<<

Social protection, income and health inequities Final report of the Task Group on GDP, Taxes, Income and Review of social determinants of health and the health divide in the WHO European Region

Social protection, income and health inequities Final report of the Task Group on GDP, Taxes, Income and Welfare Review of social determinants of health and the health divide in the WHO European Region

Task group members Olle Lundberg Espen Dahl Centre for Health Equity Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Stockholm University and Oslo and Akershus University Karolinska Institutet College of Applied Sciences Stockholm Oslo Sweden Norway Department of Health Sciences Mid Sweden University Johan Fritzell Östersund Centre for Health Equity Studies Sweden Stockholm University and Karolinska Institutet Stockholm Sweden Joakim Palme Department of Government Uppsala University Sweden Ola Sjöberg Swedish Institute for Social Research Stockholm University Sweden Address requests about publications of the WHO Regional Office for Europe to: Publications WHO Regional Office for Europe UN City, Marmorvej 51 DK-2100 Copenhagen Ø Denmark Alternatively, complete an online request form for documentation, health information, or for permission to quote or translate, on the Regional Office website (http://www.euro.who.int/pubrequest).

© World Health Organization 2016 Please note that the recommendations contained within this report are not recommendations by WHO but rather represent external expert guidance. All rights reserved. The Regional Office for Europe of the World Health Organization welcomes requests for permission to reproduce or translate its publications, in part or in full. The designations employed and the presentation of the material in this publication do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the World Health Organization concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. Dotted lines on maps represent approximate border lines for which there may not yet be full agreement. The mention of specific companies or of certain manufacturers’ products does not imply that they are endorsed or recommended by the World Health Organization in preference to others of a similar nature that are not mentioned. Errors and omissions excepted, the names of proprietary products are distinguished by initial capital letters. All reasonable precautions have been taken by the World Health Organization to verify the information contained in this publication. However, the published material is being distributed without warranty of any kind, either express or implied. The responsibility for the interpretation and use of the material lies with the reader. In no event shall the World Health Organization be liable for damages arising from its use. The views expressed by authors, editors, or expert groups do not necessarily represent the decisions or the stated policy of the World Health Organization.

Text editing: David Breuer Book design and cover design: Christophe Lanoux John McGill Photo credits: Cover: Catharina de Kat-Reynen/WHO Page 8: Christian Als/Panos Pictures Page 14: Markel Redondo/Panos Pictures Page 23: Fredrik Naumann/Panos Pictures Contents

Key recommendations...... 4 Executive summary...... 5 Introduction...... 7 Income as a key resource ...... 7 Beyond state of the art – important knowledge gaps ...... 10 Income and health from a policy perspective ...... 10 Role of social policy institutions ...... 12 Results and findings – income and health ...... 13 and mortality ...... 14 Mortality among children younger than five years ...... 15 Adult mortality ...... 17 Results and findings – social protection policies and health ...... 19 Social rights and self-rated health...... 19 Social spending and health...... 22 Results ...... 24 Social policy and health among young people ...... 26 Conclusions and recommendations ...... 29 References ...... 33 Annex 1: Work process ...... 37 Annex 2: Methods ...... 39 Key recommendations

The degree of generosity of social protection The following general recommendations are policies influences the levels of health and based on evidence from the scientific literature health inequalities, most likely by reducing and the results of this novel analysis. the risk of poverty and increasing the 1 Do something resources available to individuals and In countries with low ambitions for social families. Countries with lower poverty rates protection, some programme improvements also have lower mortality rates, and this would benefit public health and would reduce relationship becomes stronger when the health inequalities. poverty threshold is set lower. Analysis indicates that social policies may deliver 2 Do more diminishing marginal returns, which means In countries with medium or high ambitions that the health gains from social policy in terms of social protection policies, raising programmes per unit of money spent are these ambitions further would benefit health generally higher at lower levels. This and health inequalities. suggests that even modest increases in 3 Do better social protection and cash transfers would Among the most developed welfare states, be important in countries with lower income investing in more social protection is probably levels in the WHO European Region. Further, not the only way to improve public health. the impact of spending differs between However, where the redistributive and educational groups, with the people with less protective capacity of a has education gaining more. This suggests clear actually diminished, it would be beneficial potential for reducing health inequalities. to re-establish previous levels of social Universal programmes and systems that protection, both generally and, in particular, include the majority of the population tend to for the most vulnerable people. Growing be matched by higher generosity for benefits inequalities in mortality and in income targeting people with low income. In addition, strongly suggest that how the resources programmes and institutions that benefit already spent on social protection are used women appear to be important. also needs to be improved. This also applies to the countries that spend less.

4 Executive summary

The main social determinants of health mental factors. Policies that reduce the risk are synonymous with the welfare resources of poverty or, more generally, help to provide that are necessary to lead a good life. better family incomes are therefore likely These include economic resources, working to contribute to better public health. conditions, housing conditions, education Based on a strategic review of the literature and knowledge. The resources an individual and a series of novel analyses of European can command may be strictly personal data, this publication addresses two key (such as knowledge or mental energy) or may issues: the role of poverty for health and be generated by the individual in the market the role of social protection policies for (such as income or prestige) or through the health and health inequalities. As has been family (such as family income, possessions demonstrated earlier, lower poverty rates or social relations). All such individual are associated with lower mortality across resources – personal, market or familial – a range of European countries, both among are important for health and well-being. young children and adults. The amount In addition, however, individuals can also of social spending, a crude indicator of the draw on the collective resources provided generosity of social protection programmes, by welfare state institutions. appears to influence this. More specifically, such resources include Social protection designed to cover income loss from illness, and old This analysis of social protection polices age (the cash side of the welfare state) looks at these, both as legislated social rights as well as welfare services supplied free and as social spending. On the whole, the of user charges or heavily subsidized, such analysis supports the idea that higher degrees as childcare, health care and care for older of social rights in a country are related to people and people with (the better self-rated health at the individual care side). The supply and quality of such level when potential confounders have been resources are likely to influence people’s controlled for. The positive impact of extensive ability to sustain their health and well-being. social rights on health outcomes has been Moreover, these collective resources are demonstrated for all vulnerable socioeconomic likely to be more important for people with groups. Social rights in the form of cash lower incomes and poorer living conditions transfers may therefore be viewed as a generated in the market and by the family. collective resource with important external The less people have in individual resources, benefits: benefits to society over and above the more important it is that they be able those to unemployed people who directly use to draw on collective resources. This implies these transfers. Although specific programmes that welfare policies that provide more have a measurable, positive effect, it appears generous transfer payments and better-quality that the combination of more extensive social services are likely to improve public health rights in several fields (labour market, family and reduce health inequalities. and old age) is important for public health. Role of health and well-being These findingsare reiterated in the analysis of social expenditure. Across 18 European Of all the resources that are important for Union countries, net of gross domestic health and well-being, economic resources product, social expenditure is associated occupy a special position because they can with health inequalities for both sexes, easily be transformed into other types of although somewhat more consistently resources. Income in general and poverty in among women than among men. In particular, particular are also clearly linked to a range of people with a lower level of education benefit health outcomes through material, social and

5 more from high social transfers than those The research presented here does not identify with secondary and tertiary education. In specific policies that need reforming; however, both absolute and relative terms, educational the whole range of social protection policies inequalities in health decline as social analysed in this report could be reviewed spending rises. in each country. However, the relationship between spending One counterargument to the conclusions and entitlements and health is also curvilinear, and recommendations presented here with diminishing returns in terms of health is the situation in the Nordic countries, at high levels of social spending and social where health inequalities remain despite rights. This suggests that the easiest gains large welfare states and lower poverty rates. can be made among the countries with the However, as demonstrated in this report, least developed social protection systems. more generous and encompassing welfare Even small improvements in legislated social policies, including social protection policies, rights and in social spending are likely to seem to be important tools for tackling some lead to improved health, according to the of the key social determinants of health and results. Although the results invite the general health inequalities in all countries. Various conclusion that more should be spent on forces generate inequalities in welfare social protection to improve health and reduce resources and health, and inequalities in inequalities, the results also suggest that health would have been much greater without this recommendation is especially relevant the welfare states that exist in the Nordic for countries with the lowest levels of social countries and other European countries. spending in the WHO European Region. Another counterargument is that the welfare Doing something in social protection policies state undermines productivity, efficiency is better than doing nothing, and even a small and economic growth. The contention increase in social spending is likely to result that there is a trade-off between efficiency in health gains. and equality is often used to capture this Doing better view. Recent empirical and historical research contradicts this assertion, however; new In recent years, both income inequalities findings rather indicate that large welfare and health inequalities have risen in countries states do not hamper economic growth. with the most extensive welfare states. Where On the contrary, the welfare state may even the redistributive and protective capacity increase economic wealth. This suggests that of the welfare state has actually diminished, comprehensive welfare arrangements may levels of social protection generally, and for foster economic growth, human well-being the most vulnerable in particular, could well and social equality all at once. Hence, be improved again – hence, countries that social protection and welfare state policies already spend the most also have room for should be viewed as important investment more spending on social protection. However, that provides the social infrastructure given the diminishing returns, simply investing necessary for high employment rates. in more social protection is probably not the only solution. Rather, there is room for improving existing social protection policies.

6 Introduction

An important starting-point for the work of societies are facing during the life cycle” Technical Group 4 of the European review (Johansson, 1979, p. 56). More specifically, of social determinants of health and the health such resources include social insurance divide is that the main social determinants designed to cover income loss due to illness, of health also constitute the welfare resources unemployment and old age (the cash side of necessary to lead a good life. These include the welfare state) as well as welfare services economic resources, working conditions, supplied free of charge or heavily subsidized, housing conditions, education and knowledge. such as childcare, health care and care for Such resources can be defined as “… the older people and people with disabilities command over resources in terms of money, (the care side). The supply and quality of possessions, knowledge, psychological and such resources are likely to influence people’s physical energy, social relations, security and ability to sustain their health and well-being. so on by means of which the individual can The supply and quality of resources more control and consciously direct her conditions generally are key factors influencing public of life” (Johansson, 1970, p. 25). The health. However, the collective resources resources that an individual can command provided by welfare policies are not only may be strictly personal (such as knowledge important in helping individuals sustain their or mental energy) or generated by the health and well-being but are also directly individual on the market (such as income controlled by parliaments and governments. or prestige) or through the family (such Moreover, these collective resources are as family income, possessions or social likely to be more important for people with relations). All such individual resources – lower incomes and poorer living conditions personal, market or familial – are important generated in the market and by the family. for health and well-being. The less people have in individual resources, In addition, however, individuals can also the more important drawing on collective draw on the collective resources provided resources becomes. This means that welfare by welfare state institutions. Such institutions policies that provide more generous transfer are intended to assist citizens with “… the payments and better-quality services are collective matters that arise from the demands likely to improve public health and reduce and possibilities that all individuals in all health inequalities. Income as a key resource

Of all resources important for health and Income is not only a central resource for well-being, economic resources occupy ensuring good living conditions; it is also a special position because they can easily a central object for political interventions be transformed into other types of resource. through a range of existing welfare state In work on the factors that help people institutions and programmes that provide to stay healthy, Antonovsky (1979, p. 106) families and individuals with resources. starts with economic resources: “Access to A striking feature of high-income countries money, the symbolic equivalent of resources, since the Second World War is the growth is, I suggest, an important [general resistance of such collective institutions that have resource] in all societies … . Not only important implications for people’s access does money directly facilitate coping with to valuable resources. Of central importance stressors; but, linked to the acquisition is the fact that social protection policies of other [general resistance resources], it is can create a buffer against income loss also indirectly powerful.” and can redistribute income, both over the life-course and between individuals

7 (Fritzell & Ritakallio, 2010). In addition, merely costs; they are often important providing services at low cost or free of social investment that provides the social user charges, such as education and health infrastructure necessary for high employment care, plays an important role for health rates (Morel et al., 2012). Family policies, and well-being. for example, can be designed to promote high labour market participation among Further, income in general and poverty women. This, in turn, affects family incomes in particular are clearly linked to a range as well as gender relations in the market of health outcomes. Policies that reduce the and in the family. risk of poverty or, more generally, contribute to better family incomes are therefore likely Social protection and welfare state policies to help improve public health. Hence, income are not only viewed as investment in a social is an important nexus linking major policy infrastructure, however. In fact, a quite tools with health inequalities through a key common argument has been that the welfare resource and social determinant of health state undermines productivity, efficiency on the micro level. and economic growth. The contention is that there is a trade-off between efficiency A range of conditions and processes and equality. Recent empirical and historical influencethe relationships between policies, research contradicts this assertion, however. family incomes and health. Macroeconomic New findings indicate that extensive welfare processes affect the labour market and, states do not hamper economic growth. in turn, employment and market incomes, On the contrary, the welfare state may even tax revenue and thereby the economic basis increase economic wealth (Garfinkel et al., for policies. Educational policies are of key 2010; Lindert, 2004). This suggests that importance for human capital and people’s comprehensive welfare arrangements may opportunities for gainful employment. foster economic growth as well as human However, complex links and interdependence well-being and social equality. One reason for also exist within a more narrow focus. this is that, when people’s resources increase A generous social protection system requires their sense of security, economic flexibility high employment rates and high taxation and stability, their willingness to take risks, levels. Social protection policies are not well-being and social solidarity also improve.

