The Extent and Nature of Parliamentary Enclosure

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Extent and Nature of Parliamentary Enclosure The Extent and Nature of Parliamentary Enclosure By JOHN CHAPMAN N SPITE of the recent advances in our suffering from the same problems as the knowledge of the Parliamentary enclos- 'Domesday'. I ure movement, notably through the With regard to the breakdown into types work of Dr Michael Turner, ~ the details of of land affected, the situation is far worse. precisely what land was affected remain The act estimates are quite useless from this somewhat obscure. Turner's edition of point of view, since only a tiny handful give Tate's 'Domesday' offers figures for most of this type of detail, and the summaries given the English enclosures 2 but, quite apart from in the awards are only marginally better. those where no figure is given, many are Though there are now a number of major based on the act and award estimates, which studies available of some individual coun- can be wildly inaccurate. This has been ties, or substantial parts of them, these are demonstrated in detail elsewhere for North- neither numerous enough, nor necessarily ern England,3 but is by no means restricted calculated on a sufficiently comparable basis, to the remote uplands, as might be assumed. to give any overall picture of the movement Substantial errors occur in Sussex, 4 and an as a whole. ~ examination of some Leicestershire material produced surprising errors even there. Comparison of the sums of the allotments I with the award estimates given in Turner for This paper seeks to remedy some of these sixteen awards revealed that although eleven problems by presenting the results of a fell within 2 per cent the remaining four were national survey of the Parliamentary enclos- all over I 4 per cent out, rising to 23.5 per cent ure awards, v The data were collected from a at Congerstone. Strangely, in the two worst Io per cent sample of all English and Welsh cases the act estimates were far closer to the awards, full details of every individual true figure. A similar exercise on eleven allotment being abstracted for each selected Kesteven awards found eight without any award. 8 In view of the known and suspected award figure; one, Eagle, completely variations in enclosure awards in different accurate; and two over 2o per cent out. The parts of the country, 9 a simple unrestricted situation with regard to Wales is still worse, random sample was statistically unaccept- for the only list covering the whole country, able, since there was a substantial danger of that ofBowen, 5 is incomplete, in addition to drawing, for example, a disproportionate ' M Turner, English Parliamentary Enclosure, Folkestone, 198o, and (' For example, the recent work of E and R C Russell, LaMscape Enclosures in Britain 175o--183o, 1984. Changes in South Humberside: The Endosures of Thirty-Seven Parishes, : W E Tate, A Domesday of Ene.lish Enclosure Acts and Awards, M E Hull, x982, and Old and New Landscapes in the Horncastle Area, Turner, editor, P,eading, 1978. Lincoln, t985. •~ J Chapman andTM Harris, 'The Accuracy of Enclosure Estimates: v Subsequent to the unions of tile respective Parliaments with tile Some Evidence from Northern England', jolm;al of Historical English one, there appear to have been one enclosure for Scotland Geoqraphy, 8, 1982, pp 261-264. and ten for Ireland. These have been omitted. 4j Chapman, 'Some Problems in tile Interpretation of Enclosure l am grateful to the ESRC, then the SSRC, for their financial Awards', Ag Hist Rev, 26, 1978, pp l 1 I-I 12. assistance for this work, and to Dr T M Harris, then my research l Bowen, The Great Enclosures qfCommon Lands hi Wah,s, Chiswick, assistant, for his invaluable help on the project. 1914. ') Turner, English Parliamentary Enclosure, pp 32-62. 26 THE AGRICULTURAL HISTORY REVIEW Distribution of sample enclosures pre-174g × 1750-1769 + 1770-1789 X 1790-1809 OO ~ x 1810-1829 ,~1830-1849 ~7 O x + O 1850-1869 oo L * 1870 onwards ' O~ ,[3 in <)x Xx +x O q x o + [] + +0 x u +x+ ,,~ +x+ :¢o+ XxxgV ~ V+ x :.~ += # ,<o÷ x x x <)'t/X~x + / x V x x F x. ~ ~ x=~ ~+,x x ~ ~xX.~'~ / / ~ ~' + × u, -,.. +d~, x = =-@#o~< ~o 'o o f /- + "-~ _+++ ,..¢, #., ox ,,u a 0 _ o o oX+E] x~X~+x~x~"£, o x+ oO ~ .~" BD C~ + + x OD [] XoX~<~''" ~~ x x x x [] o .J l-..- v.. rn u 0 xo o_~> x 0 ..J I xX===x [] ~ _2Xx 0 '~.- u-_..'