<<

FORECASTING CONSUMPTION: THE ROLE OF CONFIDENCE IN REAL TIME WITH MANY PREDICTORS

Kajal Lahiri∗, George Monokroussos, Yongchen Zhao Department of , University at Albany, SUNY, Albany, New York, 12222, USA

April 2013

Abstract We study the role of in forecasting real personal consump- tion expenditure. We contribute to the extant literature in three main ways: First, we reexamine existing empirical models of consumption and consumer confidence not only at the quarterly frequency, but using monthly data as well. Second, we employ real-time data in addition to commonly used revised vintages. Third, we investigate the role of consumer confidence in a rich information context. We pro- duce forecasts of consumption expenditures with and without consumer confidence measures using a dynamic factor model and a large, real-time, jagged-edge data set. In a robust way, we establish the independent role of confidence surveys in improving the accuracy of consumption forecasts.

JEL Classification: E21, E27, C53 Key words: Forecasting, Consumption, Consumer Sentiment, Factor Models, Kalman Filter, Real Time Data

∗ Correspondence to: Kajal Lahiri, University at Albany, SUNY, Albany, NY, USA. E-mail: [email protected]. The authors thank Kyle Brown, Richard Curtin, and Ataman Ozyildirim for the help and clarifica- tions with respect to issues regarding the data sets used in this study. 1 INTRODUCTION

The concept of animal spirits, in the standard Keynesian sense, has influenced economic thinking for a long time and has received renewed and intense attention in the run up to the recent financial crisis and the ensuing recession, cf. Akerlof & Shiller (2010). The confidence of economic agents and its importance to theecon- omy occupy a central role in this discussion 1 . Consumer confidence, in particular, is typically at the center of attention of the business press. It has also been studied extensively by academics as well as policy makers. This interest is certainly justi- fied given the overwhelming importance of for an . Many academic studies, both for the U.S. and internationally, investigate vari- ous aspects of the relationship between consumer confidence and consumer spend- ing, at both the micro and the aggregate levels. Souleles (2004) found that aggregate shocks do not hit all segments of the population equally; rather they are systemat- ically mediated by demographic characteristics of households. In addition, given the timing advantage of the standard measures of confidence, as was first empha- sized by Howrey (2001), consumer confidence may have important implications for monitoring the economy in real time and for , as well as for testing key economic theories, such as the canonical permanent income – (PIH/RE) hypothesis. Consequently, a central preoccupation of the relevant literature, including the papers cited above, is to assess the forecasting power of consumer confidence for consumer spending at the aggregate level. As Ludvigson (2004) comprehensive study discusses, some evidence to that effect is generally found in the literature, but it becomes more modest once a few additional variables that have traditionally been considered in studies of consumer confidence are added to the specification.

1 See, inter alia, Leeper (1992); Fuhrer (1993); Carroll et al. (1994); Bram & Ludvigson (1998); Ludvigson (2004); Souleles (2004); Croushore (2005); Easaw et al. (2005); Malgarini & Margani (2007); Wilcox (2007); Al-Eyd et al. (2009); Chua (2009); Giannone et al. (2009); Dreger & Kholodilin (2010); Dees & Brinca (2011) and Starr (2012). For a worldwide review and assessment of consumer sentiment surveys, see Curtin (2007). 2 However, as Ludvigson (2004) and others stress, much of this existing literature has several limitations: First, quarterly data are commonly used. However, the most widely known measures of consumer confidence (the University of Michigan’s Index of Consumer Sentiment (ICS) and the Conference Board’s Consumer Confidence Index (CCI)) are available at a monthly frequency, and employing quarterly averages of these monthly indices in models of consumption expenditures may conflate the monthly effects of consumer confidence. 2 Moreover, consumer spending itself, and also many other relevant indicators are available on a monthly basis as well. Second, revised data on the relevant variables are employed, as opposed to the data that were actually available in real time, i.e., before any revision that only became available at subsequent points in time. Of course, for monetary policy purposes, or more generally, for the purpose of assessing the real-time forecasting power of consumer confidence, real-time data should be used. Third, the regression models used to assess the predictive power of consumer confidence typically include only a small number of additional variables, i.e.,a rather small information set, whereas many more variables, possibly in the hun- dreds, are available that are potentially relevant to consumption forecasting. In this study, we provide what is arguably a more realistic assessment of the predictive power of consumer confidence on consumer spending by addressing all of the three issues mentioned above using more recent data. Our starting point is Ludvigson (2004). We extend some of the existing models using monthly and real-time data, in addition to quarterly and revised vintages. We also employ a large real-time data set with close to two hundred explanatory vari- ables at the monthly frequency in order to assess the marginal impact of confidence on consumer spending in the context of such a large information set in real time. In this setting, a dynamic factor model is preferred to deal with the challenges, such as the proliferation of parameters (Stock & Watson (2011), Banbura et al. (2013)).

2 In what follows, we use the word “sentiment” and “confidence” interchangeably. 3 Through a series of exercises using the framework first developed by Giannone et al. (2008), we gain insight on the marginal impact of consumer confidence on consumer spending in real time by comparing consumption forecasts based on information sets with and without consumer confidence measures. In contrast to much of the existing literature, we consider both in-sample and out-of-sample forecasts. Our results generally establish the undeniable importance of consumer confidence in forecasting aggregate consumption. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 provides some discus- sion of the important aspects of the consumption and consumer confidence data. Section 3 revisits some models used in the existing literature on the predictive power of consumer confidence. Section 4 outlines the dynamic factor approach and assesses the predictive power of consumer confidence in real time when it isa part of a large information set. Section 5 concludes.

2 CONSUMPTION AND CONSUMER SENTIMENT: A CLOSER LOOK AT THE DATA

Consumer spending accounts for about two-thirds of domestic final spending in the United States. The primary measure of consumer spending on various types of and services is real personal consumption expenditure (PCE). It cov- ers purchases made by households and nonprofit institutions serving households (NPISHs). PCE data come from Personal Income and Outlays released by the De- partment of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). It can be measured by type of products or by function (health, recreation, communication, etc.). In this study, we examine the total PCE and PCE by main types of products: durable goods, nondurable goods, and services. PCE data are available at both the monthly and the quarterly frequencies. The quarterly series are released every month together with the GDP series, typically in the last week of the month. Similar to the GDP series, there is a one-quarter lag between the end of a period and the release of data covering that period. Advance 4 estimates of PCE are released for the previous quarter at the end of the first month of each quarter. At the end of the second and the third months, the preliminary and the final estimates for the previous quarter are released, respectively. The monthly series are released one day after the release of the quarterly series. The publication lag for the monthly series is one month. Monthly PCE series are also subject to revisions. Such revisions are announced in the monthly releases. The two monthly PCE values for the first two months (released at the end ofthe second and the third month of a quarter) play an important role in forecasting the quarterly PCE for that quarter and beyond, before the advance release of the quar- terly value becomes available. This implies that to someone forecasting in real time, every release, both quarterly and monthly, contains some additional information not present in any of the previous releases. To our knowledge, monthly PCE series have not been used in any study of the relationship between consumer confidence and consumer spending. We thus consider using the monthly consumption series (in addition to their quarterly counterparts) as one of our main contributions. One of the most recognized measures of consumer confidence is the Index of Consumer Sentiment (ICS) from the Survey of administered by the Survey Research Center of the University of Michigan. The Survey started as an annual survey in 1946, cf. Katona (1951). It became a quarterly survey in 1952 and then a monthly survey in 1976. The ICS index can be separated into a present conditions index and an expectations index, based on the content of the questions used in constructing the index. Each month, about 500 households are interviewed by phone. The preliminary releases of the index come out around mid-month, based on the information gathered in the first half of the month, usually two-thirds ofthe full sample. The final releases are scheduled on the last Friday of each month. Public and media attention is usually concentrated on the final releases, which are quite timely, and subject to no further revision. The Survey of Consumers tracks many different aspects of consumer attitudes and expectations. About 50 core questions are asked in each survey. Five of these