8 Although all these links and interdependence of active labour market policies contributes are important for a person’s opportunity to a social infrastructure that is likely to to live well and be healthy, the strategic focus greatly influence public health and health is on how social protection policies influence inequalities. However, studying this health through their influence on family infrastructure in terms of the economic value incomes (Fig. 1). for families of these services is complicated, both conceptually and empirically. For The social protection policies that provide example, adding the economic value of cash transfers largely insure against loss services to the income of the people who of income because of people’s inability use them will produce a picture according to participate in gainful employment. This to which terminally ill people, who depend inability, in turn, often arises from reduced on considerable expensive health care, would health and/or functional ability as a result appear to be extremely rich. Nevertheless, of injury, illness, or old age. although it is not directly presented in The value of benefits in kind (or the care Fig. 1, the value of services that are free side of the welfare state) is also central of user charges or strongly subsidized is and highly important. Health care provided important and is included in the analysis free of user charges or training as part of social spending and health inequalities.

Fig. 1 Links between key policies, income and health

Social protection policies

Employment Economic policies transfers

Taxation Taxes policies

Gainful Disposable employment family income

Health and health inequalities

9 The model is formulated on the individual currently using these programmes and level. Although individual people become services. However, the general public good ill or die prematurely, they also live in families rests on the individual value. If services that reside in neighbourhoods that in turn and transfer programmes are of poor quality are embedded in regions and countries. These for the people who need them, they will layers of social, economic and physical context not provide security for other potential are certainly important. Indeed, the policies users either, and hence their public value that are of interest here can all be regarded will also be low. as part of the institutional context that Nevertheless, at the centre of these differs across countries. Although the context, complex relationships are family incomes therefore, is at the heart of the matter, the and their relationship to existing policy tools effects of these contexts on the resources and to health outcomes. The core question on which people and their families can draw for Technical Group 4 is, accordingly, how when needed end up being most important policies that support the generation and for well-being, health and survival. In addition, maintenance of family incomes in various there are important effects over and above ways can contribute to better health at the individual-level access to resources. Good the individual and societal level, and whether education, good health care and generous the policies that are most effective in doing unemployment benefits or child allowances this can be identified. are also valuable for people who are not Beyond state of the art – important knowledge gaps

Understanding how income can contribute inequalities be identified? Identifying to better health could enable existing certain designs or properties of social institutions and programmes that involve protection policies that are associated income redistribution to be designed with better health and smaller health (or redesigned) to improve public health inequalities may enable effective policy in general and for lower-income groups in reforms to be proposed. particular. Potentially important policies here Income and health from a policy include the whole spectrum of income transfer perspective programmes as well as policies that provide resources indirectly, such as welfare services Research into income and health has or education that is subsidized or free of largely focused on the issue of whether user charges. However, despite the quite income inequality as such influences health, extensive literature about welfare states, social independently of absolute levels of income policies and poverty and the literature about or the proportion of poor people. There are income inequalities and health, important many studies, and how to interpret their knowledge gaps still need to be filled. findings is highly debated. Where Wilkinson & Pickett (2006, 2009) find clear evidence Two main issues need to be addressed in for income inequality as such being the key the context of the European review of social driver behind health (and other) inequalities, determinants of health and the health divide. others see merely methodological problems ll What is it about income that matters for and highly mixed results (Deaton, 2003; health? Uncertainty as to whether income Lynch et al., 2004). Further, most existing levels among poor people or income studies use a cross-sectional design only, inequalities per se influence health and few have looked at effects on health and health inequalities (to take but two inequalities (Kondo et al., 2009). possibilities) will create difficulty in However, it can be argued that income designing adequate policy responses. redistribution will reduce health inequalities ll Can specificfeatures of income anyway as long as there is a monotonic maintenance policies across Europe that and at least partly causal relationship between are linked to better health and smaller income and health at the individual level (Deaton, 2003; Ecob & Davey Smith, 1999;

10 Fritzell et al., 2004; Mackenbach et al., however, largely unknown. For example, 2005; Åberg Yngwe & Lundberg, 2007), if income ranking as such is highly important, and that at least part of the relationship is compressing the income distribution would causal. Nevertheless, it is important to not greatly affect health inequalities, whereas understand how such an effect is generated: the opposite is true if the distances between in other words, which mechanisms are active. positions are also important. Modern welfare states with high average Hence, the relationship between income incomes also probably have several pathways and health is complicated and certainly not that link income to health (Lundberg et al., a simple issue of “more is better” but rather 2010). Income and economic resources an issue of poverty as well as a gradient are likely to influence health through material, (albeit with diminishing returns). What is social and mental factors in ways that known and inconclusive about income as are summarized in Fig. 2 (Fritzell et al., a social determinant of health therefore needs 2007; Marmot, 2004, 2005). The relative to be clarified. This is particularly the case importance of the three pathways suggested for whether income distribution per se here (direct consumption effects, direct or poverty and purchasing power problems status effects and combinations of these) is, influences health and health inequalities.

Fig. 2 Model for pathways and mechanisms linking income and health

Material Physical conditions mechanisms

Income Health

Income Psychosocial position mechanisms

Reversed causation

Direct consumption effect Combined consumption – status effect Direct status effect

Source: Lundberg et al. (2010).

11 Role of social policy institutions their economic support (decommodification). Although this can influence health and health The numerous social determinants that are inequalities, several social determinants likely to influence health directly or indirectly probably affect health and health inequalities are also linked to a range of policy fields, rather than a single one. Typical features including economic policies, social policies, of poverty reduction may cluster countries labour market policies, school policies and nicely (at one point in time), but it does many others. Most of these types of policies not follow that countries within clusters are and programmes have primary goals in similar in other ways, such as how health terms of economic growth, employment care is funded. Although welfare state and unemployment rates, return to work, arrangements are likely to be one important poverty rates and so forth. Although all these factor influencing health and health factors and policies in these areas are likely inequalities, drawing useful conclusions to affect health, relating social policies for policy change purposes is difficult based to health is quite complex and even more on research in which welfare states are complex for reducing health inequalities. grouped into broad and analytically imprecise Early observers of health inequalities linked national welfare clusters rather than according them to differences in poverty, food supply, to the more precise mechanisms that produce housing and even anxiety and despair, and these outcomes (Goldthorpe, 2010; Lundberg policies to eradicate such problems remain et al., 2010; Tapia Granados, 2010). important for public health today. However, It has therefore been suggested that studies in modern welfare states in which these focus on the characteristics of institutions types of policies are generally in place, the or what countries actually do, policy by policy key issue is the combination of the generosity (Lundberg, 2008; Lundberg et al., 2008a). and organization of policies, programmes However, the combined impact of policies and services: the institutional characteristics. and programmes as a whole also need Recent years have witnessed an increase to be studied. People who lack resources in attempts to more systematically study generated in the market or the family are welfare states and public health. Some likely to need support from a range of welfare of these attempts have been built on existing state institutions such as unemployment approaches in the extensive welfare state insurance, sickness insurance and health literature, for example by applying the care services. The design and properties well-known typologies suggested by Esping- of the whole range of policies can therefore be Andersen (1990) or typologies inspired by assumed to be important, and more important his work (Dahl et al., 2006; Espelt et al., than the sum of the various institutions taken 2008). Nevertheless, these attempts have one by one. Further, the public policy system produced varying results. Whether based as a whole, or at least the beliefs about its on Esping-Andersen’s three worlds of welfare features and the protection offered, is probably capitalism or other principles for clustering also significant for people who do not make countries, this approach suffers from the use of transfers or services. Although the fact that most of the typologies were designed welfare regime approach may appear to be for other purposes. For one thing, they tend a response to the need for an assessment of to be part of a scientific debate over the roots the impact of all public policies taken together, and driving forces behind the emergence it is actually not, since it in effect tends of the welfare state and the reasons behind to aggregate all country-specific properties key differences: research that identifies under the welfare regime heading. What the welfare state as the dependent variable is actually needed is a method that enables rather than an independent variable. More the direct and indirect effects of a range specifically, this approach clusters countries in of policies and institutions for each country three, four or more groups of countries based to be summarized. This publication uses on one key feature. For Esping-Andersen, two attempts to achieve this, incorporating this feature is usually the degree to which both institutional characteristics and citizens are independent of the market for social expenditure.

12 Results and findings – income and health

The discussion about the effects of income health, larger income disparities are for health and health inequalities has been directly related to higher relative poverty rates. intense but also somewhat confusing. Although the worst consequences of poverty Much of the debate has focused on whether such as famine and extremely poor living or not income inequality per se influences conditions have become marginal problems at people’s health. This discussion has been least in the high-income countries in Europe, propelled by the ideas of Richard Wilkinson, the lack of economic resources is still a potent who initially raised income inequality as determinant of health everywhere (Glennerster an important factor for population health. et al., 2009). One of the traditional key However, Wilkinson has shifted his position differences between approaches to social with regard to what income inequalities protection and welfare policies is also their represent, from the proportion of relatively differing ability to reduce poverty rates poor via social cohesion and finally to (Fritzell & Ritakallio, 2010). a proxy for social distances and social Nevertheless, few studies have directly stratification. Defining income inequality investigated the role of relative poverty when clearly is essential, both for causal analysis studying cross-national variation in population and from a policy perspective. However, health. The role of welfare state programmes recognizing that income inequality is a for population health has recently been reflection of individuals’ (or households’) highlighted. Especially within the NEWS incomes is even more important. Although project (Lundberg et al., 2008a), initiated the aggregate distribution of income may in collaboration with the WHO Commission well affect individual health, it is also, on Social Determinants of Health, several and perhaps mainly, affected by factors studies were produced linking specific at the individual level such as income. designs, generosity and coverage of social Thus, irrespective of whether it is income policy programmes to overall and age-specific inequalities per se or only personal income mortality as well as morbidity (Esser & Palme, that influence people’s health, the effect 2010; Ferrarini & Norström, 2010; Kangas, is produced at the individual level. The 2010; Lundberg et al., 2008b; Norström & mechanisms may be linked to purchasing Palme, 2010). These studies focused on the power and consumption effects, social cash side of the welfare state and supported comparison and status effects or combinations the idea that more generous programmes of these, but the link between income influenced public health during the second (whether at the macro or micro level) half of the 20th century, at least for infant and and health is nevertheless evident at old-age mortality. Although the mechanisms the individual level. (For practical and involved were not studied directly, it was data-related issues, some of the analyses argued that better economic resources among presented will nevertheless be performed broad groups of society and more effective on aggregated data.) poverty alleviation were key factors. Several reviews of the literature (Furnée & This publication explores the poverty Pfann, 2010; Furnée et al., 2011) have argument directly by making use of the best suggested that income is clearly related to sources for comparative studies of poverty health and mortality but that there are mixed and mortality over a 25-year period. Because results for any independent effects of income the problem of small sample size occurs in inequality (Kondo et al., 2009; Lynch et al., most cross-national studies, this problem has 2004; Rowlingson, 2011; Wilkinson & been overcome somewhat by using multiple Pickett, 2006). Although income inequality waves of data for each country included. may or may not be a social determinant of

13 Poverty and mortality 1

This analysis adopts a social policy are poor (or “at risk of poverty”) if their perspective towards income inequalities and equivalized 2 disposable household income focuses on relative poverty to address the is below 60% of the national median. general issue of how income affects health. Although the poverty threshold (60%) One important reason for this is that reducing determines the proportion of poor households, poverty is an overarching goal for social the nature of poverty in terms of both income protection policies, which therefore often and its consequences become more severe target income protection during periods and more absolute as the income gets further of life or situations during which individuals’ away from the national median. This analysis ability to support themselves in the market used both a 60% and a 40% poverty cut-off, is limited (such as during childhood or which produce very similar results. The old age or when they are sick or unemployed). results presented below are based on the more Another reason is that relative poverty severe definition, where poverty is defined as rates are highly empirically correlated with 40% of the national median. measures of income inequality, and analysing Poverty rates are calculated from the one means also analysing the other. Luxembourg Income Study (LIS) waves The question then is how to define and around 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995, 2000 measure relative poverty. In the European and 2005, separately for children and for Union (EU) context, a commonly used adults. Age-standardized mortality rates definition of relative poverty is that individuals are calculated by using the Human Mortality

1 This section is based on a paper by Johan Fritzell, 2 Equivalized disposable income is the household’s total Olli Kangas, Jennie Bacchus Hertzman, Jenni Blomgren (after tax and transfers) income divided by an equivalent and Heikki Hiilamo and on: Fritzell J, Kangas O, Bacchus scale in which household members can be given different Hertzman J, Blomgren J, Hiilamo H. Cross-temporal weights. This procedure is used to account for the size national poverty and mortality rates among developed and composition of the household as well as economies countries. Amsterdam: Amsterdam Institute for Advanced of scale. The actual weights used in an equivalence Labour Studies; 2012 (GINI Discussion Paper 64); scale may differ; here the square root scale is used, and Fritzell J, Kangas O, Bacchus Hertzman J, which means that each household’s disposable income Blomgren J, Hiilamo H. Cross-temporal and cross-national is divided by the square root of the number of people poverty and mortality rates among developed countries. in the household. Although the choice of equivalence J Environ Public Health. 2013;2013:915490. scale can affect who is regarded as being relatively poor, it has less influence on the issue at stake here: changes over time and differences between countries (Fritzell & Ritakallio, 2010).