_ 0 C~Lx °0 . / o ~ o~ ' 80 kil0metres FIGURE I THE EXTENT AND NATURE OF PARLIAMENTARY ENCLOSURE 27 number of large northern enclosures, or of for England, or a grand total ofjust over 8.85 Midland open field ones. The sample was million acres for the whole Parliamentary therefore drawn separately from each enclosure movement. In practice these county, or, in the Welsh case, group of figures must be regarded as representing an adjacent counties, thus producing a regional upper limit, for doubts must be expressed stratification, and ensuring that each region about the validity of some of the enclosures was proportionately correctly represented in making up the grand total. If the proportion the whole. (See Fig I.) of spurious enclosures discovered in the The definition of an 'enclosure' which was sample were to be matched in the overall used was that adopted originally by Tate, ,o total for England, some seventy awards multiple awards under a single act being would be rejected, giving a projected total of regarded as part of the same enclosure. A 7.57 million acres. The Welsh figures would number of awards examined proved not to be unaffected since almost all Welsh awards fall within the normal definition of enclos- were examined and the total contains only ure, for example because they consisted those meeting acceptable criteria. The same entirely of exchanges of already enclosed is also true of several English counties, so land" or because they were simply regula- that although a figure of 8.75 million acres tory, ,2 and these were replaced by reserves, might be taken as the lower limit of the range as were any awards which were lost or too it seems likely that the true figure would lie defective to be usable. closer to the upper limit of 8.85 million. The adjusted totals of enclosures proved It must be noted that these figures refer to to be 5570, 5341 in England and 229 in Wales. the total land affected by enclosure, and as Owing to the effects of rounding in such do not equate exactly with the total individual counties, the sample consisted of amount of open or common land abolished 559 awards, 535 from England and 24 from by the process. It was a frequent practice at Wales. As this involved a slight over- enclosure for landowners to exchange small representation of Wales, and subsequent patches of old enclosed land for the new analysis demonstrated a number of signifi- allotments in order to eliminate awkward cant differences between English and Welsh detached pieces of their estates, and pro- enclosures, most calculations were per- vision for this was normally included in the formed separately for the two countries acts. Some acts, however, went further, and before figures were amalgamated to specified that all detached fields of less than a produce grand totals. This had the added particular size, usually three acres, should be advantage of permitting comparisons with thrown into the melting pot, ,3 while others existing published figures, which normally similarly incorporated any land within the refer to one or other country individually. same fence which was owned by more than In total, the sample awards affected one owner. ,4 Though the acreage involved 892,o89.25 acres of land, including old was usually small, it was by no means enclosures exchanged or reallocated. negligible, and cases involving larger areas 768,449.95 acres lay in England and are not rare. ,s In consequence, the total land 123,639.3o in Wales. Taken at face value, allotted by the awards exceeds the amount these would imply totals of approximately theoretically available for enclosure. Dis- I. 18 million acres for Wales and 7.67 million '~ e.g. Llangybi, Monmouthshire. Gwent County Record Office, Enc t. '° See, for example, W E Tate, 'A Handlist of Sus:lex Enclosure ,4 e.g. Bosham and Funtington, Sussex. West Sussex County Acts and Awards', East and West Sussex County Councils, Record Office, Rm 3 DC7; Broadwater, Sussex, PRO Record Publication, ,, 195o. CP43/9t ,. " e.g. Evington, Leicestershire; and Carisbrooke and Godshill, ,s e.g. Romsey Extra, Hampshire. Hampshire County Record Isle of Wight. Office, Enc 89; Bury, Sussex. West Sussex County Record "~ e.g. Luton, Bedfordshire. Office, QDD/6/WI8. 