5 questions are used to construct the ICS, and they are as follows: (i) We are interested in how people are getting along financially these days. Would you say that you (and your family living there) are better off or worse off financially than you were a year ago? (ii) Now looking ahead–do you think that a year from now you (and your family living there) will be better off financially, or worse off, or just about the same as now? (iii) Now turning to business conditions in the country as a whole–do you think that during the next twelve months we’ll have good times financially, or bad times, or what? (iv) Looking ahead, which would you say is more likely–that in the country as a whole we’ll have continuous good times during the next five years or so, or that we will have periods of widespread unemployment or depression, or what? (v) About the big things people buy for their homes–such as furniture, a refriger- ator, stove, television, and things like that. Generally speaking, do you think now is a good or bad time for people to buy major household items? Among these questions, (i) and (v) are mainly about the present conditions of the household and the economy, while the remaining three questions are clearly about household expectations. For each of the five questions, a respondent can choose among three responses: favorable (e.g., situation getting better), neutral (e.g., situation is the same as before), and unfavorable (e.g., situation getting worse). The relative score for each question is calculated as the percentage of respondents giving favorable replies minus the percentage giving unfavorable replies plus 100. Thus, each component measures how widely the specific subjective feeling is de- fused throughout the economy, and is typically characterized by waves of optimism and pessimism. Scores are then rounded, added up and divided by the base period value of 1966 to form an index. Based on the content of the questions, the Index of Consumer Expectations (ICE) is constructed using relative scores for questions (ii)

6 to (iv). Similarly, the Index of Current Economic Conditions (ICC) is constructed using relative scores for questions (i) and (v). And finally, the overall index, ICS, is constructed using all five relative scores. Another widely used measure of consumer confidence is the Consumer Con- fidence Index (CCI) from the Consumer Confidence Survey administered bythe Conference Board. The survey began in 1967 as a bi-monthly survey. Since June 1977, the survey has been administered monthly. Similar to the ICS, the Consumer Confidence Index can also be separated into two components, the present situation component and the expectations component. Each month, a mail survey is sent out and approximately 3,000 completed questionnaires are collected 3 . Preliminary estimates are based on survey responses collected before the 18th of each month. Final estimates are published with the release of the following month’s data, sched- uled on the last Tuesday of each month. The Consumer Confidence Index and its two components are also based on five questions. The first two are used to construct the present situations indexand the rest are used to construct the expectations index. All five questions are used to construct the Consumer Confidence Index. These questions are as follows: (i) How would you rate the present general business conditions in your area? (ii) What would you say about available jobs in your area right now? (iii) Six months from now, do you think general business conditions will be better, the same, or worse? (iv) Six months from now, do you think there will be more, the same, or fewer jobs available in your area? (v) How would you guess your total family income to be six months from now? Answers: higher, the same, or lower? To each of the five questions, three response options are available: positive, neutral, or negative. The proportion of respondents giving positive responses among those who do not give neutral responses for each question is computed first. A

3 A new sample design was introduced effective November 2010. A discussion of historical com- parability is available in the Consumer Confidence Survey Technical Note. 7 corresponding index is produced for each proportion with the average value for all months in 1985 as the benchmark. Finally, relevant indices are averaged to produce the Consumer Confidence Index and its two components. Seasonal adjustment is performed where needed. 4 In this study, we focus on consumption and consumer confidence data between January 1982 and September 2011 – a total of 357 months (119 quarters). Figure 1 compares the University of Michigan’s consumer sentiment and the Conference Board’s consumer confidence measures with the 12-month moving average ofan- nualized (advanced estimates of) monthly growth in real personal consumption expenditure. The shaded areas are periods of NBER-defined recessions. The top panel shows the two overall indices, and the lower panel shows the two expectations components. It is clear from the figure that over the business cycles, the confidence measures evolve in a similar way as the consumption growth does. However, the two measures themselves are not always that closely correlated to each other, and the variance of CCI is almost twice that of CSI primarily due to the methods of construction. As mentioned above, Figure 1 plots real-time data of consumption. The impor- tance of using real-time data for tasks such as assessing monetary policy or evalu- ating forecasts in general cannot be understated (see inter alia, Croushore & Stark (2001); Orphanides (2001)). More specifically to our context, and as Ludvigson (2004) discusses, it is essential not to use revised data when assessing the real-time forecasting power of consumer confidence for consumption. However, much of the existing literature on consumer confidence and consumer spending has employed revised data. Therefore, in the estimation and forecast evaluation exercises that follow, we employ both current/latest and first vintages (obtained from the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia’s Real-Time Data Research Center). Furthermore, and as discussed in the introduction, the existing literature em- ploys quarterly data, which can mask important information available at monthly

4 See Ludvigson (2004) for more detailed discussions. 8 frequency. Thus, in the exercises that follow, we use both quarterly and monthly data.

3 EXISTING MODELS EXTENDED

A number of attempts have been made in the literature to quantify the im- portance of consumer confidence measures in explaining and predicting quarterly consumption expenditures. In this section, we first re-examine some of the main empirical models used in previous studies (e.g., Carroll et al. (1994); Bram & Ludvigson (1998); Ludvigson (2004)), and then extend them to model monthly consumption expenditures. In the process, we focus on the significance of the confidence measure and the change in the model’s explanatory power duetothe addition of this measure.

3.1 A Univariate Approach

We first consider a simple model of consumption expenditure where consumer confidence is the only predictor, in addition to the lagged values of consumption.

For time period t, let Ct be (a type of) consumption expenditure, and let St be (a measure of) consumer confidence. We estimate the following model: τ τ Δln(Ct) = α0 + ∑ αi Δln(Ct i) + ∑ βi St i + εt (1) i=1 ∙ − i=1 ∙ − where, following the literature, the number of lags τ is set to 4. We estimate this model for monthly consumption and for quarterly consumption separately. The consumption expenditure Ct is one of the following four: total personal consump- tion expenditure (Total), expenditure on durable goods (Durable), expenditure on non-durable goods (Non-Durable), and that on services (Services). The confidence measure is one of the following four: the expectations components and the overall indices from the University of Michigan and the Conference Board. Quarterly sen- timent measures are averages of all monthly values within a quarter. Standard error estimates are robust to heteroskedasticity and serial correlation. 9 Table 1 (columns labeled “No Additional Variables”) presents the estimation results. 5 In general, the model’s explanatory power is similar to that found in the existing literature using quarterly data (see Ludvigson, 2004). Since the monthly consumption series is significantly more volatile than the quarterly values, the Rˉ2 value of the monthly model is almost one-half of that using quarterly model (0.17 vs. 0.36 for total consumption). The coefficient of sentiment in the monthly regression was 0.180, compared to 0.098 in the quarterly regression, both statisti- cally significant at 5% level of significance. In the table, incremental Rˉ2s are the 2 2 difference between the Rˉ of the above model with St i (equation (1)) and the Rˉ − of the benchmark model with only four lags of consumption and a constant. The joint significance of coefficients of all lags of the confidence measure (aswellas the sum of the coefficients) is also reported. The table shows that the consumer confidence measures do indeed explain consumption, but the amount varies. As high as 17% of additional explanatory power can be obtained by adding a confidence measure to the benchmark model, as in the case of adding the expectations component of CCI to the model of real time quarterly consumption expenditure on services. On average (over 8 cases – 2 confidence measures 4 types of consumption), when using the University of × Michigan sentiment measures, a 7.5% increase in Rˉ2 is observed in models of real-time quarterly consumption expenditures, while a 3.2% increase is observed in models of monthly expenditures. In models using the Conference Board confidence measures, an average of 7.1% incremental Rˉ2 is observed in quarterly models; and an average of 2.6% increment is observed in monthly models. Table 1 presents results based on revised quarterly consumption data as well. These figures are somewhat lower than their real-time counterparts. Thus, the use of real-time data seems to enhance the effect of confidence measures.

