarchy in the decision-makers. Elder members of the family, mothers and fathers in particular, have a significant say in the decisions made within the household. Older women (i.e. the mother-in-law) would have more say 20 in the household than the daughter-in-law (Mason and Smith, 2003). The second-best option to making decisions independently, would be making decisions together with the spouse.

The full regression for the first stage of the instrumental variable estimation is presented in table 5, where we estimate the effect of the flood shock on marital asset ownership. The instrument used in our analysis, the flood depth measured in feet, is only able to predict reduction in bari (brideprice) and not dowry. If flood depth increases by one feet, it leads to a 1 percentage point decrease in bari ownership. The flood shock does not seem to have a reduction effect on a woman’s dowry. Coming to the strength of the instrument, flood depth seems to be a good instrument for only brideprice (bari), where the Wald-test of exogeneity is significant at 5 percent. In conclusion, flooding only has a negative effect on brideprice. As brideprice is given by the husband and his family, it is used as a first resort for consumption-smoothing. Even thought legally the wife has to retain her brideprice, she does not have full control over it, and it is the first asset to be used up in emergencies. As dowry is coming from her own family, she is more likely to retain it and have a better say in it’s usage. From qualitative interviews, respondents did mentions that a lot of the brideprice was either sold to cover for losses due to the flood shock, or returned to the husband’s family during different occasions. The flood shock did not seem to have a negative effect on dowry. Women in our sample are more likely retain their dowry, as they plan on passing it on to their children for their marriages (usually jewelry). However, if a woman is able to retain most of her brideprice, there is an empowerment effect, which we see from the estimates in the second stage regressions.

The determinants of asset ownership provide intuitive results in most cases. As age in- creases, the amount of dowry and bari possession decreases. Older women are more likely to have used up their assets as more time has passed since their marriage. Qualitative interviews with the sample respondents showed at older women in the household would pass on their larger assets (especially jewelry) to their children, either as a wedding gift, or sold to finance the wedding. Coming to women’s employment, a woman who is cur- rently working is more likely to be possessing most of her dowry, though there is no effect on her brideprice. This is likely a wealth effect, as the woman worked before she got married and was able to afford her own dowry. A large household leads to a lower posses- sion of dowry and brideprice. One additional member in the house decreases dowry and brideprice possession by 10 percentage points (What are the mechanisms here? Joint 21 family? More children? Poverty?).Having say in marriage arrangement increases the bari (brideprice). This is a highly intuitive result, as a bride that can have a say in her marriage arrangement could likely be able to bargain for a higher bari (brideprice). Dowry, on the other hand, seems to not be affected by having opinion in marriage. As dowry comes from the parents’ side, choosing your own spouse might lead to getting a lower dowry from her parents, as a backlash for choosing own spouse. Receiving a higher dowry and bari at the time of marriage leads to higher possession of dowry and bari in the current period. Nikahnama possession and reading also seems to increase Bari own- ership. Having read the nikahnama and having it in possession increases bari ownership by 24 and 22 percentage points respectively. This effect could be picking up the literacy effect, where the bride is able to read her own marriage contract and is aware of her marital rights to retain any assets transferred by the husband and his family. This effect could also explain the positive and significant coefficient on Haq-e-Mahr amount (though it is not economically significant). Regarding age at marriage, higher age of the bride leads to a higher dowry, but no affect on brideprice, though the coefficient is negative. An older bride is paying a higher price according to the price model. Lastly, Baradari marriage (marriage to someone in the community), known but not related leads to a higher dowry. This is likely due to expectation of dowry from the Baradari (Makino paper, 2019). Being married to a cousin does not effect dowry or brideprice. Within an endogamous marriage, there is a lower expectation of marital transfers. Households marry within the family in order to avoid large bride-price/dowry payments at the time of marriage and keep wealth within the family. Credit constraints can have an effect on the association between brideprice/dowry payment and endogamy.