28 THE AGRICULTURAL HISTORY REVIEW regarding certain doubtful areas, which will hence overstate the earlier changes, quite be considered later, 33, I46 acres, or 3.94 per apart from any other objections which might cent of the sample, consisted of such be raised. ,9 already-enclosed land, and for England separately the figure is proportionately higher, at 4. I9 per cent. The totals actually II enclosed were thus 736,267 acres for With regard to the type of land involved, the England and I22,676 for Wales, giving overwhelming majority of awards specify implied totals of 7,253,955 and I~7,o3o clearly whether the land concerned in any respectively. The grand total enclosed particular allotment was open field, would appear to have been over 8.42 million meadow, or common waste. While this acres. division may beg certain questions about the For England alone the amount of open or real nature of some open field land common land abolished by enclosure would immediately prior to enclosure, and the therefore appear to fall in a range from 7.25 degree to which common waste had been million acres, assuming a maximum number encroached and cultivated, the legal situ- of erroneous enclosures, to 7.35 million, ation, at least, is usually clear.
Recommended publications
  • Unfree Labor, Capitalism and Contemporary Forms of Slavery
    Unfree Labor, Capitalism and Contemporary Forms of Slavery Siobhán McGrath Graduate Faculty of Political and Social Science, New School University Economic Development & Global Governance and Independent Study: William Milberg Spring 2005 1. Introduction It is widely accepted that capitalism is characterized by “free” wage labor. But what is “free wage labor”? According to Marx a “free” laborer is “free in the double sense, that as a free man he can dispose of his labour power as his own commodity, and that on the other hand he has no other commodity for sale” – thus obliging the laborer to sell this labor power to an employer, who possesses the means of production. Yet, instances of “unfree labor” – where the worker cannot even “dispose of his labor power as his own commodity1” – abound under capitalism. The question posed by this paper is why. What factors can account for the existence of unfree labor? What role does it play in an economy? Why does it exist in certain forms? In terms of the broadest answers to the question of why unfree labor exists under capitalism, there appear to be various potential hypotheses. ¾ Unfree labor may be theorized as a “pre-capitalist” form of labor that has lingered on, a “vestige” of a formerly dominant mode of production. Similarly, it may be viewed as a “non-capitalist” form of labor that can come into existence under capitalism, but can never become the central form of labor. ¾ An alternate explanation of the relationship between unfree labor and capitalism is that it is part of a process of primary accumulation.
    [Show full text]
  • The “Ill Kill'd” Deer: Poaching and Social Order in the Merry Wives of Windsor
    The “ill kill’d” Deer: Poaching and Social Order in The Merry Wives of Windsor Jeffrey Theis Nicholas Rowe once asserted that the young Shakespeare was caught stealing a deer from Sir Thomas Lucy’s park at Charlecote. The anecdote’s truth-value is clearly false, yet the narrative’s plausibility resonates from the local social customs in Shakespeare’s Warwickshire region. As the social historian Roger Manning convincingly argues, hunting and its ille- gitimate kin poaching thoroughly pervaded all social strata of early modern English culture. Close proximity to the Forest of Arden and nu- merous aristocratic deer parks and rabbit warrens would have steeped Shakespeare’s early life in the practices of hunting and poaching whether he engaged in them or only heard stories about them.1 While some Shakespeare criticism attends directly or indirectly to the importance of hunting in the comedies, remarkably, there has been no sustained analysis of poaching’s importance in these plays.2 In part, the reason for the oversight might be lexicographical. The word “poaching” never occurs in any of Shakespeare’s works, and the first instance in which poaching means “to take game or fish illegally” is in 1611—a decade after Shakespeare composed his comedies.3 Yet while the word was not coined for another few years, Roger Manning proves that illegal deer killing was a socially and politically explosive issue well before 1611. Thus, the “ill kill’d deer” Justice Shallow refers to in Act One of The Merry Wives of Windsor situates the play within a socially resonant discourse where illegal deer killing brings to light cultural assumptions imbedded within the legal hunt.
