Quick viewing(Text Mode)

Investor Attention in Financial Markets

Investor Attention in Financial Markets

Investor Attention in Financial Markets

2020 SAIF‐CAFR Financial Research Summer Camp

Zhi Da University of Notre Dame Caveats and logistics

 This is a VERY incomplete literature survey on investor attention  A partial collection of papers can be downloaded at https://www.nd.edu/~zda/PhD_Papers.rar  Check my website later this year for a survey paper with Wei Xiong and Lin Peng  Email me ([email protected]) if you are aware of other interesting related papers (including your own)  Format:  9:05 – 10:20: lecture  10:20 –10:35: Break  10:35 – 11:45: lecture  11:45 – 12:00: Q&A

2 Traditional Asset Pricing Models

Information

Trading

Price, , etc.

3 Traditional Asset Pricing Models

assume that information is incorporated into prices with lightning speed

4 The Role of Investor Attention

Information

Investor Attention

Trading

Price, volatility, etc.

5 Limited Investor Attention

Attention is a scarce Information cognitive resource (Kahneman, 1973)

“a wealth of information creates a poverty of attention and a need to allocate that attention efficiently among the overabundance of information sources that might consume it,” Herbert Simon, Nobel Laureate in Economics

6 Road Map

 Theoretical

 Measurement

 Empirical

 Future Research?

7 Theoretical Analysis

8 Conceptual framework

One can broadly divide attention effects into two large categories, motivated by Kahneman’s systems 1 and 2 thinking:

 Ex‐ante attention: deliberate attention under constraints  Focus of today

 Ex‐post attention: fast attention response to external triggers  Salience, Sensational news, Ostrich effect, etc…

9 Deliberate attention

 Rational Inattention  Representative agent is aware of her attention constraint and optimally allocates attention under the constraint  Merton (1987), Sims (2003), Peng (2005), Peng and Xiong (2006), Kacperczyk, van Nieuwerburgh and Veldkamp (2016)…

 “Neglective” Inattention  Inattentive investors are not aware of their attention constraints and do not learn from prices  Continuum of agents: prices are jointly determined by inattentive and fully attentive investors  Hirshleifer and Teoh (2003), Tetlock (2011), Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh (2011), Da, Gurun and Warachka (2014)…

10 Merton (1987, JF)

 Attention is costly and investors will not have perfect information on all at all time

 Extreme Attention Constraint: Investors include a to her portfolio only if she knows the stock

 Thus they hold “suboptimal” portfolios

11 Merton (1987, JF)

 Expected return is higher when  is higher  Idiosyncratic volatility is higher  Firm is larger  base is smaller

12 Attention and Entropy

 Sims (2003, JME)  Information reduces the uncertainty (entropy) associated with a random variable: H(X) = ‐E log[f(X)]  Investor inattention places an upper bound on the reduction in entropy

 Peng (2005, JFQA)  Investors learn about fundamental factors subject to the attention constraint as in Sims (2003)  Amount of information and asset prices are jointly determined in equilibrium

13 Peng and Xiong (2006, JFE)

 A representative investor solves two optimization problems each period: 1. Optimally allocate her limited attention to (1) market factor; (2) sector factors; (3) firm‐specific factors

attention reduces uncertainty

1. Based on the processed information, she then solves the standard consumption Bellman equation

14 Peng and Xiong (2006, JFE)

 Limited attention results in categorical learning  Investors allocate more attention to market‐ and sector‐level factors than to firm‐specific factors  In severely constrained cases, the investor allocates all attention to market‐ and sector‐level information and ignores all the firm‐specific data

 Limited attention could acerbate the impact of behavioral biases on asset prices  Excessive co‐movement

15 Kacperczyk, van Nieuwerburgh, Veldkamp (2016, Econometrica)  managers allocate attention to make profitable portfolio choices

 Their information choices are not observable

 Need a theory to link observable variable to information and portfolio choices

16 Model Setup

17 Time 1: Choose Attention Allocation

18 Equilibrium

19 Neglective Inattention  Inattentive investors are not aware of their constraints  Convenient toy model to motivate empirical studies

Consider a one‐period model. A stock pays a liquidating (d) at the end of the period, where d is a random variable with a variance of Var(d). For simplicity, we assume the stock has net zero supply and borrowing and lending rates are zero.

