Elite Groups in Russia

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Elite Groups in Russia Elite Groups in Russia VIRGINIE COULLOUDON ince 1992, Russia has been inventing its own version of democracy. The Con- Sstitutional Court acts as a supreme judicial authority; a freely elected presi- dent acts as the head of state; a democratically elected parliament is elaborating laws; and a free press exposes the abuses of Russian politicians. Despite the exis- tence of new democratic institutions, Russian officials sometimes seem to let themselves be guided by arbitrariness.1 The notion that the rule of law should pre- vail over private interests is new in Russia and is shared by only a few politicians.2 The debate on the exact role of the institutions in the decisionmaking process prevails in contemporary research on the Russian elite. There are two opposite approaches: The first emphasizes that the Communist regime collapsed only recently and explains the lack of influence of institutions such as the Constitu- tional Court or the bicameral parliament by the absence of democratic tradition in Russia. Referring to the actual transitional period, such an approach implies that Russian democratic institutions have an important role of education in the actual state building. It considers of secondary importance the fact that those insti- tutions lack influence on the decisionmaking process. The second point of view emphasizes the supremacy of the Russian presiden- tial decrees over laws and legislative documents. It points out that the 1993 con- stitution offers more powers to the president than to the parliament and gives him the last word in all circumstances.3 This approach emphasizes the strategic role not only of the executive power but also of interest groups likely to act as advis- ers to this same executive power. Since 1992, many scholars have detailed the emergence of new interest groups. There have been numerous studies of the new Russian industrial managers and bankers.4 Konstantin Mikulsky has specifically concentrated on Russian busi- nessmen, showing by in-depth interviews how they consider their own role in the new Russian society.5 Surveys have also been published on the development of the Russian provinces and the role of local elites in regional and federal deci- sionmaking.6 Among Western scholars, Amy Knight writes that the new security Virginie Coulloudon is directing a research project entitled “The Elite and Patronage in Russia” at the Davis Center for Russian Studies at Harvard University. She would like to thank the Smith Richardson Foundation for its help in conducting this project. 535 536 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA service functions the same way the KGB did and is accountable not to state inter- ests but to individuals.7 In this approach, “individuals” is the key word. Because legislation is poorly applied, local governors often make their own rules, and decrees are considered more important than laws. Representatives of the executive and their advisers have a key role in decisionmaking. The main issue raised by sociologists is whether these individuals are part of a new elite or should be considered simply as representatives of the former nomenklatura. To study them, many have done quantitative research. Here again, two points of view prevail. Olga Kryshtanovskaya and Yuri Burtin subscribe, for example, to what East European scholars call the “theory of elite reproduction.”8 This the- ory suggests that the institutional changes that have taken place in Russia since 1991 have not deeply altered the composition of the elite, which continues to grow in membership. The theory of elite reproduction recognizes that the elite may have to adapt to maintain its status, but it holds that the previous elite pos- sesses the capacities to remain at the top of the social order.9 Focusing on the elite since perestroika, Kryshtanovskaya emphasizes that the power of the party-state nomenklatura now lies in its private ownership of eco- nomic property.10 Burtin also argues that under President Boris Yeltsin the nomen- klatura survives as a socioprofessional group that administers the state, possess- es and distributes its riches, and shares the same political and economic interests.11 None of them denies that the rule of nomenklatura and its privileges are the stuff of bygone days. But they agree with a survey conducted in 1994 by the Russian Academy of Sciences’ Institute of Sociology that shows that the old nomenklatura represents 75 percent of Yeltsin’s closest political allies, 60 percent of the parliament, 74 percent of the government, 41 percent of the businessmen, and 83 percent of the regional leaders.12 As those scholars see it, members of the new elite have slipped quite naturally from the old power structures into the new ones, forging their own links with industry and the military. A new network of vested interests, special pleading, and patronage has been created within a polit- ical