    [Show full text]
  • Adam Smith: Founder of Economics
    Adam Smith: Founder of Economics Robert M. Coen Professor Emeritus of Economics Northwestern Alumnae Continuing Education January 5, 2017 Adam Smith, 1723-1790 John Rattray, 1707-71 Signatory of First Rules of Golf (1744) Ways of Coordinating Economic Activity Traditional Structures Authoritarian Structures Market structures Reasons for Slow Development of Markets Popularity of Mercantilism Government promotes exports, stifles imports Favored industries get subsidies, protection, monopoly franchises Establish and exploit foreign colonies Accumulate riches (gold) for royalty Reasons for Slow Development of Markets Popularity of Mercantilism Avarice regarded as sin False Principles of Trade Boston Minister John Cotton, 1639 A man might sell as dear as he can and buy as cheap as he can If a man lose some of his goods, say by accident at sea, he may raise the price of the rest He may sell at the price he bought, even though he paid too much Reasons for Slow Development of Markets Popularity of Mercantilism Avarice regarded as sin Indifferent attitudes toward personal betterment Prevalence of local taxes on movement of goods Lack of standardization of weights and measures Multiple currencies Resistance to innovation Land, labor, and capital not developed concepts Factors Promoting Development of Markets Enclosure of commons Ringleaders of the Enclosure Movement Rural Life After Enclosure of the Commons Factors Promoting Development of Markets Enclosure of commons Political consolidation and centralization Decay of religious spirit Bernard Mandeville,
    [Show full text]
  • John Clare, Poems Against Enclosure 1 John Clare (1793-1864)
    John Clare, Poems Against Enclosure 1 John Clare (1793-1864) The Mores Far spread the moorey ground a level scene Bespread with rush and one eternal green That never felt the rage of blundering plough Though centurys wreathed spring’s blossoms on its brow Still meeting plains that stretched them far away In uncheckt shadows of green brown, and grey Unbounded freedom ruled the wandering scene Nor fence of ownership crept in between To hide the prospect of the following eye Its only bondage was the circling sky One mighty flat undwarfed by bush and tree Spread its faint shadow of immensity And lost itself, which seemed to eke its bounds In the blue mist the horizon’s edge surrounds Now this sweet vision of my boyish hours Free as spring clouds and wild as summer flowers Is faded all - a hope that blossomed free, And hath been once, no more shall ever be Inclosure came and trampled on the grave Of labour’s rights and left the poor a slave And memory’s pride ere want to wealth did bow Is both the shadow and the substance now The sheep and cows were free to range as then Where change might prompt nor felt the bonds of men Cows went and came, with evening morn and night, To the wild pasture as their common right And sheep, unfolded with the rising sun Heard the swains shout and felt their freedom won Tracked the red fallow field and heath and plain Then met the brook and drank and roamed again The brook that dribbled on as clear as glass Beneath the roots they hid among the grass While the glad shepherd traced their tracks along Free as the
    [Show full text]
  • Making Space
    Alternative radical histories and campaigns continuing today. Sam Burgum November 2018 Property ownership is not a given, but a social and legal construction, with a specific history. Magna Carta (1215) established a legal precedent for protecting property owners from arbitrary possession by the state. ‘For a man’s home is his ASS Archives ASS castle, and each man’s home is his safest refuge’ - Edward Coke, 1604 Charter of the Forest (1217) asserted the rights of the ‘commons’ (i.e. propertyless) to access the 143 royal forests enclosed since 1066. Enclosure Acts (1760-1870) enclosed 7million acres of commons through 4000 acts of parliament. My land – a squatter fable A man is out walking on a hillside when suddenly John Locke (1632-1704) Squatting & Trespass Context in Trespass & Squatting the owner appears. argued that enclosure could ‘Get off my land’, he yells. only be justified if: ‘Who says it’s your land?’ demands the intruder. • ‘As much and as good’ ‘I do, and I’ve got the deeds to prove it.’ was left to others; ‘Well, where did you get it from?’ ‘From my father.’ • Unused property could be ‘And where did he get it from?’ forfeited for better use. ‘From his father. He was the seventeenth Earl. The estate originally belonged to the first Earl.’ This logic was used to ‘And how did he get it?’ dispossess indigenous people ‘He fought for it in the War of the Roses.’ of land, which appeared Right – then I’ll fight you for it!’ ‘unused’ to European settlers. 1 ‘England is not a Free people till the poor that have no land… live as Comfortably as the landlords that live in their inclosures.’ Many post-Civil war movements and sects saw the execution of King Charles as ending a centuries-long Norman oppression.