5 Table 1 presents quarterly results based on real-time and revised data and monthly results based on revised data only. Monthly results based on real-time data are omitted because they are not directly comparable with respective results from Section 3.2 (see footnote 6). Furthermore, and in line with the literature, results on the current conditions components of both confidence measures are also omitted. 10 3.2 Models with Additional Variables

Despite clear evidence of the importance of consumer confidence measures in models of personal consumption expenditures from the exercise above, it remains a question whether sentiment measures contain unique information that is not avail- able in other aggregate measures of economic activity. To investigate this question, we consider the following specification: τ τ τ Δln(Ct) = α0 + ∑ αi Zt i + ∑ αi Δln(Ct i) + ∑ βi St i + εt (2) i=1 ∙ − i=1 ∙ − i=1 ∙ − where in the benchmark model, apart from lagged values of consumption expendi- tures, there is a set of baseline macroeconomic variables that are typically included in the existing literature (see, inter alia, Carroll et al. (1994); Ludvigson (2004)).

We include in Zt the return to S&P500 index, the 3-month Treasury-Bill rate, and labor income growth which is wages and salaries plus transfers minus personal contributions for social insurance. We estimate the quarterly models using both real-time and revised data and the monthly models using revised series. 6 The results are reported in Table 1 as well (columns labeled “With Additional Variables”). Similar to the results in the previous subsection, in all 16 models (cor- responding to 4 types of consumption and 2 measures of confidence for both the Conference Board and University of Michigan), including consumer confidence measures increases the Rˉ2, but the effect varies on the specification considered. On average, in quarterly models using the University of Michigan sentiment measures, a 5.6% increase in Rˉ2 is observed – 1.9% less than that of the models without additional variables. In models using the Conference Board confidence measures, an average increase of 5.6% is also observed – a 1.5% decrease from the previous set of models. For the monthly models, the explanatory power in the presence of the extra regressors is about the same as before: On average, in models

6 Nominal labor income and the S&P500 index are converted to real terms using the PCE price index. Real time data for the components of labor income are only available at a quarterly frequency, thus our monthly models are estimated using only the latest vintage. 11 using the University of Michigan sentiment measures, a 3.2% increase in Rˉ2 is observed. In models using the Conference Board confidence measures, an average increase of 2.8% is observed. These results suggest that the contributions of consumer confidence measures in explaining consumption expenditures are statistically significant in most cases, but are, arguably, of modest size, as found in most other studies. 7 There is little doubt that confidence does contain a significant amount of information that isnot found in a few standard macro-economic variables. However, while the explanatory variables used here are the standard choices in the literature, there are many other variables with potentially significant explanatory power for consumption. There- fore, the findings reported above could be an artifact of having employed an infor- mation set that is too restrictive. It is conceivable that the information contained in consumer confidence measures could simply be a combination of the information found in a large number of macroeconomic indicators not included in the above models.

4 FORECASTING CONSUMPTION IN A LARGE DATA SET

Given the above discussion, we want to explore the role of confidence in fore- casting consumption, when the forecasts are generated using a wide information set. This requires using a large number of additional explanatory variables and one immediate problem that arises with this type of exercise is the lack of degrees of freedom. Even when we use monthly consumption data, the number of available

7 Croushore (2005) finds that confidence is not significant in forecasting consumption inaspec- ification that includes explanatory variables similar to the ones we used in this section. Thereare several important differences between his exercises and the ones presented here. First, for evaluating forecasts, he uses real-time consumption data, but vintages “available just prior to a benchmark revision” – these benchmark revisions are made about every five years. One may say that evaluating forecasts generated in real time using figures that only became available after several revisions may be a very stringent test that confidence measures are unlikely to pass. Second, Croushore’s sample covers 1992Q1 to 2002Q4 whereas our sample is from 1982Q1 to 2011Q3. Ivanova & Lahiri (2001) show that the benefit of including sentiment is larger in periods when conflicting economic and social-political news cause high overall uncertainty and wide swings in near-term expectations in personal income, as during the most recent recession. 12 observations is limited to the hundreds. Yet, potentially useful variables also come in the hundreds, which of course makes the classical linear regression model a poor choice. So we employ here an approach that allows us to address this challenge. The approach we use in this section is based on the dynamic factor model of Gi- annone et al. (2008), henceforth GRS. We first introduce the model, the explanatory variables, and discuss associated issues. Then we explore the effect of sentiment on the accuracy of consumption forecasts through out-of-sample pseudo-real-time exercises. Finally, we assess the marginal contribution of sentiment to consumption forecasts again, but now in the context of real-time data. The GRS framework is particularly suitable to tease out the marginal effects of specific data releases that are announced regularly at certain times of the month (Banbura et al., 2013).

4.1 The Dynamic Factor Framework

This approach utilizes a dynamic factor model in a state-space form to summa- rize the common information from a large number of explanatory variables with potentially mixed frequencies and varying patterns of missing data.

Let xt be a N 1 vector of observed independent variables for time period t, × and let Ft be a r 1 vector of latent factors representing the state of the economy. × The latent factors drive both the concurrent evolution of the explanatory variables and the future evolutions of the latent factors themselves. This relationship is sum- marized in a state-space model as follows:

xt = μ + Λ Ft + ξt (3) ∙

Ft = A Ft 1 + B ut (4) ∙ − ∙ where ξt is an N 1 vector of variable-specific innovations, Λ is an N r matrix × × of factor loadings, A is an r r matrix with all roots of det(Ir Az) outside the unit × − circle, B is an r q matrix of rank q, and ut is a q 1 vector of common shocks. As × × is standard in the literature, we set r = q = 2. Given the “jagged-edge” nature of the data, i.e., the varying missing data pat- 13 terns in the large number of explanatory variables, especially toward the end of the sample period, estimation of the model is performed in two steps. In the first step, a fully balanced panel of the explanatory variables is created by discarding any observation toward the end of the sample period for which at least one variable is not observed. This is used to obtain preliminary estimates of the latent factors by principal components. These estimates are in turn used to estimate the parameters of the model. Given these estimates, in the second step, the Kalman smoother is used to compute the latent factors for the entire sample period, including those periods discarded in the first step. In this process, the Kalman smoother forecasts the latent factors for periods when the observations for certain variables are un- available. Our variable of interest, a type of consumption expenditure, is assumed to be determined by the latent factors and possibly a lagged measure of consumer confidence. A simple OLS regression can be used to establish the link between consumption expenditure and these predictors, and to forecast future consumption expenditures given consumer confidence and forecasts of the factors. 8 To avoid the need to forecast consumer confidence to forecast consumption expenditures a number of periods ahead, we use lagged confidence measures in our model with the minimum necessary amount of lags. This two-step procedure is necessary to deal with the jagged-edge data struc- ture, which is caused by varying data release schedules and publication lags across all the explanatory variables. Such a data structure is unavoidable if no information is to be discarded when forecasting. For example, at the end of each month, the variables with a publication lag of one month will have one more observation in the data set than the variables with a publication lag of two months. With the publication lag affecting the structure of the data set at any given time, there are three main determinants of the value of an explanatory variable