There are two types of agents in the market: rational or attentive investors (labelled as r) and constrained or limited attention investors (labelled as l). Limited attention investors account for a fraction m of the economy, while rational investors account the remaining 1‐m.

Both types of investors have the CARA utility over their end‐of‐period consumption: Ui(Ci) = Ei(Ci) –0.5γVar(Ci), i= r or l, where γ is the coefficient for risk‐aversion. They have different expectations of the dividend.

What’s the equilibrium stock price today? 20 Solution

Assume xi is the stock demand of investor i, i= r or l. The utility is therefore: xi [Ei(d)‐p] –0.5γVar(xid).

First‐order condition gives the optimal demand function as xi = [Ei(d)‐ p]/[Avar(d)].

Equating aggregate demand to aggregate supply (which is assumed to be zero) gives:

m[El(d)‐p]+(1‐m) [Er(d)‐p] = 0 =>

p = mEl(d) + (1‐m) Er(d)

In other words, the equilibrium price today is the weighted average of investors’ flow expectations.

21 Three Examples (I)

 Tetlock (2011, RFS)  S1 and S2 are two different signals in two periods  Investors with limited attention perceive kS1 + S2 as the new signal in the second period  Price reacts to stale news

 Da, Gurun, and Warachka (2014, RFS)  Frog‐in‐the‐pan (FIP) investors overlook small signals (|Si| < k) during the first period  A series of small changes attracts less attention and results in under‐reaction and price

22 Three Examples (II)

 Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh (2011, RAPS)  Two types of inattentive investors  Type I pays no attention  Type II pays attention to total earnings (e) only  Rational investor pays attention to components of earnings (e = a + c) as well: cash flow (c) and accrual (a)

 Type I investor  post‐earnings announcement drift

 Type II investor  over‐reaction to accruals

23 Measurement

24 Measuring investor attention

 Measuring attention empirically is tricky  Trading volume: Gervais, Kaniel, and Mingelgrin (2001); Barber and Odean (2008); Hou, Peng, and Xiong (2008)  Extreme returns: Barber and Odean (2008)  Up/down markets: Hou, Peng, and Xiong (2008)  Firms’ advertising expense: Grullon, Kanatas, and Weston (2004), Chemmanur and Yan (2009), Lou (2014)  The existence of news: Barber and Odean (2008)  Repeated news stories: Tetlock (2011)

 Turnover and returns are noisy and “catch‐all” proxies and news coverage and advertising expense capture the supply of attention or passive attention

25 Da, Engelberg, and Gao (2011, JF)

Google’s Search Volume Index (SVI)

26 Da, Engelberg, and Gao (2011, JF)

 Consider “AAPL” and “MSFT” (shown below)  We focus on innovations in SVI of each search term

27 Da, Engelberg, and Gao (2011)

 We show that our attention measure is capturing retail attention  Intuitively it should be individual, retail investors  Barber and Odean (2008) “… individual investors are more likely to buy rather than sell those stocks that catch their attention. … this is so because attention affects buying—where investors search across thousands of stocks— more than selling—where investors generally choose only from the few stocks that they own. While each investor does not buy every single stock that grabs his attention, individual investors are more likely to buy attention‐grabbing stocks than to sell them. (pg 786)” Increased retail attention  positive price pressure

Preferences determine choices after attention has determined the choice set 28 ASVI and Retail Trading Madoff NYSE/ARCH Comparison Δ Order Δ Turnover Δ Order Δ Turnover Δ Order Δ Turnover (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) ASVI (t-1, t) 0.264*** 0.297*** 0.0920*** 0.104*** 0.166*** 0.204*** (0.0317) (0.0355) (0.0105) (0.0132) (0.0218) (0.0256) ASVI X Madoff 0.109*** 0.0951** (0.0328) (0.0374) Madoff 0.000440 0.0223*** (0.00223) (0.00253) Log(Market Cap) (t-1) -0.0117*** -0.0122*** -0.00889*** -0.0129*** -0.00411*** -0.00841*** (0.00202) (0.00207) (0.000641) (0.000713) (0.00132) (0.00152) RET (t) 0.154*** 0.0772* 0.0999*** 0.00647 0.0418 -0.0875*** (0.0372) (0.0437) (0.0173) (0.0199) (0.0284) (0.0331) |RET(t)| 1.299*** 1.570*** 1.001*** 1.418*** 1.244*** 1.622*** (0.0528) (0.0622) (0.0271) (0.0338) (0.0405) (0.0493) Chunky News Dummy (t) 0.0658*** 0.0915*** 0.0936*** 0.125*** 0.0768*** 0.0991*** (0.00997) (0.0121) (0.00301) (0.00364) (0.00678) (0.00841) Advert. Expense / Sales (t) -0.104* -0.0954 0.00255 -0.0328*** -0.0713 -0.0568 (0.0630) (0.0642) (0.00643) (0.00636) (0.0610) (0.0658) Constant 0.255*** 0.251*** 0.175*** 0.229*** 0.0570* 0.119*** (0.0480) (0.0492) (0.0148) (0.0167) (0.0303) (0.0349) Control Variables YES YES YES YES YES YES Month Fixed Effect YES YES YES YES YES YES Observations 35,280 35,280 103,253 103,253 52,837 52,837 Number of Clusters (Stock) 1,358 1,358 2,743 2,743 962 962 29R2 0.131 0.127 0.299 0.291 0.173 0.191 ASVI and Price Pressure