14 Database (see Annex 2). These calculations controlled for gross domestic product (GDP) use the direct method for age standardization per capita, data wave and social spending and the European standard population (see Annex 2). (http://www.euphix.org/object_document/ Mortality among children younger than o5338n27620.html). To allow for fiveyears exposure time on mortality after the poverty measurements and to get more stable results Fig. 3 presents bivariate scatterplots on (but avoiding overlap with subsequent relative poverty rates and mortality among poverty measurements), the adult mortality children younger than five years in the six rates are calculated as the average of the waves of data. Although the raw associations age-standardized mortality rates of the LIS are in the expected direction, that is, in all the year plus that of the three following years (in studied waves, relative poverty and child total four years). Logged mortality rates are mortality are positively related, they are used to normalize the skewed mortality data. not particularly strong. But to what extent is then relative poverty among children linked The method used is pooled cross-sectional to mortality when other factors have been time series analysis. The analysis also controlled for?

Fig. 3 Age-standardized mortality rates (deaths per 1000 person-years) among children younger than five years by child poverty rates, selected European countries, 1980–2005 Luxembourg Income Study wave 1=1980 wave 2=1985 wave 3=1990 wave 4=1995 wave 5=2000 wave 6=2005

1 2 3 4

3

2

1

0

4 5 6 4

3

2 Standardized mortality rates for children younger than 5 years 1

0 0 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20

Relative poverty rate; children (40%)

Graphs by wave

15 Table 1 presents stepwise regression models. by about one third across all models and The first model only controls for LIS wave for both sexes. The effects across all models (the trend variable). The coefficients for the are very similar for girls and boys, which association between poverty and mortality seems intuitively correct. The poverty estimate for girls and boys are highly significant. also remains essentially the same when girls The basic results do not change when GDP and boys are combined. The results from per capita is included (second model). Adding models with infant mortality as the dependent social spending to the third model erodes variable, instead of mortality of children a great deal of the poverty estimate, but it younger than five years, also give a very remains significant for both girls and boys. similar picture. It also shows that, the higher the share The coefficientof the association between of social spending as a percentage of GDP, poverty and logged mortality rates from the lower the mortality. model 2 can be interpreted as follows: an The statistical explanation for the strong increase in child poverty of one percentage attenuation of the poverty estimate when point corresponds to approximately a 2.2% social spending is added is the strong increase in child mortality among girls and, association between social spending and correspondingly, a 2.4% increase among poverty rates. Thus, the welfare state seems boys. Since the average age-standardized to influence relative poverty, and relative child mortality rates in these data were poverty influences child mortality. This main 1.46 deaths per 1000 person-years among rationale of the story remains relatively robust girls and 1.58 among boys, the lives of regardless of which countries are included more than three girls per 100 000 and close or excluded. However, the Russian Federation to four boys per 100 000 would be saved is special. When the Russian Federation is by reducing poverty by one percentage point. excluded, the poverty estimate is attenuated

Table 1 Logged age-standardized mortality of children younger than five years in relative poverty (40% below median income), girls and boys

Girls Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Coefficient P Coefficient P Coefficient P

Constant 0.85 <0.0001 1.05 <0.0001 1.34 <0.0001

Poverty 0.02 0.007 0.02 <0.0001 0.01 0.03

Wave –0.17 <0.0001 –0.14 <0.0001 –0.13 <0.0001

GDP (thousands of US dollars) –0.01 <0.0001 –0.01 <0.0001

Social spending –0.02 <0.0001

Boys Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Coefficient P Coefficient P Coefficient P

Constant 0.94 <0.0001 1.13 <0.0001 1.43 <0.0001

Poverty 0.03 0.001 0.02 <0.0001 0.01 0.03

Wave –0.19 <0.0001 –0.15 <0.0001 –0.15 <0.0001

GDP (thousands of US dollars) –0.01 <0.0001 –0.01 <0.0001

Social spending –0.02 <0.0001

16 Table 2 Logged age-standardized mortality of adults 25–65 years old in relative poverty (40% below median income), women and men

Women Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Coefficient P Coefficient P Coefficient P

Constant 1.14 <0.0001 1.39 <0.0001 1.55 <0.0001

Poverty 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.004 0.007 0.003

Wave –0.07 <0.0001 –0.04 <0.0001 –0.03 0.001

GDP (thousands of US dollars) –0.01 <0.0001 –0.01 <0.0001

Social spending –0.01 <0.0001

Men Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Coefficient P Coefficient P Coefficient P

Constant 1.90 <0.0001 2.30 <0.0001 2.53 <0.0001

Poverty 0.03 0.06 0.01 0.08 0.01 0.10

Wave –0.09 <0.0001 –0.03 0.002 –0.01 0.28

GDP (thousands of US dollars) –0.02 <0.0001 –0.02 <0.0001

Social spending –0.01 0.01

Adult mortality become nonsignificant.This effect can almost exclusively be attributed to the Adult poverty and mortality can be analysed Russian Federation. following the same logic as in the analysis of child mortality, with the results presented In summary, then, the relative poverty rates separately for women and men (Table 2). seem to influence the mortality of children younger than five years in the sampled Although the coefficients across all models countries and during the time period under are very similar for women and men, the scrutiny. It also seems perfectly plausible from coefficients for men are not significant using a life-course perspective that relative poverty standard levels of significance. Once again, more instantly affects child mortality than social spending erodes much of the poverty adult mortality. The mortality risks for adults effect. To test sensitivity, the analysis was are also affected by circumstances during rerun, this time excluding countries with earlier phases of life. The findings are in less than three waves of data (Estonia and accordance with earlier income inequality Slovakia) and the special cases of and mortality associations that have identified (China) and the Russian Federation. Excluding more consistent relationships between child these four countries, the poverty estimates mortality and inequality (Lynch et al., 2001).

17 Results and findings – social protection policies and health

As discussed above, a growing interest A systematic review by Muntaner et al. in the wider causes of the causes, or social (2011) found 75 studies of the relationship determinants of health, has fostered an between the welfare state and population interest in social policies and welfare states. health and health inequalities. They However, as cross-national comparisons identified four paradigms: welfare regimes of health inequalities show, there is no and democracy and the emerging themes simple one-to-one relationship between of political tradition and globalization. the type of welfare state and the magnitude Of these 75 studies, 31 address welfare of the inequalities. Nevertheless, evidence state and population health and/or health indicates that lower poverty rates and inequalities (p. 950), with the majority more generous welfare policies are linked (20) applying a regime approach (p. 952). to better health, which indicates the need For empirical results, the authors report for more in-depth studies of welfare policies that about 60% of the welfare regime and their consequences for health and studies found that social democratic regimes health inequalities. positively affect population health but that the association with health inequalities A growing body of literature addresses was more mixed (Muntaner et al., 2011, these issues in one way or another. Several p. 954): “... more than any other political systematic reviews of population health, theme, approximately a third of welfare health inequalities and welfare state state studies (11 studies, 35.5%) reported have been published. Beckfield & Krieger inconclusive and contradictory associations (2009) reviewed 45 studies addressing regarding its effect on reducing of social the relationship between determinants class inequalities in health”. of policy and health inequities. These fell into four categories: transition from command Brennenstuhl et al. (2012) also to capitalist economy, neoliberal restructuring synthesized available studies of welfare of economic regulations, welfare states and regimes, population health and health welfare regimes and the political incorporation inequalities. They identified 10 studies of subordinated groups (Beckfield & Krieger, of health inequalities. All focused on 2009, p. 155). The welfare state studies morbidity, mostly self-rated health and comprised about half of this literature. self-reported illness. The authors state Eleven of these studies (from Europe and (Brennenstuhl et al., 2012, p. 3): the United States) focused on welfare state “A second conclusion of our study is that policies outside the health domain. Five there is little support for the hypothesis that of these offered “suggestive” evidence that socioeconomic inequalities in health are strong welfare states and generous social smaller in social democratic regimes than policies can dampen health inequalities they are in other regime types.” They also (p. 157). The findings of the remaining concluded that a more focused approach, six were more mixed, or in the authors’ analysing policy content, is called for. own words (p. 167): “... within wealthy nations, the association between the type of welfare state and the magnitude of health inequities appears to be weak, especially for education-based inequity; ...”.

18 Social rights and self-rated health 3

Social policies should be addressed more Fig. 4 displays the cross-national bivariate directly than via welfare regime clusters. relationship between social rights and This requires using either data on legislated self-rated health, with the latter measured as social rights or data on social spending. a continuous variable (1–5, where 5 denotes Because both these approaches have their “very good” health). Country abbreviations strengths and weaknesses, both were used. in the graph are the Internet suffix of the Starting with social rights, family policy, respective country. There is an overall positive sickness, disability and unemployment but weak relationship between social rights benefits and minimum income protection and self-rated health (r = 0.55; P = 0.006). policies (social assistance) are the key social However, this relationship depends to some protection policies for adults.4 To construct degree on the difference between the welfare a single measure of the level of social rights, states in the western part of the European each of the above benefit-level indicators Region and the countries in the eastern part has been standardized according to the of the Region in levels of social rights and highest value. The analysis presented here subjective health. In fact, taken together, uses individual-level data from 23 countries 5 the relationship between social rights and from the EU statistics on income and living absolute levels of health appears to be conditions (EU-SILC) 2006. The analysis curvilinear. Trend lines including a quadratic is restricted to the core working age population term of social rights or the natural log of 25–54 years since the institutional measures social rights, reflecting diminishing marginal refer to benefits for the population of benefits of social rights on health, both display working age. better fit to the data.6 A stratified analysis, separating countries with low levels of social 3 This section is based on an unpublished paper by rights (countries in the eastern part of the Tommy Ferrarini, Kenneth Nelson and Ola Sjöberg. European region together with Greece, Spain, 4 Data on social rights in the form of state-legislated Portugal and Great Britain) from the welfare family policy, sickness and unemployment benefits states in the western part of the European are from the Social Citizenship Indicator Program (SCIP). For each of these programmes, the benefits Region, supports the notion that the effect of (for single people and families) after taxation are social rights on subjective health is curvilinear. calculated at the level of an average wage and then expressed as the ratio between the net benefit and the Fig. 4 after-tax wage. The data on disability benefits are from Social rights and self-rated health in selected European countries Palme et al. (2009) and coded with similar principles as in SCIP, assuming 100% work incapacity. Indicators Self-rated health on minimum income protection are from the Social 4.8 Assistance and Minimum Income Protection Database y = 0.965x + 3.575 2 (SaMip) (Nelson, 2007). Since minimum income 4.6 GR R = 0.305 benefits are not intended to provide income security y = 0.4611n(x) + 4.406 for losses in work income but are used to mitigate R2 = 0.347 4.4 IE low income and poverty, benefits are in this case FI AT standardized across countries by using Eurostat DK purchasing power parity. Information about countries 4.2 UK SW and programmes not covered by the above-mentioned FR databases has been collected and harmonized to allow BE NO 4 CZ NL cross-country comparisons using MISSOC (2010), ES SK the OECD Tax Database and national sources. IT 3.8 PL DE 5 SI Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, 2 EE HU y = –3.258x + 4.126x + 2.891 Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, R2 = 0.381 Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Netherlands, Norway, 3.6 PT Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden LT and the United Kingdom. 3.4 LV 6 The equation for the trend line with a quadratic term is: self-rated health = 2.89 + 4.13*(social rights) 3.2 – 3.26*(social rights)2; R² = 0.38, and the equation for the trend line with the natural log of social rights is: 3.0 self-rated health = 4.406 + 0.4615*ln(social rights), R² = 0.35. 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Social rights