8 In all of the exercises that follow, we regress consumption on the factors and the appropriate lags of confidence measures. As a robustness check, we have conducted these exercises using an alternative specification where the factors are extracted from a large data set including confidence, and consumption is regressed on these factors alone (see Lahiri & Monokroussos (2013)). Our conclusions from these exercises are largely the same. 14 in this context. The first determinant is the information content of the variable. If it contains only information that comes from other variables, in the sense that it is highly collinear with those variables, then the addition of this variable will not affect the estimates of the latent factors too much, and thus the forecasts made using these dynamic factors. The second determinant is the timeliness of the release of the variable. The shorter the publication lag, or the earlier its release date is within a month, the more useful the variable is likely to be. The last determinant is data revisions. Even though its effect on forecast accuracy is unclear, there should be no doubt that the role a variable plays in forecasting in real time cannot be fully revealed without considering the effect of data revisions. Corresponding to the three determinants above, we conduct three exercises. In the first exercise, we examine the in-sample fit of the model with and without the entire series of a confidence measure. This exercise focuses mostly on thefirst determinant, the information content. In the second exercise, we attempt to recon- struct “snapshots” or “vintages” of the jagged-edge data set based on a stylized calendar of data release schedules and publication lags. Using this data, we examine the accuracy of consumption forecasts made with and without the latest release of a confidence measure while all the historical values of this measure are always inthe data set. This exercise assesses the value of the timeliness of the data release and of the short publication lag of consumer confidence measures. In the last exercise, we construct real-time data sets as they were actually available to forecasters in the past, and use these data sets to examine the role of consumer confidence measures in real-time forecasting 9 . In addition to the two determinants considered above, this exercise accounts for the effect of data revisions on forecast accuracy. As before, we repeat all three exercises using both monthly and quarterly data. Most of our explanatory variables come from the data set put together by GRS.

9 Note that for the Conference Board confidence series (the expectations index and the overall index), the final release for any given month first becomes available with the following month’s preliminary release (unlike the University of Michigan measures, which are always available during the current month). To be consistent with the real-time nature of this exercise, we use the preliminary Conference Board data. To our knowledge, we are the first to employ these preliminary series. 15 This data set consists of nearly 200 macro variables for the US economy starting in January, 1982. These variables, most of which are at the monthly frequency, include real and monetary quantities, prices, and surveys. We construct all the variables used in the exercises in Section 3 and add them to their data set and we also remove the University of Michigan sentiment indices, the consumption expenditures, and real GDP. There are 172 variables in the resulting data set. Real time data for personal consumption expenditure and its components come from the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia’s Real-Time Data Research Center. For quar- terly consumption expenditures, monthly vintages are used instead of the quarterly vintages, since we produce forecasts of quarterly consumption expenditures at a monthly frequency.

4.2 Marginal Impact of Consumer Confidence on Forecast Accuracy

Using in-sample fitted values, we first measure the difference in mean squared errors (MSE) between models of consumption expenditure with and without the entire series of a confidence measure. This is the first exercise discussed above. We do so for all possible pairs of confidence measures and types of consumption expenditure. The results are presented in Table 2, where a relative MSE value that is smaller than 1 means that forecasts using consumer confidence too have a smaller MSE. These cells are shaded. In this and all subsequent exercises, we test the re- ported differences in MSEs using the Diebold & Mariano (1995) test with its small sample modification by Harvey et al. (1997). 10 Whenever the difference between two competing MSEs with and without using a consumer confidence measure is statistically significant at 10%, we report the relative MSE in bold. We also report the RMSE of the benchmark model, i.e., without confidence measure, for monthly and quarterly model respectively.

10 The standard Diebold–Mariano test gives conservative results in MSE comparisons between nested models. Therefore, the true contribution of confidence measures could be more significant than that indicated by the p-values reported in Table 2 and in Table 5. See Clark & McCracken (2013) (chap. 14). 16 We first confirm that the overall fit of our models are satisfactory, andtheRM- SEs of our benchmark models are similar to those of the models in the previous section. Adding a confidence measure improves the fit of all models, and quite often, this improvement is statistically significant. On average, adding a consumer confidence measure reduces the in-sample MSE by about 7%. The models ofser- vices and total consumption benefit the most from this addition, with reductions in MSE at 13% and 9% respectively. We also find that the improvements due to the addition of a University of Michigan sentiment measure are similar to those obtained using its Conference Board counterpart. Quite clearly, the message from the previous section is not only confirmed but also reinforced here: Even when considered in a rich information context, confi- dence matters when forecasting consumption. We then proceed with the second exercise, where we forecast consumption expenditure using a series of reconstructed data sets (with the first one ending in Jan. 1995) that reflect the varying data release schedules and publication lags across explanatory variables. Each month, for each pair of consumption and confidence, we make two sets of forecasts, one before we observe the confidence measure for that very month, and one after we observe it. By comparing the MSEs of the two sets of forecasts, we reveal the value of release timing and publication lag of the consumer confidence measures in forecasting consumption. With quarterly data, we place ourselves in six different points in time every quarter, namely the day of each of the three months of the quarter when the con- fidence measure is released (last Tuesday of the month for the Conference Board confidence measure and last Friday of the month for the University ofMichigan measure). On each of the three Tuesdays/Fridays, we make ten forecasts. Five of them (horizons 0 to 4) are based on the information set that includes this latest release of confidence measure, and the other five are based on the information set that does not. With monthly data, we make fourteen forecasts at the end of each month, seven of them (horizon 0 to 6) with the latest release of the confidence

17 measure, and the other seven without. For both quarterly and monthly models, horizon 0 always refers to the current period (quarter/month), horizon 1 refers to the immediate next quarter/month, etc. The results from this exercise are summarized in Table 3, where a relative MSE value that is smaller than 1 means that forecasts with the latest value of confidence have a smaller MSE. Table cells like this are again shaded. From the table, we observe that for both quarterly and monthly models, in 61% of the cases, the fore- casts made with the latest confidence measure have lower MSEs (with the average improvement being about 2% in monthly models and 5% in quarterly models). In most cases where an improvement in out-of-sample forecasting performance is observed, the dependent variable is either services or total consumption. This is consistent with the results from the previous exercise. It should be mentioned here that the improvement we get when we include the latest value of confidence is often not statistically significant. However, let’s recall that in this exercise the forecast improvements are based on an information set that is augmented in a very marginal way, i.e., with just one extra observation. Overall, even with this qualification, the broad picture that emerges from the results ofthis and the previous subsection is still one where confidence measures often lead to noticeable improvements in the accuracy of consumption forecasts. Such improve- ments can be attributed to both the information content of confidence measures and the timeliness of their releases. However, the effect of data revisions, i.e., the third determinant as discussed before, remains unaccounted for.