Week 1 Week 2 Week 3 Week 4 Week 5-52 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) ASVI 18.742*** 14.904** 3.850 -1.608 -28.912 (7.000) (7.561) (6.284) (6.903) (17.162) Log Market Cap * ASVI -21.182*** -15.647** -4.710 4.290 16.834 (6.508) (6.768) (6.516) (6.398) (88.624) Log Market Cap 2.653 3.858 3.144 3.575 -39.229 (3.023) (3.160) (3.063) (3.186) (67.405) Percent Dash-5 Volume * ASVI 3.552** 1.904 1.687 -2.744 16.258 (1.639) (1.522) (1.612) (1.717) (23.822) Percent Dash-5 Volume 1.607 1.351 1.486 0.364 119.901*** (1.644) (1.652) (1.659) (1.711) (31.765) APSVI -2.532*** -1.379 -0.701 -0.704 2.286 (0.930) (0.990) (0.808) (0.639) (9.909) Absolute Abnormal Return 1.314 -2.389 -1.128 -0.463 -1.510 (1.879) (1.979) (1.563) (1.405) (28.505) Advertising Expense / Sales -4.012* -4.686** -3.959* -4.153* -162.210*** (2.237) (2.228) (2.172) (2.234) (52.414) Log(1 + # of analysts) -3.747** -4.547*** -3.961** -4.120** -173.875*** (1.548) (1.741) (1.769) (1.769) (29.683) Log(Chunky News Last Year) -5.157 -5.549* -4.349 -5.409 -14.999 (3.370) (3.272) (3.292) (3.558) (80.730) Chunky News Dummy 3.610* 1.378 -3.825 -0.058 32.466 (2.025) (2.424) (2.483) (1.910) (28.441) Abnormal Turnover 2.398** 2.309** 2.022 0.316 10.531 (1.204) (1.144) (1.404) (1.098) (10.109)

30 Observations per week 1499 1498 1497 1496 1414 R-Squared 0.0142 0.0119 0.0112 0.0111 0.0170 First‐day IPO Return

20.00%

18.00% Mean IPO First-day Return 16.98%

Median IPO First-day Return 16.00%

14.00%

12.00% 12.00% 10.90%

10.00%

8.00%

6.07% 6.00%

4.00%

2.00%

0.00% Low Pre-IPO ASVI High Pre-IPO ASVI

31 Post‐IPO Return [5w, 52w], High vs. Low ASVI

10.00% 7.55%

5.00%

1.39%

0.00%

-1.56%

-5.00%

-10.00%

Mean Size and B/M Portfolio Adj. Post-IPO Return -15.00%

Median Size and B/M Portfolio Adj. Post-IPO Return

-20.00% -19.51%

-25.00% High First-day IPO Return, Low Pre-IPO ASVI High First-day IPO Return, High Pre-IPO ASVI

32 Institutional vs. Retail Attention?

 Attention Allocation  Institutional attention: deliberate, proactive, endogenously determined  Retail attention: fast, reactive, triggered by salient events and media coverage

 Asset Pricing  Institutional attention: Immediate, permanent price impact  Retail attention: Delayed, positive and temporary price pressure (Barber and Odean, 2008)