19 The effect of social rights is strongly positive between income and ill health also at low levels of this variable but decreases probably reflects more fundamental and becomes weakly negative at the highest systems of social stratification in society, levels of social rights. such as social class, sex, education and ethnicity (Goldthorpe, 2010). Fig. 5–8 Two other health measures are also depict simple bivariate relationships available in the EU-SILC: first, the between self-rated health (measured respondent’s self-assessment of whether on a continuous scale) and social rights, he or she is hindered in the daily life by with the sample stratified according any ongoing physical or mental health to the following stratification dimensions: problem or illness and, second, whether socioeconomic position and education the respondent suffers from any chronic (primary versus tertiary education), sex (longstanding) illness or health condition. (men versus women), ethnicity (born in the No significant association emerges between country of the interview versus immigrants) the social rights index and these two health and labour market status (economically measures. The fact that social rights active versus unemployed). measured this way do not seem to be related to these other dimensions of health Fig. 5 indicates that, cross-nationally, the could indicate that variation in self-rated effect of social rights on self-rated health health across countries to some extent does not differ much according to sex: captures variation in other aspects of life, although men show slightly higher levels such as general well-being. Moreover, of self-rated health in all but three countries for the separate benefit programmes, the (Austria, Estonia and Finland), the positive association between health and social correlation between social rights and self-rated rights is most apparent in connection health across countries is of about the same with minimum income protection, which magnitude for both men and women. is probably related to the benefit-level measurement. Since the level of minimum Fig. 5 income benefits here is standardized across Self-rated health and social rights among men countries using purchasing power parity and women (PPP), cross-country variation on this Self-rated health dimension to some extent relates to the 4.8 level of economic development. Thus, some of the association between the level 4.6 GR of minimum income protection and health GR probably results from differences in GDP 4.4 y = 0.924x + 3.628 IE 2 IE FI DK across countries. However, although there R = 0.299 AT is less correlation between the other parts FI AT UK SW DK 4.2 BE of the social rights index (family benefits, UK FR NL SW NO sickness benefits, unemployment benefits FR NO ES BE 4.0 CZ NL and disability benefits), there is a clear SK CZ IT DE association between an index consisting PL ES SK IT SI DE of all the latter components (the social rights 3.8 SI EE PL HU y = 1.001x + 3.527 index minus minimum income protection) EE PT HU R2 = 0.304 and self-rated health. Thus, for a more LT 3.6 PT general outcome such as self-rated health, LT LV the totality of social protection and social LV 3.4 rights appears to matter rather than their Men specific components. Women 3.2 Line of best fit Although it is argued here that income (men) Line of best fit as such, through the effects of direct (women) 3.0 consumption, independently affects 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 individual health, much of the association Social rights

20 Fig. 7 Fig. 6, which depicts the cross-national Self-rated health and social rights among economically relationship between the level of social rights active people and unemployed people and self-rated health for respondents born Self-rated health inside and outside the EU, respectively, 4.8 indicates that the effect of social rights differs GR according to this background characteristic: 4.6 GR y = 1.039x + 3.575 R2 = 0.310 it appears to be stronger for those born IE inside the EU than for those born outside the 4.4 FI DK EU. The same basic pattern is also apparent AT UK when the sample is stratified according to BE 4.2 SW NO labour market status (Fig. 7) and education IE FR (Fig. 8): although the extent of social rights NL ES 4.0 clearly affects the subjective health of both UK CZ DK IT DE IT FR unemployed individuals and those with lower SK FI SW ES SI AT educational attainment across countries, 3.8 PL EE HU BE NO PL SK this effect appears to be even stronger for PT y = 0.577x + 3.501 SI 2 economically active respondents as well 3.6 CZ R = 0.098 LT as for respondents with tertiary education. PT NL LV HU DE Evaluation of the effects of social rights 3.4 EE Economically active in social subgroups shows that more extensive LT LV Unemployed social policies are linked to higher self-rated 3.2 Line of best fit health. These results remain robust when (economically active) Line of best fit other macro-level factors are introduced into (unemployed) 3.0 the analysis, such as national income, the 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 extent of public services, the shape of income Social rights

Fig. 6 Fig. 8 Self-rated health and social rights among native-born Self-rated health and social rights among people with people and respondents born outside the EU primary versus tertiary education Self-rated health Self-rated health 4.8 4.8 y = 0.8992x + 3.7535 GR R2 = 0.29122 4.6 GR 4.6 y = 0.989x + 3.574 IE GR 2 AT R = 0.319 GR FI 4.4 IE IE 4.4 SW DK FI AT DK UK BE FR NO FI SW 4.2 UK SK 4.2 CZ NL UK BE FR AT NO SK IE DK AT ES FI ES NL SI FR ES 4.0 PL SK IT 4.0 CZ SW CZ IT BE DK PT DE NO PT SW NO HU UK CZ DE SK FR BE HU IT NL DE EE ES NL 3.8 PL SI 3.8 LT EE IT PL EE DE PL y = 0.514x + 3.690 LT y = 0.644x + 3.6161 HU 2 2 R = 0.18793 PT R = 0.074 3.6 LV SI 3.6 LT PT LV LV SI EE 3.4 3.4 HU LT Native born Tertiary education LV Born outside the EU Primary education 3.2 Line of best fit 3.2 Line of best fit (native born) (tertiary education) Line of best fit Line of best fit (born outside the EU) (primary education) 3.0 3.0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 00.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Social rights Social rights

21 distributions, employment patterns and However, the social expenditure approach life expectancy as well as individual-level can also be theoretically justified with regard confounders. to the notion of command over resources discussed earlier. In terms of public health, However, findings also suggest that social welfare resources are associated with the rights in the form of generous cash transfer social determinants of health, such as power, systems are as important, or perhaps status, knowledge, work, income, social even more important, for the subjective networks and general living conditions health of highly educated Europeans with (Link & Pheland, 2010; Lundberg et al., stable employment as they are for citizens 2008a). Lundberg et al. (2008a, p. 63) in weaker socioeconomic positions. These argue: “Since poverty and income are often results indicate that social rights in the seen as crucial factors influencing health, form of cash transfers may be viewed as and since a general feature of welfare state a collective resource with important external programs is to create a buffer against income benefits: benefits to society over and above loss and to redistribute income both over those to the unemployed people who the life course and between individuals, directly use such transfers (Sjöberg, 2010). we obviously have one general path how Nevertheless, extensive social rights positively welfare states might affect population health.” affect health outcomes for all vulnerable Money is normally easily converted into socioeconomic groups. One conclusion from numerous health-enhancing resources. the analysis presented here is that a broader Income transfers may reduce susceptibility, range of institutional social rights indicators prevent or reduce exposure to health risks sometimes may better explain more general like poverty and positively influence the outcomes such as self-rated health than social consequences of disease and illness indicators of individual policies that capture (Lundberg et al. 2008a, pp. 15–17). social rights targeted at specific social risks or specific parts of the life cycle. Since economic resources strongly influence the ability of individuals and families to On the whole, the multilevel analysis carried lead good and healthy lives, the collective out in this empirical section supports the idea resources distributed by welfare state that higher degrees of social rights in a country institutions are crucially important for groups are related to improved self-rated health at and situations with insufficient individual the individual level. resources. Collective welfare resources – Social spending and health 7 in cash and in kind – may thus affect the An alternative approach is to use social distribution of ill health per se and the spending to identify the ambition and social consequences of ill health such as generosity of welfare states. A common non-employment. Government provision criticism of the use of spending data is of compensatory welfare resources is thus that they reflect a combination of legislated likely to result in better population health rights (the ambition of the welfare state) and smaller health inequalities and enhance and the needs in the population, such social integration and participation among as the proportion of older people or the disadvantaged groups. Since the social unemployment rate (Kangas & Palme, 2007). expenditure figures can be adjusted to need, For example, spending on unemployment such data can be seen as a good indicator benefits may increase during a recession, of the value of the collective resources even if the benefits become less generous provided by the welfare state. Hence, the (which is not unusual as expenditure resource perspective leads to the empirical increases). From this perspective, the expectation that generous and comprehensive social rights approach is preferable. welfare provisions give disadvantaged groups access to resources in cash and in kind in 7 This section is based on an unpublished paper a compensating way and that these resources by Espen Dahl and Kjetil van der Wel and on: will influence the social determinants of health Dahl E, van der Wel K. Educational inequalities in health in European welfare states: a social expenditure towards improving health, especially among approach. Soc Sci Med. 2013;81:60–9. people with fewer individual resources.

22 However, exactly what kinds of expenditure in thousands from OECD Annual Labour Force should be included and how expenditure Statistics) and the total population (population should best be expressed in comparative dataset). This expresses the proportion of the studies are not entirely clear. For this reason, population without income from the labour the present analysis used four ways of market that therefore needs state transfers operationalizing welfare resources in terms (or other kinds of provision). The justification of social spending. These four measures of for adjusting all expenditure data with the spending are intended to measure different dependency ratio is that social expenditure aspects of generosity: the economic resources per se is driven by both social rights and need provided for each individual by the state (Castles, 2004, p. 82; Gilbert, 2009, p. 361; and (for some measures) also by private Kangas & Palme, 2007, pp. 106–109). Since actors (Gilbert, 2009). The analysis first net spending as a proportion of GDP and net differentiated between gross public social spending per capita (in PPP) are likely to more expenditure and net total social spending. accurately capture the resources each person The former is the summed costs for a range in need actually has at his or her disposal, of public social protection programmes the presentation focuses on these two ways of (including those related to old age, survivors, reflecting social expenditure. The relationship disability, health, family, active labour between social spending and health is fairly market policies, unemployment and housing similar for all four measures. benefits); the latter also includes gross All models were estimated by random voluntary private expenditure, and the value intercept multilevel logistic regressions of tax breaks has been added and paid indirect separately for men and women. At the and direct taxes have been subtracted (Adema individual level, the focus is on education, & Ladaique, 2009). Both of these measures but age, country of birth, marital status, were then calculated as a percentage of GDP immigrant status and employment status and the value per capita in United States were entered as control variables. At the dollar purchasing power parity. country level, the social expenditure variable All four measures of social spending were also is included along with GDP per capita as adjusted for need, defined as the dependency a control variable. Of main interest are ratio for each country. The dependency the interaction terms between education ratio was calculated as the ratio between and social expenditure. all employed individuals (total employment

23 Fig. 9 women than for men. Women with secondary Associations between social expenditure and education enjoy the beneficial effect of social poor self-rated health by educational group for men and women expenditure on self-rated health, whereas The predicted probabilities have been estimated from men in this educational group do not. All four model 2, Table 3 in the paper by Dahl & van der Wel coefficients are nonsignificant. These findings for net total social expenditure (PPP). are robust for models with and without GDP and could also be identified in an alternative Predicted poor self-related health, men strategic test. 0.25 Fig. 9 presents the predicted probabilities of poor self-rated health for men and women 0.20 Primary for the interaction between net total social Secondary expenditure and education based on multilevel Tertiary 0.15 regression of individual data and national spending data. The figure shows that

0.10 combining the main effects and interaction effects of these analyses makes the group with primary education have lower predicted 0.05 probabilities of poor self-rated health when social expenditure increases. This, in turn, 0 results in reduced educational inequalities Minimum Maximum in self-rated health, with higher spending Net social expenditure on social protection for men and women alike. This also applies to the other three Predicted poor self-related health, women social expenditure measures. 0.25 For women, unlike men, all the slopes for secondary education differ significantly from 0.20 Primary the one for tertiary education. Because of the Secondary positive but nonsignificant main effects, the Tertiary 0.15 positive slopes, especially for women with the highest educational level, are highly uncertain.

0.10 The positive but nonsignificant main effect also contributes to a slightly increasing slope for those with secondary education. Hence, 0.05 firm conclusions regarding the changes in probabilities of poor self-rated health in 0 the secondary and tertiary educational groups Minimum Maximum with higher social expenditure are hard to Net social expenditure draw, although they are mostly negative for the secondary education group. What Results is clear, however, is that the outcomes are A clear pattern emerges in the effect more favourable for the group with primary modificationof educational effects by social education, both in relative and absolute terms, expenditure, particularly among those with in welfare states characterized by higher primary education and secondary education. spending on social protection, regardless For all four measures of social expenditure, of the measure of social spending. the likelihood of having poor self-rated health Fig. 10 and 11 further illustrate the fact in the group with primary education falls that the primary education group benefits as social expenditure rises. The effects are more from social spending by summarizing statistically significant for both men and relative and absolute health inequalities women, except for men, using the variable by education for men and women for all net total social expenditure as a percentage four social expenditure measures (gross and of GDP. In general, the effect is stronger for net expenditures, expressed as a percentage of GDP or PPP). Increased spending more

24 drastically reduces educational inequalities of poor self-rated health associated with for women than for men, both in absolute a one standard deviation increase from the and relative terms. mean. Net total social expenditure (PPP) has the strongest effects, with maximum Assessment of the comparative strength of the effect of –0.07 (men) and –0.06 (women) effect of each social expenditure variable on and marginal effect of 0.019 (men) and poor self-rated health in the primary education 0.016 (women). Compared with some of the group is facilitated by the maximum and most influential individual-level effects, these marginal effects calculated from the regression effects are far from trivial. Compared with models. The maximum effect reflects the the reference category (male, mean age, difference in the probability of poor self-rated non-immigrant, married, tertiary education, health between the highest and the lowest not employed), the effects of having primary observed value on the social expenditure education, immigrant status and being variable in question. The marginal effect unmarried were 0.08, 0.02, and 0.03, is the change in the predicted probability respectively (in predicted probabilities).

Fig. 10 Fig. 11 Relative inequalities in self-rated health by level Absolute inequalities in self-rated health by level of social expenditure, men and women of social expenditure, men and women GPSE: gross public social expenditure (% of GDP). GPSE: gross public social expenditure (% of GDP). GPSEPPP: gross public social expenditure (in PPP). GPSEPPP: gross public social expenditure (in PPP). NTSE: net total social expenditure (% of GDP). NTSE: net total social expenditure (% of GDP). NTSEPPP = net total social expenditure (in PPP). NTSEPPP = net total social expenditure (in PPP).