4.3 Forecasting Consumption in Real Time

In this exercise, we consider a more realistic setup, which allows us to examine the effect of all three determinants affecting the role of consumer confidence in forecasting consumption expenditure, i.e., the information content, the timing and lag of data releases, and data revisions. So, in contrast to the pseudo-real-time exercises of the previous subsection, here, we create a series of true real-time data 18 sets from March 2005 to September 2011 for the last Friday of each month for the University of Michigan sentiment measures, and for the last Tuesday of each month for the Conference Board confidence measures, using the stylized data release schedule and publication lags, as well as information on data revisions associated with the GRS data set. 11 We repeat this exercise for both quarterly and monthly consumption data, just like with all previous exercises. On each of the 79 Fridays (or Tuesdays) of our sample, we produce ten fore- casts, similar to the second exercise in the previous subsection. Table 4 presents the results. Similar to Table 3, shaded cells are ones in which the relative MSE is lower than 1, i.e., adding a consumer confidence measure improves the model’s performance. MSE numbers reported in bold are those that are statistically sig- nificant at 10% based on the modified Diebold-Mariano test. In a clear majority of cases, adding a confidence measure notably improves the real-time forecasting performance (72% of the time for quarterly models, with an average improvement of 4.3% and 53% of the time for monthly models, with an average improvement of 2.6%). In 16% of all cases, this improvement is statistically significant; con- versely, the instances in which adding a confidence measure leads to a statistically significant deterioration are very rare – only 4% of thetime. Of course, the same caveat applies here as with the previous exercise. We find it remarkable that augmenting such a large information set in such a marginal way (i.e., adding just one number) often leads to noticeable improvements in the fore- casts. Still, the obvious next step is to examine, in this realistic context as well, the effect of the entire confidence variable on the forecasts. Table 5 reports the results from an exercise where forecasts based on information sets that include a confidence variable are compared to those based on information sets without any confidence measure. Thus, this exercise considers the value of the complete time

11 All the details on the schedule of data releases and publication lags are available in GRS. The real-time data for earlier than March 2005 are not readily available for all variables. The real-time data set, updated every week, was kindly provided to us by David Small of the Federal Reserve Board. This is the same data set used by Giannone et al. (2010), except for a few proprietary series. 19 series of the confidence measure against the scenario where the consumer sentiment never existed at all. The evidence is overwhelming: In 100% of the time for quar- terly models, adding a confidence measure leads to improvements (with an average improvement of about 27%). Similarly, for monthly models, adding a confidence measure leads to improvements in 88% of the time (with an average improvement of 9%). In 55% of all cases, this improvement is statistically significant, while deteriorations that are statistically significant are very rare – only 1% of thetime. Two additional observations are in order here, as they relate to patterns that repeat in both this and previous exercises. First, looking across components of personal consumption expenditures, we note that most of the sizable improvements to the forecasting performance are for models of services and total consumption. Second, regarding the effect of data frequency on forecast accuracy, quarterly con- sumption data exhibit a bigger effect from the addition of confidence than the monthly models do, primarily because the latter is significantly more volatile than the quarterly series. Overall, the main results from these real-time exercises strongly establish the positive and significant effect of consumer confidence measures on the accuracy of consumption forecasts.

5 CONCLUDING REMARKS

In this paper, we reexamine the role of consumer confidence surveys in forecast- ing personal consumption expenditure. Existing models in the literature rely mostly on simple regressions and are limited in terms of data frequency, data vintages, and number of predictors used. So, in a first step, we revisit and extend these models using both quarterly and monthly data, both in real-time and using revised data vintages. Our exercises provide concrete evidence, in a more realistic and general context, of the notable contribution of confidence measures to the in-sample fitof personal consumption expenditure. We then further consider the ability of confidence to forecast consumption in 20 a even more robust way that accounts for data frequency and vintage issues in a rich information context. We use a dynamic factor model with nearly 200 ex- planatory variables in a real-time jagged-edge data set. In this framework, we first examine the effect of the whole confidence series on the in-sample fit. Then, we examine the contribution of the latest release of consumer confidence measures on out-of-sample forecast accuracy, accounting for varying release schedules and publication lags for all explanatory variables. Lastly, we perform our most realistic forecasting exercise that helps to unveil the real-time effect of consumer confidence on the consumption forecasts. The results from our analysis establish that measures of consumer confidence in general make a notable and positive contribution in forecasting personal consumption expenditure. Note that one of the central implications of PIH/RE is that current consump- tion should reflect all available information in real time, and hence its growth should be independent of all dated information including sentiment. Using house- hold data underlying the ICS matched to Consumer Expenditure Survey, Souleles (2004) establishes a similar result and attributes part of the rejection of PIH/RE to the demographic components in forecast errors. Based on pooled household data over 1977:01-2010:03, Lahiri & Zhao (2013) find that overwhelmingly the most important set of factors that move consumer sentiment are the perceptions and expectations of households regarding their own financial conditions and that of the economy – leaving only a limited role for the demographic characteristics and available macro data. These results support the view of Blendon (1997) that consumer expectations are formed in “conversations between neighbors over the backyard fence” and are not a direct reflection of media coverage or readily avail- able official statistics. This reinforces the point made by Souleles that muchof this important information in the cross-sectional distributions of sentiment is lost in the process of aggregation, and that there are factors other than demographic characteristics that are important in explaining the excess sensitivity of consump- tion to sentiment. What our results imply is that it is the time-varying asymmetry

21 in the cross-sectional distributions in expected financial conditions, unemployment expectations, and non-economic waves of optimism and pessimism, etc., that is making sentiment significant in time series forecasting of consumption growth.

References

Akerlof, G. A., & Shiller, R. J. (2010). Animal Spirits. Princeton University Press. Al-Eyd, A., Barrell, R., & Davis, E. P. (2009). Consumer Confidence Indicies and Short-Term Forecasting of Consumption. The Manchester School, 77, 96–111. Banbura, M., Giannone, D., Modugno, M., & Reichlin, L. (2013). Now-Casting and the Real-Time Data-Flow. In G. Elliott, & A. Timmermann (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Forecasting. Elsevier-North Holland volume 2. Blendon, R. J. (1997). Bridging the Gap between the Piblic’s and ’ Views of the Economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 105–118. Bram, J., & Ludvigson, S. (1998). Does Consumer Confidence Forecast Household Expenditure? A sentiment index horse race. Federal Reserve Bank of New York, . Carroll, C. D., Fuhrer, J. C., & Wilcox, D. W. (1994). Does Consumer Sentiment Forecast Household Spending? If So, Why? American Economic Review, 84, 1397–1408. Chua, C. (2009). Can Consumer Sentiment and its Components Forecast Australian GDP and Consumption? Journal of Forecasting, 28, 698–711. Clark, T. E., & McCracken, M. W. (2013). Testing for Unconditional Predictive Ability. In G. Elliott, & A. Timmermann (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Fore- casting. Elsevier-North Holland volume 2. Croushore, D. (2005). Do Consumer Confidence Indexes Help Forecast Consumer Spending in Real Time? North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 16, 435–450. Croushore, D., & Stark, T. (2001). A Real-Time Data Set for Macroeconomists. Journal of , 105, 111–130. 22 Curtin, R. (2007). Consumer Sentiment Surveys: Worldwide Review and Assess- ment. Journal of Business Cycle Measurement and Analysis, 1, 7–42. Dees, S., & Brinca, P. S. (2011). Consumer Confidence as a Predictor of Consump- tion Spending: Evidence for the United States and The Euro Area. ECB Working Paper, 1349. Diebold, F. X., & Mariano, R. S. (1995). Comparing Predictive Accuracy. Journal of Business and , 13, 253–263. Dreger, C., & Kholodilin, K. (2010). Forecasting Consumption. DIW Berlin dis- cussion paper, 1066. Easaw, J., Garratt, D., & Heravi, S. (2005). Does consumer sentiment accurately forecast UK household consumption? Are there any comparisons to be made with the US? Journal of , 27, 517–532. Fuhrer, J. C. (1993). What Role Does Consumer Sentiment Play in the U.S. Macroeconomy? New England Economic Review, (pp. 32–44). Giannone, D., Modugno, M., Reichlin, L., & Small, D. (2010). Nowcasting in Real-Time. Paper presented at the 16th International Conference on Computing in Economics and Finance, Society for , London, UK. July 13,. Giannone, D., Reichlin, L., & Simonelli, S. (2009). Nowcasting Euro Area Eco- nomic Activity in Real Time: The Role of Confidence Indicator. National Insti- tute Economic Review, 210, 90–97. Giannone, D., Reichlin, L., & Small, D. (2008). Nowcasting: The Real-Time In- formational Content of Macroeconomic Data. Journal of , 55, 665–676. Harvey, A., Leybourne, S. J., & Newbold, P. (1997). Testing the Equality of Predic- tion Mean Squared Errors. International Journal of Forecasting, 13, 281–291. Howrey, E. P. (2001). The Predictive Power of the Index of Consumer Sentiment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 175–216. Ivanova, D., & Lahiri, K. (2001). When Should We Care About Consumer Senti-