infrastructure. Another approach, referred to as “elite circulation theory,” argues that institu- tional changes have generated substantial turnover among the elite. This theory holds that the factors that promoted mobility within the elite before 1989 are no longer operational and that new processes are at work that have dislodged old elite from its command posts and replaced it with a new elite holding a new set of attributes.13 Among the supporters of the “elite circulation theory” are Angus Roxburgh and Barbara Green, who study the political confrontation between Yeltsin and Soviet President Mikhail Gorbachev and the emergence of a new political elite in Russia.14 Boris Kagarlitsky focuses on the debates of the Moscow city parliament to describe the behavior and views of the new local political elite.15 Russian sociologists N. Lapina and Konstantin Mikulsky prefer to con- centrate on the reasons for the formation of a new elite from a sociological point of view.16 Elite Groups in Russia 537 None of these scholars denies that the Russian elite is progressively creating a clanlike mentality.17 Many Russian scholars and political analysts argue that it is these clans, as opposed to formal political institutions, that exercise real power.18 In 1996, in an interview with Moscow News, Grigory Yavlinsky claimed that the ministers of the Yeltsin government are agents of large monopolies and various oligarchic clan groups in Russia.19 Even First Deputy Prime Minister Boris Nemtsov agrees with the notion that an oligarchic capitalism rules the coun- try.20 A growing number of articles in the Russian press are devoted to this topic. As one Moscow newspaper pointed out earlier this year, “the main threat to Rus- sia comes neither from communists nor from fascists, but from the rise of an oli- garchy.”21 The aim of this article is to explore the elite groups often qualified as “clans” by the Russian press. Examining their structure and the background of their representatives, I will show that these groups do not constitute a single elite ruling the country but several elites struggling for power and thus reproducing traditional patterns of behavior. A Set of Clans By constantly referring to the “Cosa Nostra” or to the “ruling oligarchy,” the Russian press gives the false impression of a monolithic elite.22 That notion does not help to explain why the Russian president so frequently changes his mind and even signs documents and decrees contradicting one another. To understand deci- sionmaking in Russia, one must consider the profusion and fluidity of elite groups. In fact, one could speak about sets of clans stretching out to the state structures and the civil society’s informal networks. The difficulty of following the evolution of the clans lies in the existence of three different levels of con- nection: federal, sector-related (within a single industrial or economic branch), and micro (within a single ministry or private organization). On a micro level, inside a ministry, an organization, or a plant, the most impor- tant connections for building a career are family or friendship links, a tradition inherited from the Soviet times. Under the Soviet regime, family and friendship connections were one of the main criteria for co-optation at all levels of the CPSU (Communist Party) hierarchy. Consider the professional and political career of Yuri Skokov. The son of a KGB officer, Skokov was born in the southern Krasnodar region. High-ranking political protectors, such as Politburo member Vitaly Vorotnikov and Politburo deputy member Georgy Razumovsky, helped him to start a career in the military industrial complex. He was appointed direc- tor of one of the local subcontractors of the giant Kvant complex. Because he was already at the top of the plant hierarchy, he was summoned to Moscow to take over from the Kvant director who, after thirty years at the head of the factory, was relegated to the position of a mere foreman. Skokov immediately started to reor- ganize the plant. Although Kvant was still heavily depending on state orders, the new director promised to try a new form of management. In line with Gorbachev’s perestroika, his program pleased both the Soviet president and Yeltsin, then first party secretary in Moscow. Skokov was elected deputy in 1989, and three years later became the first secretary of Russia’s new Security Council. He was sacked 538 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA for political reasons to please the reformers, but remained an informal adviser to the president. Now president of the Federation of Consumer Goods Producers, his friendship with the president gives him access to the Kremlin. Under the Soviet regime, family connections have helped bureaucrats to become rich and politicians to propel themselves to the highest echelons of power. But after the collapse of the Soviet Union, when the ruling elite was trying to stay in power, it became obvious that family connections had less influence on the fed- eral level.