Relative inequalities in health, Absolute inequalities in health, primary versus tertiary, men primary versus tertiary, men 3.5 0.14 GPSE GPSE GPSE PPP 0.12 GPSE PPP 3.0 NTSE NTSE NTSE PPP 0.10 NTSE PPP

2.5 0.08

2.0 0.06 0.04 1.5 0.02

1.0 0 Minimum Maximum Minimum Maximum Net social expenditure Net social expenditure

Relative inequalities in health, Absolute inequalities in health, primary versus tertiary, women primary versus tertiary, women 4.0 0.12 GPSE GPSE 3.5 GPSE PPP 0.10 GPSE PPP NTSE NTSE NTSE PPP NTSE PPP 3.0 0.08

2.5 0.06

2.0 0.04

1.5 0.02

1.0 0 Minimum Maximum Minimum Maximum Net social expenditure Net social expenditure

25 Hence, for someone with primary education, GDP, social expenditure is associated with the reduction in the probability of poor health inequalities among both sexes but self-rated health associated with living in the somewhat more consistently for women most generous welfare state compared with than for men. People with low education the least generous one is almost equal to benefit more from high social transfers than the total effect of education at the individual those with secondary and tertiary education. level. For the other expenditure variables, In both absolute and relative terms, the maximum effects were smaller but educational inequalities in health decrease still equal to the effect of being unmarried as social spending rises. Different ways or having immigrant status. of operationalizing social spending, such as net versus gross and relative to GDP versus In conclusion, the analysis of 18 countries per capita, produce similar outcomes. in EU-SILC demonstrates that, net of Social policy and health among young people 8

From a life-course perspective, events and suggests that young people’s unemployment conditions earlier in life can strongly influence adversely affects both health and a range both living conditions and health later in of other outcomes that are correlated with life. Adolescence and early adulthood forms health – such as wages – many years later a formative period of great importance for (Bell & Blanchflower, 2009). Economic several key social determinants of health. support during times of unemployment This is the period in life when education and has been singled out as a key policy priority training is largely acquired and when entrance in this context, since such support can help into and establishment in the labour market unemployed people in sustaining their search should take place. There is a concern that for employment (Scarpetta et al., 2010). the transition into gainful employment, Moreover, high, and in many countries rising, and the social protection that follows from unemployment rates among young people that, is becoming increasingly difficult for mean that many confront at least the prospect large groups of young people across Europe. of unemployment at some stage in their lives. The health, and especially mental well-being, A large body of research provides evidence of young people is deteriorating relative to that job insecurity – the real or perceived fear other population groups in the European of becoming unemployed – is linked to many Union countries. Although mortality among adverse health outcomes, ranging from mental young people has declined over time, this distress, anxiety and depression to increased decline has been significantly smaller than mental and emotional exhaustion (Sjöberg, the decline among younger children (Viner 2010). Some even suggest that the literature et al., 2011). The current unemployment provides evidence of a causal link between crisis in many European countries has also job insecurity and well-being and that led commentators to call for urgent action causal mechanisms should be sought in the to minimize the possible scarring effects of the individual’s ability to control and plan his or current unemployment crisis on young people her life (Burchell 1994, 1999). An important and thus to avoid creating a lost generation reason why uncertainty about future (Scarpetta et al., 2010). Scarring effects unemployment affects people’s subjective means that the experience of unemployment well-being may be that it causes concern may increase future unemployment risks about financial security. Unemployment and/or may threaten future earning capacity, protection systems may alleviate the through a depreciation of human capital negative effects of job insecurity on the or through signalling effects (employers may subjective well-being of employed people interpret periods of unemployment as a signal by reducing concerns about future financial of low productivity). Thus, in addition to the security. However, although the importance fact that unemployed people are especially of a sense of economic security for the likely to report poor health, evidence mental well-being of both unemployed and 8 This section is based on an unpublished paper by Ola Sjöberg.

26 Table 3 Correlations between self-rated health and unemployment benefit generosity for older (30–54 years old) and younger (18–29 years old) respondents

All countries Countries included in all four waves

Aged 18–29 years Aged 30–54 years Aged 18–29 years Aged 30–54 years

2002 0.61** 0.68** 0.70** 0.69**

2004 0.53* 0.78** 0.63* 0.74**

2006 0.49* 0.74** 0.53* 0.77**

2008 0.32 0.69** 0.29 0.65**

*P < 0.05; **P < 0.01.

employed people has long been recognized of young respondents was 4.15 and among (Eisenberg & Lazarsfeld, 1938), the role older respondents (aged 30–54 years) it was of economic security as a moderator of the 3.92. In 2008, the corresponding figures effect of labour market insecurity on the health was 4.21 (young respondents) and 3.96 of young people has been absent from the (older respondents). literature (Ferrie et al., 2005). In 2002, unemployment benefit generosity Four waves (2002, 2004, 2006 and 2008) was strongly and highly significantly of the European Social Survey have been associated with self-rated health among used here to analyse possible links between both young and old respondents (Table 3). unemployment benefit generosity and However, whereas this association has self-assessed health and mental well-being remained strong and significant for older among young people (aged 18–29 years) respondents in all four waves of the European and whether such links have changed over Social Survey, it has weakened notably over time. Data are available for 20 countries time for younger respondents, especially (15 of them included in all four waves).9 between 2006 and 2008. This conclusion is valid regardless of which countries are The European Social Survey data indicate included in the analysis (all countries or only a clear age gradient in self-rated health: the 15 countries included in all four waves). young respondents report significantly better health than older respondents. This age If the analysis is restricted to changes between gradient has also been fairly constant over 2006 and 2008, changes in unemployment the years: in 2002, the self-rated health benefit generosity appear to explain at least some of the change in self-rated health 9 The four surveys of the ESS all contain questions on among young people between these two years self-rated health (“How is your health in general?”, (Fig. 12). Self-rated health tends to improve where the possible answers range from 1 to 5, and 5 denotes better health). In addition, the ESS survey from (or remain more or less constant) in countries 2006 contains questions on mental well-being according in which unemployment benefit generosity to the Center for Epidemiologic Studies Depression Scale increased and self-rated health tends to (Radloff, 1977). The Center for Epidemiologic Studies Depression Scale was constructed to identify populations worsen in countries in which unemployment at risk of developing depressive disorders, and benefit generosity fell between these two respondents were asked to indicate how often in the week years. However, there is clearly no one-to-one before the survey they felt or behaved in a certain way relationship between changes in these two (felt depressed, felt that everything was an effort, slept badly, felt lonely, felt sad, could not get going, enjoyed variables between 2006 and 2008. To take life or felt happy). These eight items were summed to an one example, Sweden and Denmark both index than can vary from 8 to 32, where higher values reduced the generosity of their unemployment indicate better mental well-being. Unemployment benefit generosity is measured by an additive index (ranging from benefits between 2006 and 2008 by roughly 0 to 4, with higher values denoting a more generous the same magnitude. But whereas average system) consisting of four indicators: replacement level; levels of self-rated health dropped among qualifying period (the number of weeks individuals have young people between these two years in to work to qualify for unemployment benefits); duration of benefits; and expenditure on unemployment benefits Sweden (–0.13), they were more or less per unemployed person.

27 constant in Denmark. This illustrates the risks Fig. 12 of overinterpreting findings in causal terms Change in the generosity of unemployment benefits and that the macro and micro relationships and self-rated health, EU-SILC, 2006 to 2008 involve many complex factors and processes. Change in self-related health The age gradient in self-rated mental well- 0.25 being is less apparent than for self-rated general health. On average, younger 0.20 y = 0.4027x + 0.0659 respondents report better mental well-being 2 0.15 R = 0.29345 than older respondents, but this difference

is small, and in about half the countries, 0.10 older respondents report better mental well-being than younger respondents. Among 0.05 those 18–29 years old, mainly women and those with primary education report relatively 0 –0.35 –0.30 –0.25 –0.20 –0.15 –0.10 0–0.05 0.05 0.10 0.15 low levels of mental well-being. Gender appears to interact with education as a factor, –0.05

since the reported mental well-being score –0.10 for women 18–29 years old with primary

education is 25.8 versus 26.5 for men. –0.15 However, this interaction is even stronger for older respondents: the self-reported mental –0.20 well-being score for women 30–54 years old with primary education is 25.2 versus –0.25 26.2 for men. Change in unemployment benefit generosity Self-reported mental well-being is also

strongly related to unemployment benefit Fig. 13 generosity (Fig. 13). However, adding Generosity of unemployment benefits and mental well-being a quadratic term improves the fit to the (Center for Epidemiologic Studies Depression Scale) data further, which indicates that the among respondents 18–29 years old, EU-SILC, 2006 relationship between unemployment benefit Subjective mental well-being generosity and mental well-being among (CES-D scale) young people might be curvilinear. Although 28.0 this relationship should be interpreted with y = –0.8418x2 + 6.759x + 13.673 2 some care – for example, the number of R = 0.66134 countries analysed is relatively small – it 27.5 nevertheless supports the general conclusions of the present report: countries that provide relatively low levels of economic support 27.0 during times of unemployment and that have lower average levels of mental well-being among young people can improve the health 26.5 status of young people by improving the economic safety net. In contrast, in countries that provide a relatively extensive economic 26.0 safety net for unemployment and that generally have lower levels of mental well- y = –0.3995x + 25.134 R2 = 0.3225 being among young people, such measures 25.5 should preferably be complemented by other measures to further improve the health of

young people. 25.0 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5 5.0 Unemployment benefit generosity

28 Conclusions and recommendations

The problem with health inequalities demonstrated that low poverty rates are linked is not the low mortality and the good health to universal, comprehensive and generous among more affluent and better educated social protection programmes. Although people but the poorer health and lower life combating poverty more effectively through expectancy among those with less educational targeted income redistribution might seem and economic resources. The problem with logical, universal programmes do a better job the different trends in mortality and life in terms of poverty alleviation. One reason for expectancy in various socioeconomic strata is this is that poverty is a graded phenomenon, not the improvement among the better off but and that an inherent feature of targeted the slower rate of improvement among those policies is that they require identifying poor who already lag behind in terms of health or needy people. This, in turn, will mean that and life expectancy (Shkolnikov et al., 2012; that programmes are means-tested with more Strand et al., 2010; Tarkiainen et al., 2011). limited population effects, marginal effects that cause poverty traps and higher control The differences in health and mortality costs. Another reason is that including broader across strata defined by their educational groups in society improves the standards and or economic level are caused in part by the quality of programmes and services, which resources used to describe health inequalities, benefits the poorest people. It also means that often the level of education and income of popular support for and willingness to pay the individuals and families. Although there are taxes needed for more generous programmes certainly several layers of intermediate factors is high across broad segments of the linking, for example, income with health, population, which adds to the sustainability increased income is likely to improve health of programmes. Taken together, this means and survival, albeit with diminishing returns. that universal programmes are best suited Although there are no easy solutions that to reducing poverty and increasing income will reduce health inequalities, improving security in broader segments of society. the economic resources of those with lower incomes is clearly one way to reduce As this report has demonstrated, the ability health inequalities by making more rapid of social protection policies to maintain improvement among those who are worse off. income and reduce poverty also extends to health and mortality. The unique analyses The question is, accordingly: what types presented in this report indicates that lower of policy are most effective in improving poverty is associated with lower mortality, economic resources among the poorer both among young children and adults. The segments of society? As illustrated in Fig. 1, amount of social spending, a crude indicator disposable income is affected by several of the generosity of social protection policy tools, including labour market policies, programmes, appears to influence this. welfare and social protection policies and, as a result, taxation policies. Although In more direct analysis of the health effects this publication has focused on income of needs-adjusted social spending and social maintenance and social protection, market entitlements in a broad set of programmes, incomes are essential for family incomes. this analysis has confirmed that more The ability of families to earn market incomes generous social protection systems are is in turn affected by several factors, including linked to better health across a wide range skills that are directly affected by education. of European countries. Although the analyses are rooted in different traditions and principles Nevertheless, educational and labour market regarding how best to capture the content policies are not the only important policy and ambitions of the welfare state, they responses. A large body of research has