Asset ownership and domestic violence:

We replicate the disempowerment regression for the incidence and attitudes towards do- mestic violence as the dependant variables. Table 6 presents the second-stage results for the effects of asset ownership on measures and attitudes towards domestic violence‡. The incidence of domestic violence questions were only asked from the female respondents, while the attitutes towards domestic violence questions were asked from all respondents (540 female and 120 male respondents). Columns 1, 2, and 3 show the effects of dowry ownership on physical and emotional abuse, and attitudes towards domestic abuse, re- spective. Columns 3, 4, and 5 replicates these regressions for bari ownership. There is

‡The first stage is the same as table 5 22 no effect of asset ownership, dowry or bari, on physical and emotional abuse. But the at- titudes towards domestic violence are seen to improve the more bari a woman possesses. Individuals from households where women possess more bari are about 50 percentage points less likely to justify the use of domestic violence, although the coefficient is only significant at 10 percent.

Turning to the covariates of domestic violence (not presented), the direction of the coeffi- cients on a few important determinants of domestic violence goes against the theoretical predictions in the literature. More schooling is associated with about 1 percentage points more physical violence. Age, work status, household income, and household size are imprecise, though the coefficients are in the right direction. Women are less likely to to justify domestic violence by about 23 to 30 percentage points. Individuals who report having a say in their marital arrangements are also less likely to justify domestic violence, although the coefficients on the incidence of domestic violence are statistically insignificant. Counter-intuitively, those who have read their Nikahnama are more likely to justify domestic violence, by about 20 percentage points. Possession of the Nikah- nama has no effect, although the coefficients are in the right direction. Age of marriage also reducing justification of domestic violence, i.e. an older bride is more empowered in her marital household. Surprisingly, relation to the husband does not seem to reduce domestic violence; women married to relatives are about 20 percentage points more likely to experience both physical and emotional abuse. This goes against the idea that endogamy has a protective effect for women. Initial endowment of marital transfers do reduce justification of domestic violence, though the coefficients are not economically significant.

In summary, there is no conclusive evidence of the effects of women’s asset ownership on domestic violence. The weakness of the results is likely due to under-reporting of domestic violence. Previous literature on domestic violence has shown that there is under-reporting of domestic violence in household surveys. The estimates of domestic violence are then a lower bound of the true effect. (Khan and Klasen, 2018) 23

V - Conclusion

In this paper, we estimate the determinants of marital and parental bridal payments in Pakistan, and whether these payments correlate with the wife’s bargaining power in her marital household. We use the flood as an instrument to conduct a two stage least squares (2SLS) estimation to estimate the effects this wealth shock on the marital assets and subsequently, women’s empowerment. The difference marital payment customs in provinces and the differential impact of the flood across districts helps tease out the impact of this natural disaster on women’s inheritance and empowerment.

Our estimation results show that in rural Pakistan, retaining marital assets are associ- ated with a higher status of women in the household. Specifically, retaining a higher brideprice leads to an increase in the empowerment of women in the household. Addi- tionally, there is weak evidence showing that marital asset ownership leads to a improve- ment in attitudes towards domestic violence. There are no significant effects of assets on the incidence of domestic violence. We believe there is under-reporting of spousal abuse in our sample.

Our study contributes to the literature on women’s asset ownership in two major ways. First, it provides empirical evidence on the effect of women’s asset ownership in Pakistan, where the overall empirical evidence remains scarce for intrahousehold allocation of resources. Second, the study provides a foundation of policy debate concerning the marital customs of dowry and brideprice in Pakistan, where dowry is not yet legally banned and is a hot policy topic because of its alleged negative consequences (Makino, 2019). In order to formulate effective policy for enhancing women’s welfare, the effect of marital assets should be examined, as in a country with poor property rights for women, a marital transfer might be the only asset that women receives and serves as their only source of protection after marriage. 24

Bibliography

Agarwal, B. (1994). A Field of One’s Own. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

Agarwal, B. (1997). Bargaining and Gender Relations: Within and Beyond the Household. Feminist Economics 3(1): 1-51.