    [Show full text]
  • Second Serfdom and Wage Earners in European and Russian Thought from the Enlightenment to the Mid-Nineteenth Century
    CHAPTER 1 SECOND SERFDOM AND WAGE EARNERS IN EUROPEAN AND RUSSIAN THOUGHT FROM THE ENLIGHTENMENT TO THE MID-NINETEENTH CENTURY The Eighteenth Century: Forced Labor between Reform and Revolution The invention of backwardness in Western economic and philosophical thought owes much to the attention given to Russia and Poland in the beginning of the eighteenth century.1 The definitions of backwardness and of labor—which is the main element of backwardness—lies at the nexus of three interrelated debates: over serfdom in Eastern European, slavery in the colonies, and guild reform in France. The connection between these three debates is what makes the definition of labor—and the distinction between free and forced labor—take on certain character- istics and not others. In the course of the eighteenth century, the work of slaves, serfs, and apprentices came to be viewed not just by ethical stan- dards, but increasingly by its efficiency. On that basis, hierarchies were justified, such as the “backwardness” of the colonies relative to the West, of Eastern relative to Western Europe, and of France relative to England. The chronology is striking. Criticisms of guilds, serfdom, and slavery all hardened during the 1750s; Montesquieu published The Spirit of the Laws in 1748, which was soon followed by the first volumes of the Ency- clopédie.2 In these works the serfdom of absolutist and medieval Europe was contrasted with the free labor of Enlightenment Europe. Abbé de Morelli took up these themes in 1755, condemning both ancient serf- dom and modern forms of slavery, in both the colonies and Russia.
    [Show full text]
  • John Stuart Mill and Harriet Taylor : Their Correspondence
    UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA LIBRARIES Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from LYRASIS Members and Sloan Foundation http://www.archive.org/details/johnstuartmillhaOOmill JOHN STUART MILL AND HARRIET TAYLOR ERRATA On the title page instead of Their Correspondence read Their Friendship On p. 25, line 14, instead of given as a frontispiece to read reproduced opposite page 128 of On p. 35, line 8, instead of form read from On p. 60, line 16, instead of morally read morality On p. 140, line 6, instead of his read this On p. 218, line 26, instead of Avignon, read Avignon- On p. 236, line 11, instead of of Antinous read or Antinous On p. 240, line 19, instead of Molo read Molos On p. 246, line 11, instead of clothers read clothes On p. 249, line 23, instead of Galiagni s read Galignani's On p. 264, lines 13 and 14, instead of malherreux read malheureux On p. 266, line 21, instead of on opposite page read on the opposite page On p. 284, line i, insert is before given On p. 294, line 4, instead of on typed envelope read on a typed enve- lope On p. 294, line 14, instead of at least, read at least as a note. On p. 301, line 31, instead of Chateuroux read Chateauroux On p. 311, line 6, instead of {1791-1892) read {1791-1862) JOHN STUART MILL AND HARRIET TAYLOR JOHN STUART MILL AND HARRIET TAYLOR Their Correspondence and Subsequent Marriage BY F. A. HAYEK THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO PRESS CHICAGO ILLINOIS [40.