23 ment? Evidence From Linear and Markov-Switching Models. Indian Economic Review (An issue in honor of Victor Zarnowitz), 36, 153–169. Katona, G. (1951). Psychological Analysis of Economic Behavior. New York: McGraw-Hill. Lahiri, K., & Monokroussos, G. (2013). Nowcasting US GDP: The Role of ISM Business Surveys. International Journal of Forecasting, Forthcoming. Lahiri, K., & Zhao, Y. (2013). Factors Determining Consumer Sentiment – Evi- dence from Household Survey Data. Department of Economics working paper, University at Albany, SUNY,. Leeper, E. M. (1992). Consumer Attitudes: King for a Day. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review, 77, 1–16. Ludvigson, S. (2004). Consumer Confidence and Consumer Spending. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18, 29–50. Malgarini, M., & Margani, P. (2007). Psychology, Consumer Sentiment and Household Expenditures: A Disaggregated Analysis. , 39, 1719–1729. Orphanides, A. (2001). Monetary Policy Rules Based on Real-Time Data. Ameri- can Economic Review, 91, 964–985. Souleles, N. S. (2004). Expectations, Heterogeneous Forecast Errors, and Con- sumption: Micro Evidence from the Michigan Consumer Sentiment Surveys. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 36, 39–72. Starr, M. (2012). Consumption, Sentiment, and Economic News. Economic In- quiry, 50, 1097–1111. Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2011). Dynamic Factor Models. In M. P. Clements, & D. F. Hendry (Eds.), Oxford Handbook on Economic Forecasting. Oxford University Press. Wilcox, J. (2007). Forecasting Components of Consumption with Components of Consumer Sentiment. , 42, 36–46.

24 Table 1. Incremental Explanatory Power of Sentiment/Confidence Measures

This table gives the incremental ̅ (Inc ̅ ; positive means adding sentiment measure increases explanatory power), the sum of coefficients of four lags ( ̂) of sentiment measure, and the p-value of the test of their joint significance ( ). Newey-West standard errors are used with 4 lags. The p-values in bold are those smaller than 0.1. Dependent variable is [ln(PCEt)-ln(PCEt-1)]*400 for quarterly models and is [ln(PCEt)-ln(PCEt-1)]*1200 for monthly models. The sample covers Jan 1982 to July 2011.

Monthly Model (Revised Data) Quarterly Model (Revised Data) Quarterly Model (Real-Time Data)

PCE and Sentiment No Additional Variables With Additional Variables No Additional Variables With Additional Variables No Additional Variables With Additional Variables Component Inc ̅ ̂ Inc ̅ ̂ Inc ̅ ̂ Inc ̅ ̂ Inc ̅ ̂ Inc ̅ ̂

CB Exp. 0.026 0.351 0.014 0.037 0.514 0.002 0.052 0.081 0.028 0.030 0.257 0.105 0.041 0.085 0.088 0.032 0.231 0.329

CB Index 0.009 0.078 0.132 0.012 0.141 0.055 0.070 -0.011 0.006 0.037 0.014 0.022 0.051 -0.002 0.029 0.042 0.033 0.111 Durable Goods UM Exp. 0.026 0.461 0.004 0.030 0.587 0.001 0.052 0.128 0.063 0.001 0.131 0.241 0.055 0.131 0.087 0.045 0.204 0.222

UM Index 0.018 0.383 0.025 0.024 0.533 0.006 0.063 0.073 0.034 0.010 0.088 0.238 0.069 0.087 0.061 0.060 0.159 0.140

CB Exp. 0.029 0.104 0.011 0.038 0.127 0.005 0.009 0.021 0.516 0.026 0.070 0.280 0.023 0.001 0.169 0.048 0.078 0.134

CB Index 0.006 0.034 0.155 0.007 0.039 0.141 0.032 -0.002 0.179 0.028 0.008 0.311 0.005 -0.009 0.425 0.037 0.020 0.133 Non-Durable Goods

25 UM Exp. 0.032 0.138 0.001 0.030 0.145 0.003 0.035 0.034 0.097 0.005 0.046 0.234 0.013 0.012 0.200 0.023 0.058 0.221

UM Index 0.031 0.133 0.004 0.027 0.142 0.007 0.034 0.028 0.124 0.004 0.042 0.407 0.022 0.000 0.134 0.030 0.052 0.185

CB Exp. 0.044 0.061 0.001 0.035 0.061 0.000 0.052 0.043 0.035 0.039 0.046 0.054 0.174 0.031 0.000 0.091 0.022 0.000

CB Index 0.012 0.015 0.087 0.007 0.015 0.153 0.022 0.008 0.115 0.014 0.009 0.172 0.138 0.016 0.000 0.083 0.017 0.000 Services UM Exp. 0.026 0.053 0.016 0.022 0.058 0.009 0.027 0.034 0.122 0.019 0.036 0.209 0.126 0.032 0.000 0.071 0.025 0.000

UM Index 0.027 0.053 0.005 0.024 0.058 0.009 0.038 0.036 0.070 0.027 0.039 0.096 0.130 0.037 0.000 0.062 0.030 0.000

CB Exp. 0.064 0.120 0.000 0.074 0.147 0.000 0.037 0.027 0.068 0.016 0.048 0.189 0.077 0.026 0.008 0.057 0.055 0.099

CB Index 0.017 0.032 0.054 0.016 0.039 0.038 0.035 -0.001 0.103 0.016 0.000 0.197 0.055 0.004 0.036 0.056 0.014 0.038 Total UM Exp. 0.052 0.134 0.000 0.056 0.156 0.000 0.033 0.034 0.182 0.001 0.019 0.365 0.087 0.043 0.024 0.073 0.047 0.060

UM Index 0.041 0.123 0.003 0.046 0.147 0.000 0.039 0.023 0.136 0.004 0.010 0.399 0.098 0.032 0.018 0.081 0.041 0.051

Table 2. Relative MSEs of In-Sample Predictions With/Without Consumer Sentiment/Confidence

This table shows the relative MSE of in-sample predictions made with and without consumer sentiment/confidence measure. Relative MSE is the ratio between models with sentiment and models without sentiment, i.e., relative MSE smaller than 1 means adding sentiment measure improves the fit/predictive performance. Shaded cells are those in which the relative MSE is smaller than 1. The relative MSEs and p-values in bold are those where one-sided DM test rejects at 10%. Benchmark RMSE is that from the benchmark model where no confidence measure is included. The sample covers Jan 1982 to July 2011.