Ahmad, N. and Khan, H., 2016. Measuring women’s disempowerment in (Vol. 1512). Intl Food Policy Res Inst.

Alderman, H., and M. Garcia. 1996. Poverty, Household Food Security, and Nutrition in Rural Pakistan. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.

Alkire, S., Meinzen-Dick, R., Peterman, A., Quisumbing, A., Seymour, G. and Vaz, A., 2013. The women’s empowerment in agriculture index. World Development, 52, pp.71-91

Ambrus, A., Field, E., & Torero, M. (2010). Muslim family law, prenuptial agreements, and the emergence of dowry in Bangladesh. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(3), 1349-139

Ashraf, N., Bau, N., Nunn, N. and Voena, A., 2016. Bride Price and Female Education. NBER Working Paper, (w22417).

Aslam, M., G. Kingdon, and M. S¨oderbom. 2008. “Is Female Education a Pathway to Gender Equality in the Labor Market? Some Evidence from Pakistan.” In Girls’ Education in the 21st Century. Gender Equality, Empowerment, and Economic Growth, edited by M. Tembon and L. Fort, 67–92. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Bank, W. (2001). Engendering Development. World Bank: Washington DC.

Beaman, L. C. (2009). Powerful Women: Does Exposure Reduce Bias? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(4), 1497–1540., https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1497.

Beaman, L. C. (2009). Powerful Women: Does Exposure Reduce Bias? . The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(4), 1497–1540. , https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1497.

Beegle, K. E. (2001). Bargaining Power within Couples and Use of Prenatal and Delivery Care in Indonesia’, . Studies in Family Planning 32(2): 130-46.

Behrman, J. (1988). Intrahousehold Allocation of Nutrients in Rural India: Are Boys Favored? Do Parents Exhibit Inequality Aversion? Oxford Economic Papers, 40(1), 32–54.

Bhagowalia, P., P. Menon, A. Quisumbing, and V. Soundararajan. 2012. What Dimensions of Women’s Empowerment Matter Most for Child Nutrition? Evidence Using Nationally Represen- tative Data from Bangladesh. IFPRI Discussion Paper 01192. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute. 25

Bhalotra, S. &.-F. (2014). Health and the Political Agency of Women. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 6(2), 164–197., https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.6.2.164.

Bonilla, J., Zarzur, R. C., Handa, S., Nowlin, C., Peterman, A., Ring, H., & Seidenfeld, D. (2017). Cash for Women’s Empowerment? A Mixed-Methods Evaluation of the Government of Zambia’s Child Grant Program. World Development, 95, 55–72.

Breza, E. (2005). Intrahousehold Resource Allocation in Hausa-speaking Nigeria: Uncovering Gender Assymmetries of Wealth and Savings Behavior. mimeo, Yale University Economics Department: New Haven CT.

Bukhari, S. I. A., & Rizvi, S. H. (2017). Impact of 2010 Floods on Pakistan’s Agriculture. Journal of Environmental & Analytical Toxicology, 07(01).

Chan, W. and Zhang, J. (1999). Dowry and wife’s welfare: a theoretical and empirical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 107 (4):786-808.

Corno, L., Hildebrandt, N., and Voena, A. (2016). Weather shocks, age of marriage and the direction of marriage payments. Working Paper.

Corno, L. and Voena, A. (2016). Selling daughters: Age of marriage, income shocks and bride price tradition. Working Paper.

Deere, C. D., & Doss, C. R. (2006). The Gender Asset Gap: What Do We Know and Why Does It Matter? Feminist Economics, 12(1–2), 1–50. de Brauw, A., Gilligan, D. O., Hoddinott, J., & Roy, S. (2014). The Impact of Bolsa Fam´ılia on Women’s Decision-Making Power. World Development, 59, 487–504.

Doss, C. (2006a). The Effects of Intrahousehold Property Ownership on Expenditure Patterns in Ghana. Journal of African Economies 15: 149-80.