    [Show full text]
  • The Enclosure of English Common Lands, 1475-18391
    A SAMPLING APPROACH TO HISTORY: THE ENCLOSURE OF ENGLISH COMMON LANDS, 1475-18391 Gregory Clark and Anthony Clark February, 2000 Using samples of charity land we estimate the amount of land subject to some type of communal control in England from 1475 to 1839. Our estimates suggest three things. First only about 20 percent of land had common rights in 1750, so that after 1750 enclosure on charity plots is overwhelmingly by Parliamentary means. Second only about four percent more charity land was common in 1600 than would be implied by the records of Parliamentary enclosure. From 1600 to 1750 there was little enclosure by individuals or by private agreements. Modern property rights predominated even in 1600. Finally only about four percent of land even in 1600 was common with potentially open access. Most of the common land even in 1600 was controlled and regulated. Historians have long debated the timing and the mechanism of enclosure of common land in England, in part as an index of the modernization of English agriculture, and in part out of concern for the social effects of enclosure. “Common land” here refers to any land subject to some form of common control or access. Thus common includes open field arable and open field meadow which were common for only part of the year, stinted pastures, and “waste.”2 “Waste” was the only type of land that was common in the modern sense of having free access, and which thus the landless had access to.3 The Parliamentary enclosure movement is estimated to have removed common rights on 22 percent of all land in the years after 1750.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Bardwashing' Shakespeare: Food Justice, Enclosure, and the Poaching Poet Kevin A. Quarmby1 KEYWORDS
    Journal of Social Justice, Vol. 5, 2015 (© 2015) ISSN: 2164-7100 ‘Bardwashing’ Shakespeare: Food Justice, Enclosure, and the Poaching Poet Kevin A. Quarmby1 William Shakespeare arguably represents the height of English intellectual creativity. His drama and poetry transcend his mortality, speaking to generation upon generation with an authoritative appeal that seems morally superior because of its durability over the centuries. In his play As You Like It, Shakespeare even appears to glorify the social bandit and proto food activist. Characters that survive in the Forest of Arden by poaching their usurping duke’s deer are likened to the mythical figure, Robin Hood. The allusion achieves greater significance when considered alongside near- contemporary pseudo-biographies that record Shakespeare’s early life as a poacher and youthful renegade. At face value, Shakespeare’s Robin Hood reference might suggest his subtle advocacy of food sovereignty and social justice. This romanticized image is supported by later historiographies that interpret medieval and early modern enclosure from a specifically partisan viewpoint. Early nineteenth century historians who referenced More’s Utopia, and whose influence is evident in enclosure analyses ranging from Marx to Polanyi and Bookchin, unwittingly assist in perpetuating the iconography of the social bandit Shakespeare, united with his rebellious rural contemporaries. Surprisingly, however, Shakespeare’s true personality – that of a shrewd and ruthless businessman, at ease with hoarding in time of famine as purchasing common-land rights and privileges at the expense of his impoverished neighbors – is less familiar. The opportunistic, land-grabbing, pro-enclosure Bard, while not erased from critical view, is certainly shielded by the bardolatrous hero- worship of later ages.