Monthly Model (Revised Data) Quarterly Model (Revised Data)

PCE and Component Data Series Sentiment Benchmark Relative Benchmark Relative p-value p-value RMSE MSE RMSE MSE Expectations 0.999 0.390 0.952 0.112 Conference Board Durable Overall Index 0.998 0.349 0.974 0.177 32.336 9.736 Goods Expectations 0.997 0.292 0.956 0.112 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.998 0.358 0.966 0.153

Expectations 0.993 0.417 0.964 0.173 Conference Board Non-Durable Overall Index 0.991 0.365 0.950 0.160 7.683 2.214 Goods Expectations 0.991 0.354 0.939 0.124 26 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.991 0.344 0.935 0.115

Expectations 0.934 0.008 0.763 0.001 Conference Board Overall Index 0.960 0.036 0.835 0.015 Services 3.353 1.381 Expectations 0.935 0.009 0.785 0.004 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.933 0.007 0.767 0.003

Expectations 0.987 0.090 0.836 0.009 Conference Board Overall Index 0.989 0.102 0.885 0.028 Total 5.809 1.929 Expectations 0.982 0.053 0.833 0.009 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.984 0.066 0.838 0.012

Table 3. Relative MSEs of Out-of-Sample Predictions With/Without the Latest Consumer Sentiment/Confidence

This table shows the relative MSE of out-of-sample predictions made with and without the latest release (i.e., on value) of consumer sentiment/confidence measure. Relative MSE is the ratio between models with sentiment and models without sentiment, i.e., relative MSE smaller than 1 means adding sentiment measure improves the fit/predictive performance. Shaded cells are those in which the relative MSE is smaller than 1. The p-values in bold means two-sided DM test rejection at 10%. Training sample starts from Jan 1982. Evaluation sample covers Jan 1995 to July 2011.

Monthly Quarterly PCE and Data Sentiment First Month of a Quarter Second Month of a Quarter Third Month of a Quarter Component Series H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 H=5 H=6 H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 Expectations 0.979 0.987 1.015 0.990 0.999 1.003 1.012 0.961 0.922 0.966 1.101 0.975 0.981 0.939 0.975 1.106 0.969 1.015 0.955 0.987 1.106 0.965 Conference Board Overall Index 0.987 1.000 1.007 0.996 1.000 1.001 1.003 0.963 0.986 0.971 1.043 0.969 0.973 0.993 0.974 1.044 0.971 0.986 0.998 0.975 1.043 0.970 Durable Goods Expectations 0.984 0.988 1.008 1.000 0.994 1.008 0.997 0.992 0.981 0.940 1.090 0.929 1.006 0.989 0.946 1.090 0.928 1.030 0.998 0.955 1.090 0.928 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.979 0.994 1.006 1.003 0.994 1.011 0.996 0.945 0.997 0.925 1.085 0.929 0.958 1.003 0.929 1.086 0.928 0.981 1.010 0.935 1.085 0.926

Expectations 0.975 0.997 1.008 1.000 1.007 0.998 1.010 0.920 1.011 1.005 0.953 0.984 0.944 1.019 1.016 0.959 0.980 0.978 1.033 1.027 0.968 0.980 Conference Board Overall Index 0.991 1.003 1.003 1.000 1.001 0.998 1.002 0.960 0.991 0.978 0.964 0.943 0.973 0.998 0.984 0.968 0.942 0.990 1.004 0.990 0.972 0.943 Non-Durable Goods Expectations 0.988 0.995 1.000 0.997 1.003 0.998 1.008 0.965 0.957 1.074 0.916 0.958 0.986 0.965 1.076 0.921 0.956 1.014 0.971 1.081 0.929 0.957 27 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.986 0.997 0.998 1.000 1.000 1.002 1.004 0.943 0.963 1.038 0.933 0.917 0.961 0.970 1.039 0.936 0.915 0.988 0.975 1.043 0.943 0.915

Expectations 0.917 0.957 1.028 0.986 0.955 1.018 1.013 0.905 0.848 0.944 0.894 0.924 0.943 0.881 0.970 0.911 0.937 0.976 0.914 0.997 0.928 0.955 Conference Board Overall Index 0.956 0.975 1.017 0.988 0.981 0.996 1.007 1.009 0.978 0.980 0.937 0.920 1.031 0.995 0.989 0.944 0.926 1.049 1.009 0.997 0.951 0.934 Services Expectations 0.959 0.951 1.002 1.012 0.978 0.968 1.027 0.957 0.909 0.984 0.917 0.902 0.978 0.926 0.996 0.924 0.909 0.993 0.940 1.010 0.932 0.920 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.964 0.945 1.037 0.981 0.981 0.969 1.006 0.974 0.910 0.948 0.929 0.873 0.996 0.927 0.956 0.934 0.879 1.013 0.941 0.967 0.941 0.887

Expectations 0.929 0.980 1.036 0.974 0.992 1.012 1.029 0.866 0.874 0.941 1.057 0.923 0.917 0.908 0.965 1.064 0.927 0.985 0.940 0.993 1.073 0.937 Conference Board Overall Index 0.963 0.997 1.017 0.989 0.997 0.999 1.010 0.939 0.978 0.959 0.994 0.929 0.963 0.995 0.967 0.998 0.933 0.989 1.008 0.974 1.001 0.936 Total Expectations 0.958 0.967 1.012 1.000 0.985 1.006 1.009 0.927 0.927 0.966 1.010 0.892 0.959 0.946 0.978 1.013 0.896 1.000 0.963 0.995 1.019 0.902 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.949 0.975 1.022 0.997 0.984 1.015 0.997 0.863 0.945 0.927 1.029 0.855 0.891 0.962 0.935 1.030 0.857 0.927 0.978 0.946 1.034 0.862

Table 4. Relative MSEs of Real-Time Forecasts With/Without the Latest Consumer Sentiment/Confidence

This table shows the relative MSE of real-time forecasts made with and without the latest release (i.e., on value) consumer sentiment/confidence measure. Relative MSE is the ratio between models with sentiment and models without sentiment, i.e., relative MSE smaller than 1 means adding sentiment measure improves the fit/predictive performance. Shaded cells are those in which the relative MSE is smaller than 1. The p-values in bold means two-sided DM test rejection at 10%. Training sample starts from Jan 1982. Evaluation sample covers Mar 2005 to July 2011.

Monthly Quarterly PCE and Data Sentiment First Month of a Quarter Second Month of a Quarter Third Month of a Quarter Component Series H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 H=5 H=6 H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 Expectations 0.958 0.990 1.031 0.975 0.994 1.005 1.036 0.894 0.946 0.929 1.010 1.042 1.029 0.938 0.963 1.021 1.027 1.059 0.955 0.973 1.019 1.007 Conference Board Overall Index 0.981 1.001 1.008 0.991 0.998 0.997 1.007 0.962 0.981 0.980 0.999 1.006 0.994 0.981 0.989 1.005 1.007 1.005 0.984 0.989 1.003 0.998 Durable Goods Expectations 0.982 0.983 1.012 1.004 0.983 1.016 0.995 0.975 0.975 0.943 1.029 1.004 1.031 0.961 0.954 1.014 0.985 1.035 0.961 0.967 1.013 0.983 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.974 0.997 1.017 0.997 0.981 1.022 0.993 0.963 0.988 0.955 1.031 1.010 1.004 0.966 0.953 1.013 0.991 1.028 0.966 0.964 1.016 0.981

Expectations 0.957 1.051 1.007 1.010 1.027 0.974 1.029 0.922 1.018 0.919 0.974 1.015 0.980 1.023 0.951 1.021 0.993 0.996 1.040 0.970 1.022 0.978 Conference Board Overall Index 0.979 1.027 0.997 1.007 1.005 0.980 1.002 0.956 1.002 0.963 0.981 1.004 0.989 1.006 0.972 0.991 0.997 0.994 1.009 0.978 0.989 0.990 Non-Durable Goods Expectations 0.978 1.032 0.972 1.020 1.001 0.997 1.016 0.955 0.980 0.994 0.982 0.997 0.999 0.992 1.001 0.995 0.967 1.007 0.996 0.999 1.007 0.970 28 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.987 1.042 0.958 1.041 0.978 1.013 1.002 0.949 0.993 0.984 0.997 1.004 0.988 0.993 0.990 0.991 0.960 1.000 1.001 0.991 1.003 0.962