Duflo, E. (2000). Grandmothers and Granddaughters: Old-Age Pension and Intrahousehold Allocation in South Africa. mimeo, Department of Economics, , Massachusetts Institute of Technology: Cambridge MA.

Duflo, E. (2003). Grandmothers and Granddaughters: Old-Age Pensions and Intrahousehold Allocation in South Africa. The World Bank Economic Review, 17(1), 1–25.

Dyson and Moore. 1983. ”On Kinship Structure, Female Autonomy, and Demographic Behavior in India,” Population and Development Review 9(1): 35–60.

Fafchamps, M. a. (2002). ‘Control and Ownership of Assets Within Rural Ethiopian Households. ournal of Development Studies 38(6):, 47-82. 26

FAO (Ed.). (2011). Women in agriculture: closing the gender gap for development. Rome: FAO.

FAO, TCARC, & IFAD (Eds.). (2014). Youth and agriculture: key challenges and concrete solutions. Rome: Published by the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) in collaboration with the Technical Centre for Agricultural and Rural Cooperation (CTA) and the International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD).

Forum, W. E. (2016). Global Gender Gap Report 2016 (Insight Report). http://wef.ch/1yrt8iq.

Friedemann-S´anchez, G. (2006). Assets in Intrahousehold Bargaining among Women Workers in Colombia’s Cut-Flower Industry . Feminist Economics 12(1 & 2): 247-69.

Galloway, R., and M. Anderson. 1994. “Pregnancy Nutritional Status and Its Impact on Birth Weight.” SCN News 11 (6): 6–10.

Heath, R., & Tan, X. (2014). Intrahousehold bargaining, female autonomy, and labor supply: Theory and evidence from India. University of Washington.

Hou, X. 2011. “Women’s Decision Making Power and Human Development: Evidence from Pakistan.” Washington, DC: World Bank.

Hussain, R., 1999. Community perceptions of reasons for preference for consanguineous mar- riages in Pakistan. Journal of biosocial science, 31(4), pp.449-461.

Jejeebhoy, Shireen J. and Zeba A. Sathar. 2001. ”Women’s Autonomy in India and Pakistan: The Influence of Religions and Region,” Population and Development Review 27(4): 687–712.

Jejeebhoy, S. J. 1995. Women’s Education, Autonomy, and Reproductive Behaviour: Experience from Four Developing Countries. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.

Katz, E. a. (2003). Gender, Land Rights, and the Household Economy in Rural Nicaragua and Honduras.

Kaye, D., Mirembe, F.and Bantebya, G., Ekstrom, A., and Johansson, A. (2005). Implications of bride price for domestic violence and reproductive health in Wakiso district, Uganda. African Health Sciences, 5(4):300303.

Khan, S., and R. Awan. 2011. Contextual Assessment of Women Empowerment and Its De- terminants: Evidence from Pakistan. Munich Personal RePEc Archive. Paper 30820. Robina, Australia: Bond University.

Malapit, H. J., K. Sproule, C. Kovarik, R. Meinzen-Dick, A. Quisumbing, F. Ramzan, E. Hogue, and S. Alkire. 2014. Measuring Progress toward Empowerment: Women’s Empowerment in 27

Agriculture Index—Baseline Report. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research In- stitute.

Malhotra, A., S. Schuler, and C. Boender. 2002. “Measuring Women’s Empowerment as a Vari- able in International Development.” Background paper prepared for the World Bank Workshop on Poverty and Gender: New Perspectives. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Makino, M., 2015. Marriage, dowry, and women’s status in rural Punjab, Pakistan (No. 534). Institute of Developing Economies, Japan External Trade Organization (JETRO).

Marphatia, A.A., Ambale, G.S. and Reid, A.M., 2017. Women’s marriage age matters for public health: a review of the broader health and social implications in . Frontiers in public health, 5, p.269.