    [Show full text]
  • Contracting the Right to Roam
    Contracting the Right to Roam Wallace McNeish and Steve Olivier © 2017, Palgrave Macmillan, reproduced with permission of Palgrave Macmillan This extract is taken from the author's original manuscript and has not been edited. The definitive, published, version of record is available in the Palgrave Handbook of Leisure Theory, edited by K. Spracklen et al., available from: http://www.palgrave.com/gp/book/9781137564788 Contracting the Right to Roam Wallace McNeish and Steve Olivier Introduction This chapter critically examines the issue of free recreational access to the environment – the right to roam, from the perspective of political philosophy. We begin by setting the right to roam within a comparative socio-legal context that indicates how ongoing social and economic change has moved it to centre stage in the increasingly contested sphere of what Rojek (2001; 2010) calls leisure politics. We then move on to consider the political- philosophical debate that has traditionally revolved around rights and duties pertaining to private property, and the conception of the social contract. In recent decades the emergence of environmental ethics – and in particular conceptions of environmental sustainability and environmental justice, have added extra dimensions of complexity to the philosophical terrain upon which the right to roam is contested. Two very different versions of the social contract will be juxtaposed to bring the key arguments into high relief. On the one hand we consider Hardin’s influential eco-Hobbesian Tragedy of the Commons (2000, [1968]) thesis. This positions human beings as possessive, selfish and competitive individuals who will inevitably be responsible for generalized environmental degradation, unless their restless desires (including to roam) are held in check by a coercive Green Leviathan.
    [Show full text]
  • Property in Land
    Article Property in Land Robert C. Ellicksont CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ............................................. 1317 I. THE CASE FOR INDIVIDUAL OWNERSHIP OF LAND .................. 1322 A. Three Simple Land Regimes .............................. 1323 B. Small Events: The Relative Ease of MonitoringBoundaries ........ 1327 1. The Genius of Individual Land Ownership ................ 1327 2. Technologiesfor Marking, Defending, and Proving Boundaries . 1328 C. Medium Events: A Simple Way to Promote Cooperative Relations ... 1330 II. THE ADVANTAGES OF GROUP OWNERSHIP OF LAND .................. 1332 A. When Returns Increase with Parcel Size ..................... 1332 1. Efficient Boundaries ................................. 1332 2. Large Events ..................................... 1334 B. Three Pioneer Settlements ............................... 1335 1. Jamestown ........................................ 1336 2. Plymouth .......................................... 1338 3. Salt Lake City ...................................... 1339 t Walter E. Meyer Professor of Property and Urban Law, Yale Law School. I thank participants in workshops at the Harvard, University of Toronto, and Yale Law Schools for comments on a preliminary draft. I am especially indebted to Betsy Clark, Jim Coleman, Rob Daines, Harold Demsetz, Henry Hansmann, Jim Krier, Tony Kronman, John Langbein, Eric Rasmusen, Roberta Romano, Richard Ross, David Schmidtz, Peter Schuck, Jim Scott, Steve Shavell, Paul Stephan, Ed Zelinsky, and, as always, Carol Rose. Simon Frankel, Robin Kelsey,
    [Show full text]
  • Accumulation by Securitization: Commercial Poaching, Neoliberal Conservation, and the Creation of New Wildlife Frontiers
    This is a repository copy of Accumulation by securitization: Commercial poaching, neoliberal conservation, and the creation of new wildlife frontiers. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/132716/ Version: Accepted Version Article: Massé, F. and Lunstrum, E. (2016) Accumulation by securitization: Commercial poaching, neoliberal conservation, and the creation of new wildlife frontiers. Geoforum, 69. pp. 227-237. ISSN 0016-7185 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geoforum.2015.03.005 Reuse This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs (CC BY-NC-ND) licence. This licence only allows you to download this work and share it with others as long as you credit the authors, but you can’t change the article in any way or use it commercially. More information and the full terms of the licence here: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/ Takedown If you consider content in White Rose Research Online to be in breach of UK law, please notify us by emailing [email protected] including the URL of the record and the reason for the withdrawal request. [email protected] https://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/ Accepted Manuscript -GEOFORUM Accumulation by Securitization: Commercial Poaching, Neoliberal Conservation, and the Creation of New Wildlife Frontiers1 Francis Massé Elizabeth Lunstrum Abstract: Part of a broader interest in the escalating securitization of conservation practice, scholars are beginning to take note of an emerging relationship between conservation-securitization, capital accumulation, and dispossession. We develop the concept of accumulation by securitization to better grasp this trend, positioning it in the critical literatures on neoliberal conservation, green grabbing, and conservation-security.
    [Show full text]