33 Institutional Attention

Ben‐Rephael, Da, and Israelsen (2017) examine abnormal institutional attention (AIA) using ticker search on 34 Bloomberg “WWE” EXAMPLE: ABNORMAL INSTITUTIONAL ATTENTION & NEWS

Earnings AnalystAnnouncements Recommendation Changes

News about Executives

News about Litigation

News about Competitors

Other News

35 Post‐earnings‐announcement drift Only when institutional investors fail to pay attention

36 Fedyk (2018): Front page News on Bloomberg

FP

NFP

37 Fedyk (2018)

 Establish causality using random front‐page news positioning on the Bloomberg terminals  Front Page News vs. Non Front Page News: High vs. Low attention

More attention  more trading More attention  faster price adjustment

38 Financial Attention

 Sicherman, Loewenstein, Seppi, and Utkus (RFS, 2015)  Use daily investor online account logins to measure financial attention  Strong ostrich effect: more logins in up market than in down markets, more so for males and for wealthy investors  High VIX  less logins; More media coverage  more logins

39 Online Brokerage Account Activities

 Gargano and Rossi (RFS, 2018)  New brokerage account dataset covering 10,000 random selected accounts over 2013/01 ~ 2014/06  Access to their entire online activity on the trading platform

 Different types of attention  Overall attention  Categorical attention (Balance and Positions; Research; Trading…)  Stock attention (time spent on each ticker)

 Differentiate deliberate vs. fast attention

40 41 Click Data: Attention to Specific News  Benamar, Foucault, and Vega (2020, RFS)  Use Bitly data on clicks by individuals on news articles URL: https://blogs.wsj.com/economics/2016/01/07/why-december- private-payrolls-arent-a-great-predictor-of-the-jobs-report/  SURL created using Bitly is: http://on.wsj.com/2oJQ2py

 Write down a model of endogenous attention allocation where more attention is allocated to more uncertain events  # clicks before an event is therefore a measure of uncertainty associated with that event  Predicts stronger announcement effect

42 Attention to Macro Announcements

43 Big data allow us to measure attention more directly and more precisely

44 Empirical Evidence

45 Outline

 Anecdotal Evidence

 Asset pricing  Limited attention to different types of information

 Corporate and others

 Identification

46 MCI‐MCIC  Massively Confused Investors Making Conspicuously Ignorant Choices (Rashes, 2001)  MCI is an NYSE‐listed closed‐end fund. MCIC is MCI Communications  When MCI Communications was in acquisition talks with WorldCom, these two securities had very similar trading patterns  Excessive price co‐movement during 94‐97

47 More recent example

Shares of Tweeter Home Entertainment Group surged briefly after investors apparently confused the stock for that of Twitter. Its ticker now changed from “TWTRQ” to “THEGQ” 48 The wrong Hathaway?

But students in theory class at KU found the news coverage of Anne Hathaway is highly correlated with the trading volume in Berkshire Hathaway’s stock

49 Time‐varying attention constraint

 Corwin and Coughenour (2008, JF)  NYSE specialists allocate effort toward their most active stocks during periods of increased activity, resulting in less frequent price improvement and increased transaction costs for their remaining assigned stocks

 Identification: distraction due to MSFT is plausible exogenous (negative) attention shock to F

50 A Piece of NYSE History at Mendoza

51 Time‐varying attention constraint

 Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh (2009, JF)  Investor distraction hypothesis: More post‐earnings announcement drift following days with more announcements

 DellaVigna and Pollet (2009, JF)  More post‐earnings announcement drift following Friday announcement

52 Limited attention to ‐term information

 DellaVigna and Pollet (2007, AER)  Demographic shocks today lead to predictable shifts in consumption and industry profitability in 5 to 10 years  Investors have limited attention to information beyond 5 years, resulting in return predictability

53 DellaVigna and Pollet (2007, AER) Future population can be accurately predicted

54 DellaVigna and Pollet (2007, AER) Demographic change affects future industry CF in a highly predictable way

55 DellaVigna and Pollet (2007, AER) But investor limited attention may cause a delayed price adjustment

56 Limited attention to long‐term information

 Da and Warachka (2009, JFE)  Equity analysts issue both ‐term and long‐term earnings forecasts  Investors pay more attention to the short‐term forecasts than to the short‐term forecasts  Disparity in the forecasts predicts future return

57 Da and Warachka (2009, JFE)

Disparity LTG and ISTG reflects limited attention to long‐term implication of information