Mason, K. O., and H. L. Smith. 2003. Women’s Empowerment and Social Context: Results from Five Asian Countries. Gender and Development Group. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Mbaye, L. M. and Wagner, N. (2017). Bride price and fertility decisions: Evidence from rural Senegal. The Journal of Development Studies, 53(6):891-910.

Mehdi, R. (2000). Gender and Property Law in Pakistan, Resources and Discourses. Lahore: Vanguard Books.

Narayan, D. 2002. “Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook.” Washington, DC: World Bank. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/15239. License: CC BY 3.0 IGO.

Oldenburg, V.T., (2002) Dowry murder. Oxford University Press, New York

Panda, P. a. (2005). Marital Violence, Human Development, and Women’s Property Status in India. World Development 33(5): 823-50.

Pitt, M., Rosenzweig, M., & Hassan, M. N. (1990). Productivity, Health, and Inequality in the Intrahousehold Distribution of Food in Low-Income Countries. American Economic Review, 80(5), 1139–56.

Quisumbing, Agnes R., and B´en´edicteDe La Bri`ere.Women’s assets and intrahousehold alloca- tion in rural Bangladesh: Testing measures of bargaining power. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute, 2000.

Quisumbing, A. R. (2003). Household decisions, gender, and development: a synthesis of recent research. Washington, D.C: International Food Policy Research Institute. Quisumbing, A. R. (2003). Resources at Marriage and Intrahousehold Allocation: Evidence from Bangladesh, Ethiopia, Indonesia, and South Africa. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65: 283-327. 28

Quisumbing, A.R., and K. Hallman. (2003). Marriage in Transition: Evidence on Age, Educa- tion, and Assets from Six Developing Countries. Policy Research Division Working Paper 183, Population Council: New York.

Quisumbing, A. R., & Maluccio, J. A. (2003). Resources at marriage and intrahousehold allo- cation: Evidence from Bangladesh, Ethiopia, Indonesia, and South Africa. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65(3), 283-327.

Rahman, Lupin and Vijayendra Rao. 2004. ”The Determinant of Gender Equity in India: Examining Dyson and Moore’s Thesis with New Data,” Population and Development Review 30(2): 239–68.

Rangel, M. A. (2006). Alimony rights and intrahousehold allocation of resources: evidence from Brazil. The Economic Journal, 116(513), 627-658

Saleem, S., and M. Bobak. 2005. “Women’s Autonomy, Education and Contraception Use in Pakistan: A National Study.” Reproductive Health 2 (8): 1–8.

Sathar, Z., and S. Kazi. 2000. “Women’s Autonomy in the Context of Rural Pakistan.” Pakistan Institute of Development Economics 39 (2): 89–110.

Sengupta, M. and Johnson, N.E., 2006. Does Educational Superiority Autonomize Daughters- in-law who Live with Their Mothers-in-law in India: A Test of Caldwell’s Thesis. Women In International Development.

Schuler, S., and S. Hashemi. 1994. “Credit Programs, Women’s Empowerment and Contracep- tive Use in Rural Bangladesh.” Studies in Family Planning 25 (2): 65–76.

Smith, L. C., and L. Haddad. 2000. Explaining Child Malnutrition in Developing Countries. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.

Smith, L. C., U. Ramakrishnan, A. Ndiaye, L. Haddad, and R. Mortorell. 2003. The Importance of Women’s Status for Child Nutrition in Developing Countries. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.

Sultana, N., H. Nazli, and S. Malik. 1994. “Determinants of Female Time Allocation in Selected Districts of Rural Pakistan.” The Pakistan Development Review 33 (4): 1141–1153.

Thomas, D. (. (1999). Intrahousehold Resource Allocation: An Inferential Approach. Journal of Human Resources 25(4): 635-64.