29 produce remarkably similar results. It is not the past two decades or so (Kvist et al., only clear that the generosity or ambition 2012). For example, the social assistance of the welfare state, whether measured as and minimum income benefits have become needs-adjusted spending or the value of legal less generous and less adequate in alleviating entitlements, is positively associated with poverty in the Nordic countries since the health. More social security is actually better. early 1990s (Kuivalainen & Nelson, 2012). In addition, the collective resources provided This indicates that the levels of social by the welfare state benefit people with protection for the most vulnerable people low education more and therefore help to need to be reinstated, and hence that there reduce health inequalities. This is consistent is room for more spending on social protection with the idea that the collective resources even in countries that already spend the most. provided by the welfare state are more This becomes especially important since important to those who have fewer individual the results suggest that more ambitious social or family-generated resources. security programmes tend to benefit everyone and not only those who need the benefits. The relationship between spending and entitlements and health is also curvilinear, However, given the diminishing returns, with diminishing returns for health at high simply investing in more social protection levels of social spending and social rights. is probably not the only solution. Rather, this This suggests that the easiest gains can suggests that the existing social protection be made in the countries with the least policies should be improved. The research developed social protection systems. Even presented here, does not indicate specific small improvements in legislated social policies that need reforming; the whole rights and in social spending are likely to lead range of social protection policies analysed in to improved health, according to the findings this report could be reviewed in each country. here. Although the results generally indicate Such reviews could focus on the issue of that spending more on social protection whether policies are optimal in relation to will improve health and reduce inequalities, their primary goals (return to work, poverty they also suggest that this recommendation alleviation, educational credentials etc.) is especially relevant for countries with but should also consider the possible health the lowest levels of social spending in the effects of various policy solutions. WHO European Region. Hence, the research Although doing more and doing better are presented here clearly suggests that doing the main conclusions and recommendations, something in terms of social protection are there specific areas of social policy that policies is better than doing nothing, and should be in focus? In other words, what that even small increases in social spending policy changes should be made in which are likely to result in health gains. policy areas to reduce health inequalities? Nevertheless, if at least some social protection These are difficult questions, not only because would improve health and health inequalities this report has studied broad measures of in the less affluent countries in the European overall ambitions rather than specific policy Region, and the countries that already have areas but also because there is large variation some social protection would benefit from between countries. However, some earlier more, what about the countries that already studies suggest that more generous universal spend extensively? The growing inequalities policies, such as basic pensions (Norström in mortality in several affluent countries & Palme, 2010) can be important. In terms in the western part of the European Region of social investment, policies targeting resulting from less favourable mortality trends children, adolescents and their parents will in population groups with fewer resources be important. This research has focused suggest that the adequacy of existing social primarily on economic resources, and the protection may still be worth considering. To economic resources controlled by families some extent, at least in the Nordic countries, and individuals depend on many factors the redistributive and protective capacity of and policy areas other than social protection the welfare state has actually declined during policies. As illustrated in Fig. 1, policies

30 that affect employment and market incomes, provision, school policies and labour market including education and active labour market policies are all likely to be important policies, are vitally important. But social aspects of investment aimed at improving protection policies are also highly important, employment, economic resources and both for the groups that need economic health among young people across Europe. support at any given moment but also for all In this context, larger and more supportive those who can potentially benefit from various welfare states may not only influence types of social insurance. This is exemplified public health and inequalities in health in Fig. 7, where the positive correlation but may also be more socially inclusive between social rights and self-rated health in terms of higher labour force activity among is stronger among economically active people disadvantaged groups. New research evidence than among unemployed people. More supports the idea that large and active welfare generous social rights do seem to form an states are better endowed to employ groups important social infrastructure that benefits that are often considered hard to employ. whole societies. For example, van der Wel et al. (2011) found Nevertheless, the findings enable general that higher social spending and more active conclusions regarding priorities. One is that labour market policy were associated with social protection policies are important across higher employment rates among people the whole life-course. The level of ambition with a low level of education and who had or generosity of the welfare state as a whole limiting longstanding illness. This suggests rather than any single particular welfare policy that, in stronger welfare states, disadvantaged is crucial. Although it is important not to people are able to achieve better living oversimplify by solely relying on broad regime conditions through economic activity. A likely types, it is the welfare state in its entirety, macro effect is that such welfare states are and its collective resources, that influence more sustainable over time. the welfare resources and health chances One critical counterargument to these of individuals. This is likely to be true cross- conclusions and recommendations relates to sectionally as well as over the individual the Nordic countries. If larger, more generous life-course – the standards of pensions and welfare states that have more extensive social old-age care are important for the relatives rights and spend more on social protection of older people, who would otherwise have have better public health and fewer health to shoulder a heavier care load. Good pensions inequalities, why are there still substantial and care services available for older people and growing health inequalities in the Nordic reduce the informal care work family members countries? This is an important question, have to carry out. Further, the prospects and there does not seem to be any simple of good pensions and care services after answer. The findings here are based on retirement are also part of the social contract the variation in poverty, social rights and social for people of working age. From a longer-term spending across many European countries perspective, therefore, upgrading the whole and are not simply determined by the Nordic range of social protection policies appears countries. These results are also based on to be important. a variety of theoretical approaches, and the In the short term, investing in children and similarity in results indicates the robustness young adults appear to be most urgent. of the findings. The example of unemployment replacement Nevertheless, the Nordic question remains. rights and health among young people clearly Numerous factors shape health problems indicates this. Although well-functioning and health inequalities, and although some unemployment benefit systems are crucial of these are linked to economic resources both as security for people who are employed and welfare policies, others are not. Thus, and as a way to combat poverty among those the Nordic countries have traditionally been who are currently unemployed, other policies successful in alleviating poverty and income are probably even more important for children inequality – outcomes directly related and young adults. Family policies, childcare to the welfare state and social protection

31 policies – the further connection with health social protection policies, are important tools and health inequalities is much less direct. for tackling some key social determinants of For example, the north–south divide in health health and health inequalities in all countries. inequalities in Europe is largely associated Inequalities in welfare resources and health with cardiovascular disease, which in turn are attributable to a variety of factors, and is determined by numerous individual, existing inequalities in health would have cultural and historical factors outside the been much greater without the welfare states social protection system. In certain cases, of the Nordic and other European countries. key aspects of the Nordic welfare state Nevertheless, the development of welfare model, such as the high female labour force policies, welfare resources and health participation rate, may be associated with inequalities in the Nordic countries remains increased rather than decreased health a crucial issue for policy-making and inequalities through, among many things, research alike. higher smoking rates among women. A further counterargument is that the welfare Nevertheless, the Nordic welfare model state undermines productivity, efficiency referred to in these debates is not a static and economic growth. According to this view, construct. The regimes suggested by the larger the welfare state and the more Esping-Andersen (1990) are based on ambitious the social protection, the lower the situation in the mid-1980s. Many growth will be. The contention that there fundamental changes have taken place is a trade-off between efficiency and equality since then in all the Nordic countries. They is often used in this argument. However, are still more successful than most other recent empirical and historical research European countries at reducing poverty contradicts this assertion: large welfare states rates and income inequality, yet the latter do not appear to hamper economic growth has nevertheless risen in the Nordic countries and may, on the contrary, even increase also. The gaps between the welfare models economic wealth (Garfinkel et al., 2010; of the Nordic countries and those in the Lindert, 2004). Hence, social protection rest of the WHO European Region have clearly and welfare state policies should be viewed diminished over time (Kvist et al., 2012). as important investment that provides the social infrastructure necessary for high In conclusion, this implies that dismissing employment rates (Morel et al., 2012). ideas and findings about the importance By investing in social protection, governments of welfare state institutions is not particularly may therefore actually be able to improve fruitful merely because health inequalities health and well-being, reduce social and still exist in the Nordic countries. As this health inequalities, and thereby improve report has demonstrated, more generous and human capital and productivity. comprehensive welfare policies, including

32 References

Åberg Yngwe M, Lundberg O (2007). Castles FG (2004). The future of the welfare Assessing the contribution of relative state: crisis myths and crisis realities. Oxford: deprivation to income differences in health. Oxford University Press. In: Fritzell J, Lundberg O, editors. Health Dahl E, Fritzell J et al. (2006). Welfare state inequalities and welfare resources: continuity regimes and health inequalities. In: Siegrist J, and change in Sweden. Bristol: Policy Press. Marmot M, editors. Social inequalities in Adema W, Ladaique M (2009). How health. New evidence and policy implications. expensive is the welfare state? Gross and net Oxford: Oxford University Press. indicators in the OECD Social Expenditure Deaton A (2003). Health, inequality, and Database (SOCX). OECD Social, Employment economic development. J Econ Literature. and Migration Working Papers. Paris: 41:113–58. OECD Publishing. Ecob R, Davey Smith G (1999). Income and Antonovsky A (1979). Health, stress, and health: what is the nature of the relationship? coping. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Soc Sci Med. 48:693–705. Atkinson AB, Rainwater L et al. (1995). Eisenberg P, Lazarsfeld PF (1938). The Income distribution in OECD countries: psychological effects of unemployment. evidence from the Luxembourg Income Psychol Bull. 35:358–90. Study (LIS). Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Espelt A, Borrell C et al. (2008). Inequalities in health by social class dimensions in Beck N, Katz J (1995). What to do (and not European countries of different political to do) with time-series-cross-section data traditions. Int J Epidemiol. 37:1095–105. in comparative politics. Am Political Sci Rev. 89:634–47. Esping-Andersen G (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press. Beckfield J,Krieger N (2009). Epi + demos + cracy: linking political systems and priorities to Esser I, Palme J (2010). Do public pensions the magnitude of health inequities – evidence, matter for health and wellbeing among retired gaps, and a research agenda. Epidemiol Rev. persons? Basic and income security pensions 31:152–77. across 13 western European countries. Int J Soc Welfare. 19:S103–20. Bell DNF, Blanchflower DG (2009). What should be done about rising unemployment in Ferrarini T, Norström T (2010). Family policy, the UK? Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor economic development and infant mortality: (IZA Discussion Paper 4040). a longitudinal comparative analysis. Int J Soc Welfare. 19:S89–102. Brennenstuhl S, Quesnel-Vallée A et al. (2012). Welfare regimes, population Ferrie JE, Shipley MJ et al. (2005). health and health inequalities: a research Self-reported job insecurity and health in the synthesis. J Epidemiol Community Health. Whitehall II study: potential explanations of 66:397–409. the relationship. Soc Sci Med. 60:1593–602. Burchell B (1994). The effects of labor market Fritzell J, Ritakallio V-M (2010). Societal position, job insecurity, and unemployment on shifts and changed patterns of poverty. Int J psychological health. In: Gallie D, Marsh C, Soc Welfare. 19:S25–41. Vogler C, editors. Social change and the Fritzell J, Lennartsson C et al. (2007). Health experience of unemployment. Oxford: Oxford inequalities and welfare resources – findings University Press:188–212. and forecasts. In: Fritzell J, Lundberg O, Burchell BJ (1999). The unequal distribution editors. Health inequalities and welfare of job insecurity, 1966–86. Int Rev Appl Econ. resources: continuity and change in Sweden. 13:437–58. Bristol: Policy Press.

33 Fritzell J, Nermo M et al. (2004). The impact Kangas O (2010). One hundred years of of income: assessing the relationship between money, welfare and death: mortality, economic income and health in Sweden. Scand J Publ growth and the development of the welfare Health 32:6–16. state in 17 OECD countries 1900–2000. Int J Soc Welfare. 19:S42–59. Furnée CA, Pfann GA (2010). Individual vulnerability and the nurturing state: the case Kangas O, Palme J (2005). Coming late – of self-reported health and relative income. catching up: the formation of a “Nordic Soc Sci Med. 71:125–33. model”. In: Kangas O, Palme J, editors. Social policy and economic development Furnée CA, Groot W et al. (2011). Health in the Nordic countries. Houndsmills: and income: a meta-analysis to explore Palgrave/Macmillan:17–59. cross-country, gender and age differences. Eur J Publ Health. 21:775–80. Kangas O, Palme J (2007). Social rights, structural needs and social expenditure: Garfinkel I, Rainwater L et al. (2010). Wealth a comparative study of 18 OECD countries & welfare states. Is America a laggard or 1960–2000. In: Clasen J, Siegel N, editors. leader? Oxford: Oxford University Press. Investigating welfare state change: The Gilbert N (2009). The least generous “dependent variable problem” in comparative welfare state? A case of blind empiricism. analysis. Cheltenham; Edward Elgar. J Comparative Policy Anal Res Pract. Kittel, B. (1999). Sense and sensitivity in 11:355–67. pooled analysis of political data. Eur J Political Glennerster H, Bradshaw J et al. (2009). Res. 35:225–53. Reducing the risks to health: the role of social Kondo N, Sembajwe G et al. (2009). protection. Report of the Social Protection Income inequality, mortality, and self rated Task Group for the strategic review of health health: meta-analysis of multilevel studies. inequalities in England post 2010. CASE BMJ. 339:b4471. Report 139. London: London School of Economics and Political Science. Kreft I, De Leeuw J (1998). Introducing multilevel modelling. London: Sage. Goldthorpe JH (2010). Analysing social inequality: a critique of two recent Kuivalainen S, Nelson K (2012). Eroding contributions from economics and minimum income protection in the Nordic epidemiology. Eur Sociolog Rev. 26:731–44. countries? Reassessing the Nordic model of social assistance. In: Kvist J, Fritzell J, Hicks A (1994). Introduction to pooling. In: Hvinden B, Kangas O, editors. Changing Hicks A, Janoski T, editors. The comparative social equality. The Nordic welfare model in political economy of the welfare state. the 21st century. Bristol: Policy Press:69–88. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press:169–88. Kvist J, Fritzell J, Hvinden B, Kangas O, editors. (2012). Changing social equality. Hsiao C (1990). Analysing of panel data. The Nordic welfare model in the 21st century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bristol: Policy Press. Huber E, Stephens JD (2000). Partisan Lindert PH (2004). Growing public: social governance, women’s employment, spending and economic growth since the and the social democratic service state. eighteenth century. Cambridge: Cambridge Am Sociolog Rev. 65:323–42. University Press. Johansson S (1970). Om Link B, Pheland J (2010). Social conditions Levnadsnivåundersökningen [On the Level of as fundamental causes of health inequalities. Living Survey]. Stockholm: Allmänna förlaget. In: Bird CE, Conrad P, Fremont AM, Johansson, S. (1979). Mot en teori för social Timmermans S, editors. Handbook of medical rapportering [Towards a theory of social sociology. Nashville: Vanderbilt University reporting]. Stockholm: Swedish Institute for Press:3–16. Social Research.