Recommended publications
  • Questions to Russian Archives – Short
    The Raoul Wallenberg Research Initiative RWI-70 Formal Request to the Russian Government and Archival Authorities on the Raoul Wallenberg Case Pending Questions about Documentation on the 1 Raoul Wallenberg Case in the Russian Archives Photo Credit: Raoul Wallenberg’s photo on a visa application he filed in June 1943 with the Hungarian Legation, Stockholm. Source: The Hungarian National Archives, Budapest. 1 This text is authored by Dr. Vadim Birstein and Susanne Berger. It is based on the paper by V. Birstein and S. Berger, entitled “Das Schicksal Raoul Wallenbergs – Die Wissenslücken.” Auf den Spuren Wallenbergs, Stefan Karner (Hg.). Innsbruck: StudienVerlag, 2015. S. 117-141; the English version of the paper with the title “The Fate of Raoul Wallenberg: Gaps in Our Current Knowledge” is available at http://www.vbirstein.com. Previously many of the questions cited in this document were raised in some form by various experts and researchers. Some have received partial answers, but not to the degree that they could be removed from this list of open questions. 1 I. FSB (Russian Federal Security Service) Archival Materials 1. Interrogation Registers and “Prisoner no. 7”2 1) The key question is: What happened to Raoul Wallenberg after his last known presence in Lubyanka Prison (also known as Inner Prison – the main investigation prison of the Soviet State Security Ministry, MGB, in Moscow) allegedly on March 11, 1947? At the time, Wallenberg was investigated by the 4th Department of the 3rd MGB Main Directorate (military counterintelligence);
    [Show full text]
  • The Russia You Never Met
    The Russia You Never Met MATT BIVENS AND JONAS BERNSTEIN fter staggering to reelection in summer 1996, President Boris Yeltsin A announced what had long been obvious: that he had a bad heart and needed surgery. Then he disappeared from view, leaving his prime minister, Viktor Cher- nomyrdin, and his chief of staff, Anatoly Chubais, to mind the Kremlin. For the next few months, Russians would tune in the morning news to learn if the presi- dent was still alive. Evenings they would tune in Chubais and Chernomyrdin to hear about a national emergency—no one was paying their taxes. Summer turned to autumn, but as Yeltsin’s by-pass operation approached, strange things began to happen. Chubais and Chernomyrdin suddenly announced the creation of a new body, the Cheka, to help the government collect taxes. In Lenin’s day, the Cheka was the secret police force—the forerunner of the KGB— that, among other things, forcibly wrested food and money from the peasantry and drove some of them into collective farms or concentration camps. Chubais made no apologies, saying that he had chosen such a historically weighted name to communicate the seriousness of the tax emergency.1 Western governments nod- ded their collective heads in solemn agreement. The International Monetary Fund and the World Bank both confirmed that Russia was experiencing a tax collec- tion emergency and insisted that serious steps be taken.2 Never mind that the Russian government had been granting enormous tax breaks to the politically connected, including billions to Chernomyrdin’s favorite, Gazprom, the natural gas monopoly,3 and around $1 billion to Chubais’s favorite, Uneximbank,4 never mind the horrendous corruption that had been bleeding the treasury dry for years, or the nihilistic and pointless (and expensive) destruction of Chechnya.
    [Show full text]
  • Privatization in Russia: Catalyst for the Elite
    PRIVATIZATION IN RUSSIA: CATALYST FOR THE ELITE VIRGINIE COULLOUDON During the fall of 1997, the Russian press exposed a corruption scandal in- volving First Deputy Prime Minister Anatoli Chubais, and several other high- ranking officials of the Russian government.' In a familiar scenario, news organizations run by several bankers involved in the privatization process published compromising material that prompted the dismissal of the politi- 2 cians on bribery charges. The main significance of the so-called "Chubais affair" is not that it pro- vides further evidence of corruption in Russia. Rather, it underscores the im- portance of the scandal's timing in light of the prevailing economic environment and privatization policy. It shows how deliberate this political campaign was in removing a rival on the eve of the privatization of Rosneft, Russia's only remaining state-owned oil and gas company. The history of privatization in Russia is riddled with scandals, revealing the critical nature of the struggle for state funding in Russia today. At stake is influence over defining the rules of the political game. The aim of this article is to demonstrate how privatization in Russia gave birth to an oligarchic re- gime and how, paradoxically, it would eventually destroy that very oligar- chy. This article intends to study how privatization influenced the creation of the present elite structure and how it may further transform Russian decision making in the foreseeable future. Privatization is generally seen as a prerequisite to a market economy, which in turn is considered a sine qua non to establishing a democratic regime. But some Russian analysts and political leaders disagree with this approach.