Thomas, D., and J. Strauss. 1992. “Prices, Infrastructure, Household Characteristics and Child Height.” Journal of Development Economics 39 (2): 301–331. 29

Udry, C. (1996). Gender, Agricultural Production, and the Theory of the Household. Journal of Political Economy, 104(5), 1010–1046. https://doi.org/10.1086/262050

Udry, C., Hoddinott, J., Alderman, H., & Haddad, L. (1995). Gender differentials in farm productivity: implications for household efficiency and agricultural policy. Food Policy, 20(5), 407–423. https://doi.org/10.1016/0306-9192(95)00035-D

UN-Habitat, 2012. Pakistan, U.H., Pakistan settlements flood recovery project: A Guide to land and property rights in Pakistan

UN-OCHA (United Nations Office for the Coordination of Humanitarian Affairs). 2010. Pakistan floods emergency response plan, September revision.UN-OCHA

United Nations, Departmetn of Economics and Social Affairs, Population Division. 2012. World Fertility Report 2012: Fertility at the Extremes. United Nations.

Waheed, Abdul. 2009. ”Dowry among Indian Muslims: Ideals and Practices,” Indian Journal of Gender Studies 16(1): 47–75.

Winkvist, A., and Z. A. Akhtar. 2000. “God Should Give Daughters to Rich Families Only: At- titudes Towards Childbearing Among Low-Income Women in Punjab, Pakistan.” Social Science Medicine 51: 73–81.

WFP(2010). Pakistan flood impact assessment. World Food Program.

Zhang, J. and Chan, W., 1999. Dowry and Wife’s Welfare: A Theotrical and Empirical Analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 107(4), pp.786-808. 30 Gallo IndharGhanwar IndherHussain BelliIshaque Indhar 11 12 Mitho IndharNooral Chachar 11 12 Panhwari VillagePhullo Goth 12 12 Raza 12 GothSoomra VillageTotal 12 12 12 118 SINDH ShikarpurGaber JunejaGarhi RehmatHazar Khan LashariManik Freq. Lashari SukkarMasiti 12 12 Nawan 12 JunejaQadir DinoRajo 12 LabanoSadullah Naper Freq. Taib 12 Total 11 12 12 12 13 120 MuzaffargarhBasti ArhiBasti Bullah BalochBasti Gazran Freq. DuabaGharib 10 AbadJhouk SaharanKhangan Shumali 12 Mehmood Kot 12 StationThatta SialaThatti Hamza 12 15 12 12 Total 12 12 13 122 PUNJAB Sample breakdown by Province, District, and Village DG Khan Bait MohriBareem WalaBasti Ali ShahBasti RindanDitay wala 11 12 Haji Ghazi 12 SharqiMoza shakira arian 12 Shah 14 WalaSukhera 9 Arain 12 Umer SandeelaTotal 12 12 12 118 Table 1: AgraDheri ShabaraDheri ZardadHisara Yaseenzai 12 MarchakyMirzagan 12 12 Nisatta 12 Painda KhelPlosa 12 weno Garhi 12 Total 12 12 12 12 120 KPK NowsheraAli MuhammadBanda ChelBanda Freq. Muhib 12 CharsaddaDheri Katti KhelMeshakMughulki 11 12 12 Freq. NandrakPashtoon GarhiPir SabaqSpin 12 Kani 12 12 Total 12 12 13 120 31

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics

Individual characteristics Freq. Mean (s.d.)

Age 718 39.50 (11.90) Schooling 718 0.77 (1.72) Working 718 0.32 ( 0.47) Earnings 176 Rs.8,007 (Rs.15,890) HH Income 718 Rs. 26,326 (Rs. 55,668) Household size 718 6.97 (3.20) Father literate 718 0.232 (0.42) Mother literate 718 0.032 (0.17) Marital information Freq. Mean (s.d.) Marital Asset Freq. Mean (s.d.)