34 Lundberg O (2008). Commentary: politics Nelson K (2007). Introducing SaMip: and public health – some conceptual the social assistance and minimum income considerations concerning welfare state protection interim dataset. Stockholm, characteristics and public health outcomes. Swedish Institute for Social Research Int J Epidemiol. 37:1105–8. (Scandinavian Working Papers in Economics). Lundberg O, Fritzell J et al. (2010). The Norström T, Palme J (2010). Public pension potential power of social policy programmes: institutions and old-age mortality in a income redistribution, economic resources comparative perspective. Int J Soc Welfare. and health. Int J Soc Welfare. 19:S2–13. 19:S121–30. Lundberg O, Åberg Yngwe M et al. (2008a). Palme J, Nelson K et al. (2009). European The Nordic experience: welfare states and social models, protection and inclusion. public health (NEWS). Health equity studies. Stockholm: Institute for Future Studies. Stockholm: CHESS. Radloff LS (1977). The CES-D Scale: Lundberg O, Åberg Yngwe M et al. (2008b). a self-report depression scale for research in The role of welfare state principles and the general population. Appl Psychol Meas. generosity in social policy programmes for 1:385–401. public health: an international comparative Rowlingson K (2011). Does inequality study. Lancet. 372:1633–40. cause health and social problems? York: Lynch J, Smith GD et al. (2004). Is income Joseph Rowntree Foundation. inequality a determinant of population health? Scarpetta S, Sonnet A et al. (2010). Rising 1. A systematic review. Milbank Q. 82:5–99. youth unemployment during the crisis: how Lynch J, Smith GD et al. (2001). Income to prevent negative long-term consequences inequality, the psychosocial environment, on a generation? Paris: OECD. and health: comparisons of wealthy nations. Schneider S, Müller W (2009). Measurement Lancet. 358:194–200. of education in EU-SILC – preliminary Mackenbach JP, Martikainen P et al. (2005). evaluation of measurement quality. The shape of the relationship between income Brussels: Equalsoc. and self-assessed health: an international Shkolnikov VM, Andreev EM et al. (2012). study. Int J Epidemiol. 34:286–93. Increasing absolute mortality disparities by Marmot M (2004). Social causes of social education in Finland, Norway and Sweden, inequalities in health. In: Anand S, Fabienne P, 1971–2000. J Epidemiol Community Health. Sen A, editors. Public health, ethics, and 66:372–8. equity. Oxford: Oxford University Press:37–61. Sjöberg O (2010). Social insurance as Marmot, M (2005). Social determinants of a collective resource: unemployment benefits, health inequalities. Lancet. 365:1099–104. job insecurity and subjective well-being in a comparative perspective. Soc Forces. Micklewright J (1994). The analysis of pooled 88:1281–304. cross-sectional data. In: Dale A, Richard B, editors. Analyzing social and political change: Strand BH, Groholt EK et al. (2010). a casebook of methods. London: Sage. Educational inequalities in mortality over four decades in Norway: prospective study Morel N, Palier B et al. (2012). Towards a of middle aged men and women followed social investment welfare state? Ideas, policies for cause specific mortality, 1960–2000. and challenges. Bristol: Policy Press. BMJ. 340:c654. Muntaner C, Borrell C et al. (2011). Politics, Tapia Granados JA (2010). Politics and health welfare regimes, and population health: in eight European countries: a comparative controversies and evidence. Sociol Health Illn. study of mortality decline under social 33:946–64. democracies and right-wing governments. Soc Sci Med. 71:841–50.

35 Tarkiainen L, Martikainen P et al. (2011). Wilkinson RG, Pickett KE (2006). Income Trends in life expectancy by income from inequality and population health: a review 1988 to 2007: decomposition by age and and explanation of the evidence. Soc Sci Med. cause of death. J Epidemiol Community 62:1768–84. Health. 66:573–8. Viner RM, Coffey C et al. (2011). 50-year van der Wel KA, Dahl E et al. (2011). Social mortality trends in children and young people: inequalities in “sickness”: European welfare a study of 50 low-income, middle-income, states and non-employment among the and high-income countries. Lancet. chronically ill. Soc Sci Med. 73:1608–17. 377:1162–74. Wilkinson R, Pickett K (2009). The spirit level: why more equal societies almost always do better. London: Allen Lane.

36 Annex 1 Work process

Thirteen topic and cross-cutting task groups The background papers have contributed worked to review the evidence on social to and informed some peer-reviewed determinants and the health divide in the academic publications, which are cited WHO European region. Each task group here in case of further interest. was led by a chair who appointed leading Fritzell J, Kangas O, Hertzman JB, experts in the field to his task group. Task Blomgren J, Hiilamo H. Cross-temporal and groups worked between 2010 and 2012 cross-national poverty and mortality rates independently, before reporting to the Review among developed countries. J Environ chair on their findings. Public Health. 2013;2013:915490. Five pieces of work were commissioned doi:10.1155/2013/915490 to cover the key issues identified by the Dahl E, van der Wel KA. Educational Technical Group. inequalities in health in European welfare 1 Dynamics of cross-national poverty and states: a social expenditure approach. mortality rates Soc Sci Med. 2013;81:60–69. Johan Fritzell, Olli Kangas, Jennie Bacchus Ferrarini T, Nelson K, Sjöberg O. Hertzman, Jenni Blomgren, Heikki Hiilamo Unemployment insurance and deteriorating 2 Health inequalities across Europe: self-rated health in 23 European countries. do welfare arrangements make a difference? J Epidemiol Community Health. Espen Dahl, Kjetil van der Wel 2014;68:657–662. doi:10.1136/jech- 2013-203721 3 Social rights and self-rated health in Europe Tommy Ferrarini, Kenneth Nelson, The work has been made possible because Ola Sjöberg of the extraordinary efforts of the Technical Group members and the other colleagues who 4 Self-rated health among youths in Europe contributed these pieces of high-quality work Ola Sjöberg in extremely short time to the Technical Group. 5 Social protection policy transition and its effect on children’s health and health inequalities in a liberal welfare state (New Zealand) Frank Pega, Kristie Carter

37 Annex 2 Methods

Poverty and mortality analysis

The two main data sources are the to about 2009 or 2010 (www.mortality.org). Luxembourg Income Study (LIS) and the Currently, the database includes information Human Mortality Database. LIS is a cross- for 37 countries, which are partly the same national harmonized database that includes and partly different than those in the LIS multiple waves of micro data for a number database. Our study includes all countries of countries. It focuses on income inequality from LIS that have at least two waves of data and poverty but also includes much from the same original survey source, and for information on such factors as family situation these countries, all LIS waves for which also and employment status. The first wave started mortality data were available in the HMD for around 1980 with five-year intervals so that the corresponding years. Further, we decided wave six of the data is around 2005 (for a to exclude Taiwan, China because of its thorough presentation of the database, see peculiar nature compared with other mostly Atkinson et al. (1995)). LIS is commonly non-Asian countries that were included. regarded as the best source for cross-national These principles led to a country sample comparisons of poverty and income inequality. of 25 countries with 2–6 waves, a total At the time of writing, the database included of 116 data points. The countries included data from 36 countries. The Human Mortality are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Database (HMD), maintained by the Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, University of California at Berkeley and the Germany, Hungary, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Max Planck Institute of Demographic Luxembourg, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Research, provides detailed open access the Russian Federation, Slovakia, Slovenia, mortality and population data for a number Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United of countries for years reaching from the 1800s Kingdom and the United States. Variables

The exposure of interest is then relative The poverty rates in each country and poverty rates, or at-risk-of-poverty rates each wave were calculated separately for as they are now called in EU language, two age bands: children (0–4 years old) for 25 countries from about 1980 to about and working-age adults (25–64 years old). 2005 (waves 1–6 of the Luxembourg Income Data on deaths and populations at risk Study). We use a standard income poverty were collected for 1-year age bands for each head-count measurement in which the country from the HMD for all LIS wave years individuals living in households with and for the three following years of each equivalent disposable income lower than wave. The rates were calculated separately 60% of the median income are regarded for each of the two age bands. Standardized as poor. Accordingly, we measure income rates were calculated to adjust for the different after taking into account welfare state age structures of the countries. In these transfers and taxes. To be able to compare calculations, we used the direct method households of different sizes, we use and the European standard population a standard one-parameter equivalence (http://www.euphix.org/object_document/ scale that simultaneously tries to manage o5338n27620.html). The standardized rates economies of scale and the fact that costs thus represent what the crude rates would increase so that each household’s disposable have been if the populations of the countries income is divided by the square root of had the same age distribution as the European the number of people in the household.

38 standard population. To allow for some social spending. We finally decided to use exposure time on mortality after the cross- GDP as an indicator of the general income sectional poverty measurement, we calculated level and wealth in the country. lagged mortality rates. Lagged standardized We also tested the impact of income mortality rates were calculated as the average inequality (as expressed by the Gini index). of the SMR of the LIS year and that of three After numerous experiments, we did not following years. use the Gini index as a variable in models; All analysis used LIS wave number to allow the issue is discussed later. for time-related changes in poverty and The data on social expenditure are from OECD mortality rates. The wave number is also databases and expressed as a percentage of an indicator variable pertaining to the more GDP. The measure includes both benefits in or less automatic change process that takes cash and in kind. In addition, administrative place in all countries. costs are included, but that is not a major Data on GDP per capita were derived from problem since these costs comprise 2–4% of Penn’s world tables (http:pwt.econ.upenn. all expenditure. An additional welfare state edu/php_site/pwt_index.php), which contain measure is a dummy for the welfare state information on the GDP per capita levels regime to which a country belongs. The for all the countries included in the analysis. classification follows the more or less standard The GDP levels are adjusted to the changes classifications: Nordic welfare state model in the cost of living across time and space (Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden); and are given in 2005 values. An additional continental European model (Austria, income variable used was the household Belgium, France, Germany, Luxembourg, the median disposable income provided by the Netherlands and Switzerland), the liberal LIS. These numbers were transformed into cluster (Australia, Canada, Ireland, United US dollars PPP by using the PPPs given Kingdom and United States); the southern in Penn’s world tables. Our initial hypothesis European regime (Italy, Portugal and Spain), was that the household disposable income the post-socialist block (Czech Republic, is a better indicator of families’ economic Estonia, Hungary, Poland, Russian Federation, standards than GDP, which is more a macro- Slovakia and Slovenia) and the category of level variable. However, analysis showed that other (Israel and Taiwan, China). In principle, the correlation between these two variables is it was also possible to use country dummies, high (r = 0.91), and in some cases the but in practice it was not a viable strategy household income variable was automatically given the high number of countries and the dropped away when regressing together with relatively small number of cross-sections. Methods

In the first part of the analysis, we inspected Stata statistical package. Several regression bivariate plots to see the general pattern techniques are available to deal with the of the relationship between mortality rates special problems of analysing pooled data, and the background variables. Thereafter Each has its weaknesses, and the results seem we proceeded to multivariate analysis to see to be highly sensitive to the specific method how the bivariate relationships will change applied (Beck & Katz, 1995; Hsiao, 1990; when other variables are included in the Huber & Stephens, 2000; Kittel, 1999). In regression models. For regression analysis, this study, it is neither necessary nor possible we used pooled cross-sectional time-series to go deeper into these methodological methods. These methods take advantage problems. By using cross-sectional analysis of the panel structure of the data while taking and combining this with pooled regression care of the correlations of data points between data, we simply want to shed some light waves using panel-corrected standard errors on the debate on the relationships between (Hicks, 1994; Hsiao, 1990; Micklewright, poverty, economic growth, the characteristics 1994). The analysis was conducted using the of the welfare state and mortality.