58 Limited attention to economic links

 Cohen and Frazzini (2008)

Supplier’s stock price reacts to shocks to its customer with a delay

59 Cohen and Frazzini (2008)

60  Cohen and Frazzini (2008)

61 Limited attention to stale information

 Tetlock (2011, RFS)  “People everywhere confuse what they read in the newspaper with news.” –A. J. Liebling  Identify stale news using textual similarity measure  Price reacts to stale news immediately, followed by reversal

 Gilbert et. al. (2012, MS)  The US Leading Economic Index (LEI) is a summary statistic of previously released inputs  Yet investors react to its announcement  Smart front runs

62 Limited attention to continuous information

 Da, Gurun, and Warachka (2014, RFS)

63 64 65

 Kempf, Manconi, and Spalt (RFS, 2016)  “Distracted” make “worse” corporate decisions  Diversifying, ‐destrorying acquisition  Cut  Less likely to fire bad‐performing CEOs

 Causality  Use exogenous shocks to unrelated parts (e.g. different industry) of institutional shareholders’ portfolio

66 Identification

67 68 Merger & Acqusition

 Lie (JFQA, 2019)  In certain acquisitions, target shareholders can choose to receive either cash or acquirer shares  Ecolab acquisition of Nalco in 2011: “Nalco stockholders may elect to receive either 0.7005 shares of Ecolab or $38.80 in cash, without interest, per share of Nalco common stock.”

 Define Value wedge as log(stock value / cash value)  Ignore taxes, take stock if Value wedge>0; otherwise take cash

69 Payment Choices

100%

10% partially inattentive

0% -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 Value wedge

Fraction stock Fraction cash

70 No Election

30%

7% inattentive

0% -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 Value wedge

71 Insider Trading

 Alldredge and Cicero (JFE, 2015)  Insider trading may come from insiders pay close attention to public info when outside investors are relatively inattentive  Setting: supplier insider trade on public info on customers  Extending Cohen and Frazzini (2008) to insider trading

72 IPO

 Bajo, Chemmanur, Simonyan, and Tehranian ( JFE, 2016)

 Lead underwriters who are central in the network of investment bankers are better in attracting investor attention to the IPOs  More attention  more information extraction  better IPOs

73 Center of Attention

74 CEO Equity Vesting

 Edmans, Goncalves‐Pinto, Groen‐Xu, and Wang (2018, RFS)  CEOs regular sell stocks after they are vested  They strategically release 20% more news (not always positive) during scheduled vesting months  Why?  Identification issues? Corr(sales, news release)>0

75 2SLS

76 77 Causal Evidence in the Existing Literature

 Distraction by unrelated shocks  Multiple earnings announcements on the same day: Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh (2009, JF)  Earnings announcements on Fridays: DellaVigna and Pollet (2009, JF)  NYSE specialist making market on multiple stocks: Corwin and Coughenour (2008, JF), Schmit (2019)  Distracted shareholder: Kempf, Manconi, and Spalt (2016, RFS)  Competing special news on TV: Liu, Sherman, and Zhang (2014, MS), Peress and Schmit (2019, JF)

78 Causal Evidence in the Existing Literature

 Distraction by unrelated shocks  Shocks in the family (marriage / divorce / parental loss): Lu, Ray and Teo (JFE, 2016), and Shu, Sulaeman and Yeung (2017)

79 Causal Evidence in the Existing Literature

 Exogenous events  Weather shocks: Engelberg and Parsons (2011, JF), Gargano and Rossi (2018, RFS)  Newspaper strike: Peress (2014, JF)  College football Bowl games: Mayer (2018)

80 Causal Evidence in the Existing Literature

 Positioning / salience of information  Discontinuity around WSJ “Category Kings” ranking: Kaniel and Parham (2017, JFE)

 Record‐setting days in Dow () but not in S&P500 (NYSE Composite) : Yuan (JFE, 2015)  Stock ranking variation due to rounding: Wang (2017, WP)

81 Three elements of an interesting attention paper

 New application  Make sure it has not been done before

 Identification: Pin down causality  (in)attention  outcomes

 Ex‐ante surprising results  It usually is not enough to just document that investors did not pay attention  What are some unexpected consequences of their inattention?

82 Conclusion  Investors are likely to have limited attention

 Limited investor attention affects outcomes both theoretically and empirically

 Measuring attention and pinning down causality are challenging tasks

83