Opinion marriage 718 0.47 Dowry received 718 0.48 (0.50) (0.50) Read Nikahnama 718 0.36 KP 240 0.79 (0.48) (0.41) Have Nikahnama 718 0.36 Punjab 240 0.54 (0.48) (0.50) Right to divorce 350 0.22 Sindh 238 0.09 (0.41) (0.29) Mahar amount 718 Rs. 6,348 Total Dowry Rs. 718 Rs. 49,801 (Rs. 47,129) (Rs. 169,916) Condition husband 718 0.07 Dowry possession 718 4.01 (0.25) (1.66) Marriage age 718 19.83 Bari received 718 0.67 (4.85) (0.47) First cousin marriage 718 64 KP 240 0.94 (0.48) (0.23) Relative marriage 718 0.15 Punjab 240 0.47 (0.36) (0.50) Unrelated marriage 718 0.17 Sindh 238 0.59 (0.38) (0.49) Baradari marriage 718 0.06 Total Bari Rs. 718 Rs. 55,393 (0.24) (Rs. 180,243) Watta Satta Marriage 691 0.294 Bari possession 718 3.97 (0.45) (1.69) 32

Table 3: Disempowerment Index - Dimensions and Indicators

Domain Indicator Weight Domain weight Children 0.2 School attendance 0.025 Discipline 0.025 Daughter schooling 0.05 Son marriage 0.05 Daughter marriage 0.05 Fertility 0.2 Children number 0.1 Birth control use 0.05 Birth control type 0.05 Participation 0.2 Political participation 0.1 Labour force participation 0.1 Expenditure 0.2 Consumption 0.05 Household 0.05 Child education 0.05 Child clothing 0.025 Medical expenditure 0.025 Mobility 0.2 Visit to Family 0.1 Visit to In-laws 0.05 Visit to Friends 0.05 Source: Authors’ calculations Adapted from Alkire et al. (2013) 33

Table 4: Effects of Asset ownership on Women’s Disempowerment

Disempowerment cut-off Decisions - Self w/ Partner Decisions - Self w/ Partner Second stage estimates Dowry Dowry Bari Bari Dowry possession 0.3565 -0.7199** (0.2608) (0.2870) Bari possession 0.3432* -0.7240*** (0.2033) (0.2231) Residual -0.3587 0.7409*** -0.3187 0.7367*** (0.2576) (0.2831) (0.2007) (0.2187) Female 0.1762*** -0.0493 0.1190** 0.1147** (0.0413) (0.0489) (0.0495) (0.0563) Age -0.0030* 0.0073*** -0.0018 0.0049*** (0.0018) (0.0020) (0.0012) (0.0013) Years schooling -0.0010 -0.0000 -0.0007 0.0025 (0.0071) (0.0080) (0.0070) (0.0078) LFP -0.0624* -0.0451 -0.0822*** -0.0001 (0.0354) (0.0422) (0.0309) (0.0373) HH income -0.0000 -0.0000 -0.0000 -0.0000 (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) HH size 0.0055 0.0060 0.0084 0.0040 (0.0082) (0.0086) (0.0071) (0.0073) Opinion marriage -0.0506 -0.0359 -0.0459 -0.0506 (0.0347) (0.0370) (0.0346) (0.0368) Read Nikahnama 0.1401*** -0.2642*** 0.1381*** -0.2684*** (0.0325) (0.0403) (0.0323) (0.0392) Have Nikahnama 0.0189 0.0056 0.0337 -0.0328 (0.0339) (0.0401) (0.0364) (0.0429) Mahar amount -0.0000 -0.0000 -0.0000 -0.0000** (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) Condition husband 0.0085 0.0363 0.0206 0.0153 (0.0611) (0.0826) (0.0619) (0.0826) Marriage age 0.0004 -0.0062 -0.0023 0.0010 (0.0034) (0.0039) (0.0031) (0.0036) First cousin marriage -0.0856 -0.2498** -0.1145 -0.1789 (0.0836) (0.1152) (0.0800) (0.1112) Relative marriage -0.1093 -0.1850* -0.1242* -0.1386 (0.0686) (0.1053) (0.0702) (0.1056) Unrelated marriage -0.0740 -0.1438 -0.0716 -0.1537 (0.0877) (0.1228) (0.0881) (0.1199) Baradari marriage -0.0001 -0.2264* -0.0449 -0.1340 (0.1121) (0.1342) (0.0996) (0.1234) Initial endowment - Dowry 0.0013*** -0.0000 0.0011*** -0.0000 (0.0004) (0.0001) (0.0003) (0.0001) Initial endowment - Bari 0.0001 -0.0001 0.0001 -0.0001 (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001)

District FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 718 718 718 718 First-Stage Flood depth -0.004 -0.004 -0.008*** -0.008*** (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Wald-test of exogeneity 1.79 1.79 7.59 7.59 Prob >Chi2 0.1812 0.1812 0.0059 0.0059

Notes: Robust standard errors appear below coefficients in parentheses. * = significant at 10% ; ** = significant at 5% ; *** = significant at 1% 34

Table 5: Effect of Floods on Asset ownership - First stage regressions

Marital Asset Ownership First stage estimates Dowry Possession Bari Possession

Flood depth (in feet) -0.004 -0.008*** (0.003) (0.003) Female 0.250 -0.511*** (0.177) (0.157) Age -0.025*** -0.013*** (0.005) (0.004) Years schooling 0.009 -0.012 (0.032) (0.038) LFP 0.332*** 0.110 (0.126) (0.124) HH income 0.000* 0.000* (0.000) (0.000) HH size -0.099*** -0.093*** (0.022) (0.023) Opinion marriage 0.137 0.251** (0.121) (0.120) Read Nikahnama 0.142 0.240* (0.125) (0.126) Have Nikahnama 0.050 0.217* (0.135) (0.126) Mahar amount 0.000** 0.000** (0.000) (0.000) Condition husband 0.055 0.168 (0.216) (0.230) Marriage age 0.021* -0.013 (0.011) (0.012) First cousin marriage 0.459 0.175 (0.329) (0.326) Relative marriage 0.095 -0.082 (0.286) (0.287) Unrelated marriage 0.012 0.125 (0.367) (0.353) Baradari marriage 0.869** 0.562 (0.388) (0.387) Initial endowment Dowry 0.001** 0.000 (0.000) (0.000) Initial endowment Bari 0.001** 0.001** (0.000) (0.000) District FE Yes Yes

Observations 718 718 Wald-test of exogeneity 1.79 7.59 Prob >Chi2 0.1812 0.0059

Notes: Robust standard errors appear below coefficients in parentheses. * = significant at 10 % ; ** = significant at 5 % ; *** = significant at 1 % 35 -0.2507 0.0691 -0.4861* (0.2355) (0.2658) (0.2643) (0.0532) (0.0630) -0.2978*** -0.2319*** Effects of Asset ownership on Domestic Violence - Incidence and Attitudes 540 540 718 540 540 718 YesYesYesYes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 1.79 1.79 1.79 7.59 7.59 7.59 -0.004 -0.004 -0.004 -0.008*** -0.008*** -0.008*** 0.3558 0.0079 0.19750.1812 0.2311 0.1812 -0.0481 0.1812 0.4645* 0.0059 0.0059 0.0059 Dowry Dowry Dowry Bari Bari Bari (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) -0.3918 0.0021 -0.2487 (0.2851) (0.3462)(0.2801) (0.3326) (0.3411) (0.3298) (0.2295) (0.2599) (0.2607) Table 6: Physical Abuse Emotional abuse Attitudes towards DV Physical Abuse Emotional abuse Attitudes towards DV 2 Chi > : The estimation includes individual characteristics, household characteristics, marital information and district fixed effects. Prob Domestic violence Second stage estimates Dowry possession Bari possession Residual Individual characteristics HH characteristics Marital information District FE Observations First-Stage Flood depth (in feet) Wald-test of exogeneity Female Notes Robust standard errors appear below coefficients, in parentheses. * = significant at 10% ; ** = significant at 5% ; *** = significant at 1%