39 Models assuming and modelling the short-term changes (Huber & Stephens autocorrelation tended to produce larger 2000). To avoid this, we chose the approach standard error but, satisfactorily enough, described above. It seems reasonable to the levels of significance were robust. Pooled assume that it is the level of poverty rather regression was run using the STATA 12 than fluctuating yearly changes that affects cross-sectional time-series package using mortality. We assume that the magnitude Prais-Winsten regression. Here we tested two of poverty is lethal and not as much the possible ways to model the autocorrelation. annual fluctuation. The issue here is in which (1) The PSAR(1) model uses AR1 kind of circumstances people live or die and autocorrelation that is panel-specifically not as much how minor changes affect their calculated. The good side is that it is health. One can think that a child poverty tailored for each panel separately and the rate of 25% versus 10% percent rather flip side is that it may be unstable it there than a change in poverty from 10% to 15%. are few cross-sections. (2) The AR(1) However, to consider some of the fixed effects, model uses as the name indicates use AR1 we used dummies for the LIS wave and autocorrelation structure that is common welfare state regime. The underpinning idea for all panels. In order to further test in the welfare regime thinking is that, in their robustness of our results, we ran both the social policies, some countries, due to learning AR(1) and PSAR(1) models separately. from their closest neighbours and due to In practice, the results were robust for the other historical legacies, have a high degree different methods applied, and although of family resemblance, and consequently, the standard errors varied, the interpretations not only are the institutional set-ups of of the results did not. social policy but also the consequences, such as in terms of poverty, are similar in The other option was to use fixed-effect countries with the same welfare state regime regression models, but then we would have (Esping-Andersen, 1990; Kangas & Palme, lost the effect of the level variables and our 2005; Kvist et al., 2012). results would have been more dependent on Social rights analysis

The EU statistics on income and living activity by any ongoing physical or mental conditions (EU-SILC) was introduced to health problem, illness or disability (where improve the reliability and coverage of social “strongly limited” and “limited” = 1 and indicators in the EU, and the analysis in our “not limited” = 0); and (ii) whether the study is based on data from 2006. Health respondent has any chronic (longstanding) is indicated by the respondents’ own rating, illness or condition. Analysis is restricted to previously demonstrated to be a reliable the core working age population 25–54 years indicator of health status and frequently used old since our institutional measures refer in epidemiology. Analysis is mainly based on to benefits for the population of working age, the question “How is your health in general? except when we replicate the results from Would you say it is…”, where respondents Dahl & van der Wel (paper 2 commissioned for could choose between five categories ranging this report) when the population 18–85 years from “very bad” to “very good”. Analysis using old is analysed. this variable (recoded so that 5 = “very good Several individual-level characteristics health” and 1 = “very bad health”) can are also introduced as control variables in also be compared with the results using the multi-level analyses and for stratifying a dichotomized version (where “fair”, “good” the sample in analysis comparing subgroups. and “very good” = 1 and 0 otherwise) of this Following Dahl & van der Wel (2011), variable. Two other variables measuring other a three-level version of International Standard aspects of self-rated health are also used: Classification of Education (ISCED) 97 was (i) the respondent’s self-assessment of used in the analysis, where the educational whether he or she is hampered in the daily groups 0–2 (low, lower-secondary completed),

40 3–4 (medium, upper-secondary completed) and Minimum Income Protection Database and 5–6 (high, tertiary education completed) (SaMip) (Nelson, 2007). Since minimum are grouped into the respective categories: income benefits are not intended to provide primary, secondary and tertiary education. income security for losses in work income Economic status is based on reported but are used to mitigate low income and activity status in the income reference poverty, benefits are in this case standardized period (normally 12 months): if the number across countries by using Eurostat PPP. of months in full- or part-time work exceeds Information on countries and programmes not 6, the respondent is considered to be covered by the above-mentioned databases economically active; if the number of months have been collected and harmonized to in unemployment exceeds 6, the respondent allow cross-country comparisons using is considered to be unemployed; if the MISSOC (2010), the OECD Tax Database number of months in retirement exceeds 6, and national sources. the respondent is considered to be retired; To construct a single measure on the level and if the number of months in education of social rights, each benefit-level indicator or inactivity exceeds 6, the respondent above has been standardized according is considered to be inactive. Household type to the highest value. The level of social is divided into single households, couples rights is the mean value of the standardized living together with no children, couples living benefit levels for unemployment insurance, together with one or more children and lone sickness and disability benefits, family parents with one or more children. Country benefits and minimum income benefits. For of birth is divided into native-born, born in some countries, in particular those in central another EU country and born outside the EU. and eastern Europe and parts of southern Finally, the presence of economic problems Europe, incomplete coverage and uptake is based on respondent’s own assessment of benefits may distort the analysis and bias of the level of difficulty experienced by the the results (Palme et al., 2009). It has not household in making ends meet (where been possible to collect reliable comparable “with great difficulty” = 1 and 0 otherwise). information on benefit coverage and uptake The data on social rights refer to the covering all EU countries. We therefore situation in 2005 and are from several had to rely on other strategies, which involve different sources. The Social Citizenship weighting the social rights index above by per Indicator Program (SCIP) provides type-case capita adjusted social benefit expenditure.10 benefit level data on state-legislated family The rationale for doing this is that high benefit policy, sickness and unemployment benefits. levels together with high levels of benefit For each programme, the size of benefits coverage and uptake should result in high after taxation is calculated at the level of levels of per capita expenditure. High benefit an average wage for a single earner type-case levels combined with very low levels of per and a two-parent family with children. To capita expenditure are likely to be the result standardize indicators across countries, of insufficient benefit coverage or uptake. the benefit levels are expressed as net The multi-level analysis also uses a measure replacement rates: the ratio between the of the provision of public services (measured net benefit and the after-tax wage for each as provision of public services per head). type case. For unemployment and sickness Public services are here defined as benefits insurance, the average of two periods granted in the form of goods and services. of duration in receipt of benefits is used: 1 week and 26 weeks, while for the other 10 The social expenditure data are from Eurostat. benefits the yearly benefit rate is used. The Per capita social expenditure is an additive index that includes unemployment benefit expenditure per data on disability benefits are from Palme et unemployed person, benefit expenditure per inactive al. (2009) and coded with similar principles citizen due to sickness or disability and family benefit as in the SCIP, assuming 100% work expenditure per child younger than 14 years. Although incapacity. Indicators on minimum income the correlation between the weighted and unweighted social rights indices is very high (r = 0.86), the weighted protection are from the Social Assistance figures particularly reduce benefit levels in most of the countries in central and eastern Europe.

41 The classification of in-kind versus cash accommodation, assistance in carrying benefitsis based on the European system out daily tasks and rehabilitation. In family of integrated social protection statistics policy, benefits in kind consist of childcare, (ESSPROS) method. The most important in accommodation and home help. Related kind benefits are the following: in sickness to unemployment, benefits in kind consist and health care, in-kind benefits consist of mobility and resettlement, vocational mainly of inpatient health care (both direct training and placement services and job- provision and reimbursement), outpatient search assistance. Finally, in areas related health care and direct provision and to social exclusion benefits, in kind consists reimbursement of pharmaceutical products. mainly of accommodation and rehabilitation Benefits in kind related to disabilities are of alcohol and drug abusers. Social expenditure analysis

Analytical strategy and presentation All models were estimated by random intercept multilevel logistic regression: xtlogit The data are analysed by multilevel models in STATA version 9. (Kreft & De Leeuw, 1998), with individuals nested within countries. Multilevel modelling Dependent variable allows us to estimate the effects of individual The health outcome is self-perceived and contextual characteristics as well as health. It was measured by a question on cross-level interactions simultaneously on the self-rated (global) health. On a 1-to-5 scale, dependent variable, in this case individuals’ 4 (poor health) and 5 (very poor health) self-rated health. The main issue of the paper are coded 1 (poor self-rated health) and – whether and how welfare characteristics 0 otherwise. modify the association between social position and health – is essentially a question of Individual-level independent variables statistical interaction between a level I variable A three-level version of ISCED 97 was used (education) and a level II variable (spending): in the analysis, where the educational groups cross-level interaction. Hence, the method 0–2 (low, lower-secondary completed), chosen in this paper is to test interaction terms 3–4 (medium, upper-secondary completed) between education and our four measures and 5–6 (high, tertiary education completed) of welfare expenses in separate models. were grouped into the respective categories: It seems that this approach – which we see primary, secondary and tertiary education both as the most appropriate and powerful (Schneider, 2009). one, is rarely seen in comparative studies of welfare and health inequalities. Since our In addition, the following variables were attention is directed towards relative and entered in all models: age (25–80+ years), absolute inequalities, the results are presented marital status: married, unmarried, previously as graphs illustrating both kinds of inequalities married; country of birth: EU, other; as well as levels in terms of probabilities. employment status: employed, non-employed. The analysis was stratified by sex. We use the EU-SILC 2005 cross-sectional national surveys, which include 26 EU Contextual “welfare” variables countries as well as Norway and Iceland The four measures of spending are intended (Eurostat, 2008). Because of missing to measure different aspects of generosity: information on social spending, seven the economic resources provided for each countries had to be excluded from the present individual – standardizing for differences in analysis: Cyprus, Estonia, Hungary, Greece, need – by the state, and (for some measures) Latvia, Lithuania and Slovenia. Thus, this also by private actors (Gilbert, 2009). analysis encompasses 19 countries and Our empirical approach meets several of includes 133 226 women and 117 969 men the objections raised against the spending within the age span 25–80+ years of age. approach. As recommended by Gilbert (2009), we are controlling for “need”,

42 although imperfectly, and GDP. As Gilbert per capita in US dollar purchasing power (2009) argues, (potential) recipients’ welfare parities (GDPpc) given by NTSE above: depends on what they actually are paid: NTSEpc = GDPpc * NTSE/100. net benefits and not gross benefits. Thus, All four measures of social spending we compare social spending per GDP per were divided on “need”, or the countries’ population in need with welfare generosity dependency ratio. This dependency ratio as measured by PPP per capita divided was estimated by estimating the rate between by the population in need. all employed individuals (total employment Net transfer payments take account of in thousands from OECD Annual Labour Force taxes, tax expenditure and private welfare Statistics) and the total population (population expenditure (Gilbert, 2009). In particular, dataset). It expresses the proportion of the in a resource perspective, net transfer population not provided for by the labour payments may be more exact and to the market and that hence needs state transfer point than gross transfers. payments (and other kinds of provision). The motivation for dividing all expenditure The following four measures of resource data by the dependency ratio is that our allocation were obtained from the OECD measures of social expenditure are principally Social Expenditure Database (SOCX). indifferent to need (Castles, 2004; Gilbert, Gross public social expenditure as a 2009, p. 361). This often-overlooked property percentage of GDP (GPSE) of social expenditure data has led to an (Source: DELSA/ELSA/WDSEM, 2009), implicit assumption that the more, the better. Table A.3.1.a, page 84, data for 2005). Countries that spend a higher proportion of their GDP or more dollars per capita on Includes: old-age, survivors, incapacity, social welfare measures are leaders and those health, family, active labour market policies that do not are laggards (Gilbert, 2009, and unemployment, housing and other p. 361). Thus, the expenditure measure may social policy areas. simply reflect large shares of older people in Net total social spending as a percentage the population or widespread unemployment of GDP (NTSE) rather than the actual resources available to individuals in need. Making the social Estimated by OECD in the source above by expenditure data relative to the share of the firstestimating gross total social expenditure, population not provided for by the labour which is GPSE added to gross voluntary market obtains a more precise measure private expenditure. To obtain the NTSE of resource allocation within each country. measure, direct and indirect taxation had been subtracted from GTSE. As net spending divided by GDP and net per capita (PPP) are measures that are likely Gross public social expenditure per capita to more accurately capture the money or in US dollar purchasing power parities the resources each person in need actually (GPSEpc) has at his or her disposal, and hence express Following Gilbert (2009, Appendix 1), the amount of goods he or she can buy, we estimated these numbers by taking we might expect that these two versions the relevant percentage off of OECD’s GDP of social spending will more strongly affect per capita in US dollar purchasing power the distribution of health than the two parities (GDPpc) given by GPSE above: other measures. GPSEpc = GDPpc * GPSE/100. At the national level, GDP per capita (GDPpc) Net total social spending per capita in US was entered as a control variable to remove dollar purchasing power parities (NTSEpc) the effect of national differences in wealth. This was collected from Eurostat and centred Following Gilbert (2009, Appendix 1), on its mean. Also, GDPpc was divided by we estimated these numbers by taking 1000 to obtain regression coefficients with the relevant percentage off of OECD’s GDP readable decimals.

43 Analytical model Predicted probabilities: (P = 1/(1+EXP(–predicted logged odds)) For each sex, we estimated four equations, each including a separate and distinct The values of the four individual control measure of social expenditure (denoted soc. variables were kept constant. The graphs exp in the equation below). show the interaction between education, social spending and poor health for a person Logit(poor health)=B0+B1*edu+B2*controls of average age, who is born inside the +B3*GDPpc+B4*soc.exp + B5*(soc. EU, married and economically active. exp*edu) The advantage of calculating probabilities Where the “controls” were age, country is that it enables us to examine absolute of birth, marital status and employment levels and absolute inequalities as well as status. The coeffecient B5 for the interaction relative inequalities. term captures how social expenditure modifies the relationship between educational level and poor health. Thus, we graphed these interrelationships by using the formula:

44

The WHO Regional Office for Europe The World Health Organization (WHO) is a specialized agency of the created in 1948 with the primary responsibility for international health matters and public health. The WHO Regional Office for Europe is one of six regional offices throughout the world, each with its own programme geared to the particular health conditions of the countries it serves. Member States Albania Andorra Armenia Austria Azerbaijan Belarus Belgium Social protection, income Bosnia and Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia and health inequities Cyprus Czech Republic Denmark Estonia Final report of the Finland France Georgia Task Group on GDP, Taxes, Germany Greece Hungary Income and Welfare Iceland Ireland Review of social determinants of health and Israel Italy the health divide in the WHO European Region Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Malta Monaco Montenegro Netherlands Norway World Health Organization Poland Portugal Regional Office for Europe Republic of Moldova Romania UN City Russian Federation Marmorvej 51 San Marino DK-2100 Copenhagen ø Serbia Denmark Slovakia Slovenia Tel.: +45 45 33 70 00 Spain Sweden Fax: +45 45 33 70 01 Switzerland E-mail: [email protected] Tajikistan Website: www.euro.who.int The former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia Turkey Turkmenistan Ukraine United Kingdom Uzbekistan