Expectations 1.082 0.954 1.031 0.983 0.942 1.024 1.002 1.057 0.765 0.795 0.879 1.056 1.221 0.884 0.924 0.952 1.070 1.151 0.876 0.957 0.991 1.045 Conference Board Overall Index 0.964 0.957 1.005 0.976 0.979 0.994 0.987 0.956 0.926 0.934 0.959 0.989 0.999 0.952 0.967 0.974 0.994 0.993 0.962 0.971 0.980 0.988 Services Expectations 1.008 0.959 1.025 0.968 0.965 0.992 1.008 0.957 0.832 0.853 0.918 0.932 1.074 0.862 0.906 0.942 0.933 1.062 0.882 0.935 0.998 0.951 University of Michigan Overall Index 1.005 0.952 1.052 0.938 0.969 1.011 0.976 1.019 0.834 0.861 0.940 0.954 1.059 0.860 0.873 0.936 0.919 1.066 0.907 0.933 0.998 0.948

Expectations 0.887 0.985 1.047 0.954 1.000 1.001 1.057 0.818 0.891 0.845 0.973 1.048 1.096 0.911 0.928 1.012 1.023 1.118 0.944 0.960 1.017 0.998 Conference Board Overall Index 0.938 1.003 1.014 0.979 0.996 0.982 1.011 0.926 0.967 0.944 0.987 0.997 0.988 0.974 0.966 0.993 0.996 1.000 0.979 0.973 0.991 0.986 Total Expectations 0.945 0.965 1.004 1.021 0.967 1.004 1.005 0.929 0.928 0.905 1.000 0.973 1.052 0.931 0.932 0.999 0.939 1.071 0.935 0.955 1.016 0.949 University of Michigan Overall Index 0.942 0.981 1.017 1.008 0.955 1.027 0.976 0.934 0.955 0.907 1.025 0.984 1.013 0.936 0.916 0.997 0.931 1.060 0.945 0.946 1.018 0.938

Table 5. Relative MSEs of Real-Time Forecasts With/Without the Consumer Sentiment/Confidence Variable

This table shows the relative MSE of real-time forecasts made with and without the consumer sentiment/confidence measure (i.e., the sentiment variable, not just the last observation of the variable). Relative MSE is the ratio between models with sentiment and models without sentiment, i.e., relative MSE smaller than 1 means adding sentiment measure improves the fit/predictive performance. Shaded cells are those in which the relative MSE is smaller than 1. The p-values in bold means one-sided DM test rejection at 10%. Training sample starts from Jan 1982. Evaluation sample covers Mar 2005 to July 2011.

Monthly Quarterly PCE and Data Sentiment First Month of a Quarter Second Month of a Quarter Third Month of a Quarter Component Series H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 H=5 H=6 H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4 H=0 H=1 H=2 H=3 H=4

Conference Expectations 0.954 0.999 1.007 0.976 0.998 1.003 0.986 0.674 0.836 0.815 0.888 0.977 0.774 0.808 0.840 0.869 0.924 0.913 0.814 0.869 0.902 0.899 Board Durable Overall Index 0.976 1.001 0.999 0.993 0.997 0.998 0.990 0.905 0.963 0.938 0.941 0.942 0.924 0.960 0.946 0.941 0.933 0.962 0.979 0.969 0.960 0.931 Goods University of Expectations 0.974 1.000 1.005 1.002 0.997 1.018 0.996 0.789 0.870 0.829 0.904 0.896 0.844 0.863 0.841 0.887 0.866 0.910 0.859 0.858 0.903 0.842 Michigan Overall Index 0.977 1.019 1.012 1.003 1.003 1.026 0.997 0.779 0.900 0.850 0.923 0.925 0.811 0.889 0.858 0.904 0.893 0.895 0.887 0.872 0.919 0.856

Conference Expectations 0.978 1.037 0.984 0.967 0.965 0.941 0.961 0.804 0.832 0.769 0.783 0.871 0.861 0.847 0.780 0.783 0.861 0.941 0.900 0.799 0.816 0.848 Board Non-Durable Overall Index 0.956 0.982 0.955 0.947 0.947 0.945 0.954 0.852 0.879 0.884 0.909 0.955 0.877 0.883 0.878 0.901 0.957 0.925 0.928 0.893 0.924 0.952 29 Goods University of Expectations 0.820 0.989 0.971 0.967 0.944 0.984 0.971 0.802 0.825 0.867 0.791 0.873 0.871 0.852 0.865 0.794 0.851 0.918 0.871 0.869 0.812 0.846 Michigan Overall Index 0.821 0.977 0.956 0.965 0.921 0.983 0.957 0.752 0.801 0.828 0.797 0.879 0.821 0.826 0.823 0.789 0.847 0.882 0.852 0.832 0.801 0.834

Conference Expectations 0.862 0.770 0.787 0.749 0.758 0.802 0.767 0.414 0.320 0.357 0.411 0.442 0.520 0.393 0.378 0.415 0.473 0.586 0.462 0.409 0.441 0.493 Board Overall Index 0.833 0.835 0.867 0.840 0.848 0.870 0.860 0.654 0.553 0.590 0.645 0.695 0.668 0.588 0.581 0.634 0.702 0.728 0.670 0.582 0.637 0.706 Services University of Expectations 0.820 0.789 0.809 0.778 0.798 0.821 0.821 0.436 0.387 0.471 0.511 0.531 0.433 0.405 0.448 0.487 0.530 0.501 0.470 0.459 0.510 0.547 Michigan Overall Index 0.820 0.785 0.810 0.753 0.794 0.815 0.795 0.460 0.347 0.415 0.479 0.485 0.428 0.368 0.375 0.443 0.476 0.526 0.471 0.405 0.467 0.494

Conference Expectations 0.802 0.893 0.906 0.851 0.880 0.872 0.825 0.428 0.561 0.540 0.614 0.641 0.551 0.580 0.577 0.606 0.638 0.713 0.634 0.629 0.637 0.634 Board Overall Index 0.870 0.933 0.931 0.903 0.912 0.912 0.889 0.731 0.779 0.762 0.798 0.806 0.749 0.793 0.770 0.793 0.812 0.820 0.851 0.801 0.811 0.810 Total University of Expectations 0.793 0.887 0.913 0.896 0.877 0.921 0.873 0.539 0.631 0.628 0.662 0.657 0.606 0.641 0.631 0.650 0.640 0.673 0.667 0.658 0.670 0.643 Michigan Overall Index 0.798 0.900 0.915 0.881 0.869 0.925 0.849 0.519 0.635 0.603 0.665 0.659 0.555 0.638 0.598 0.642 0.632 0.649 0.678 0.631 0.661 0.625

Figure 1. Sentiment Measures and Total Consumption Growth

This figure shows the overall index (top) and the expectations index (bottom) of both the University of Michigan (UM, dotted line) and the Conference Board (CB, thin solid line) measure (both on left axis), compared with 12-month moving average of annualized monthly percentage growth in real total personal consumption expenditure (PCE Total, thick solid line, on right axis).

4 140

3 120

2 100

1 80

0 60

40 -1 CB Overall Index UM Overall Index PCE Total MA 20 -2

1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

140 4

120 3

100 2

80 1

60 0

40 -1 CB Expectations UM Expectations PCE Total MA 20 -2

1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

30