    [Show full text]
  • Russia: CHRONOLOGY DECEMBER 1993 to FEBRUARY 1995
    Issue Papers, Extended Responses and Country Fact Sheets file:///C:/Documents and Settings/brendelt/Desktop/temp rir/CHRONO... Français Home Contact Us Help Search canada.gc.ca Issue Papers, Extended Responses and Country Fact Sheets Home Issue Paper RUSSIA CHRONOLOGY DECEMBER 1993 TO FEBRUARY 1995 July 1995 Disclaimer This document was prepared by the Research Directorate of the Immigration and Refugee Board of Canada on the basis of publicly available information, analysis and comment. All sources are cited. This document is not, and does not purport to be, either exhaustive with regard to conditions in the country surveyed or conclusive as to the merit of any particular claim to refugee status or asylum. For further information on current developments, please contact the Research Directorate. Table of Contents GLOSSARY Political Organizations and Government Structures Political Leaders 1. INTRODUCTION 2. CHRONOLOGY 1993 1994 1995 3. APPENDICES TABLE 1: SEAT DISTRIBUTION IN THE STATE DUMA TABLE 2: REPUBLICS AND REGIONS OF THE RUSSIAN FEDERATION MAP 1: RUSSIA 1 of 58 9/17/2013 9:13 AM Issue Papers, Extended Responses and Country Fact Sheets file:///C:/Documents and Settings/brendelt/Desktop/temp rir/CHRONO... MAP 2: THE NORTH CAUCASUS NOTES ON SELECTED SOURCES REFERENCES GLOSSARY Political Organizations and Government Structures [This glossary is included for easy reference to organizations which either appear more than once in the text of the chronology or which are known to have been formed in the period covered by the chronology. The list is not exhaustive.] All-Russia Democratic Alternative Party. Established in February 1995 by Grigorii Yavlinsky.( OMRI 15 Feb.
    [Show full text]
  • Welfare Reforms in Post-Soviet States: a Comparison
    WELFARE REFORMS IN POST-SOVIET STATES: A COMPARISON OF SOCIAL BENEFITS REFORM IN RUSSIA AND KAZAKHSTAN by ELENA MALTSEVA A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of Political Science University of Toronto © Copyright by Elena Maltseva (2012) Welfare Reforms in Post-Soviet States: A Comparison of Social Benefits Reform in Russia and Kazakhstan Elena Maltseva Doctor of Philosophy Political Science University of Toronto (2012) Abstract: Concerned with the question of why governments display varying degrees of success in implementing social reforms, (judged by their ability to arrive at coherent policy outcomes), my dissertation aims to identify the most important factors responsible for the stagnation of social benefits reform in Russia, as opposed to its successful implementation in Kazakhstan. Given their comparable Soviet political and economic characteristics in the immediate aftermath of Communism’s disintegration, why did the implementation of social benefits reform succeed in Kazakhstan, but largely fail in Russia? I argue that although several political and institutional factors did, to a certain degree, influence the course of social benefits reform in these two countries, their success or failure was ultimately determined by the capacity of key state actors to frame the problem and form an effective policy coalition that could further the reform agenda despite various political and institutional obstacles and socioeconomic challenges. In the case of Kazakhstan, the successful implementation of the social benefits reform was a result of a bold and skillful endeavour by Kazakhstani authorities, who used the existing conditions to justify the reform initiative and achieve the reform’s original objectives.
    [Show full text]
  • Festschrift for Immanuel Wallerstein Part I
    The Hard-Earned Integration of the East in the World Economic System Silviu Brucan orld socialism was a subsystem of the world-system and as such Wcould not run deeper than the system of which it was a part. Had Lenin realized the workings of the world economic system, he would have concluded that Russia had no chance whatsoever to build an antisystemic economy in the midst of an overpowering world capitalist system. In his earlier writings, Lenin had a glimpse of that reality, hoping that another socialist revolution would break out in Germany, bailing out the Russian one. Instead, as his dream failed to materialize he began a desperate enter- prise: socialism in one country. In retrospective, I venture to say that the pervasive power of the world- system expressed itself in the fact that Lenin and Stalin, unconsciously, conceived both socialist society, as well as the future communist society, within the limits of the industrial system, which historically belongs to the capitalist epoch. This began when Stalin presented industrialization as the goal of socialism (industrialization being essentially a capitalist operation), and ended with Lenin’s defi nition of communism “Soviets plus electrifi cation,”and Stalin’s threshold to communism expressed in terms of millions of tons of pig iron, steel, coal and oil B both indicating the limit of their historical perspective within the industrial system. Never did they formulate a new type of productive forces that would usher in the formation of a postcapitalist society, remaining intellectual prisoners of the industrial system. Silviu Brucan Str. Helesteului 26 Sector 1 71297 Bucuresti Romania journal of world-systems research, vi, 2, summer/fall 2000, 444-453 Special Issue: Festchrift for Immanuel Wallerstein – Part I http://jwsr.ucr.edu issn 1076-156x © 2000 Silviu Brucan 444 445 Silviu Brucan The Hard-Earned Integration of the East in the World Economic System 446 Stalin tried hopelessly to escape from that theoretical framework.
    [Show full text]
  • La Russie De 1991 À Nos Jours
    La Russie de 1991 à nos jours Contenu : Introduction : L’indépendance de la Fédération de Russie ..................................................................... 1 I- La Russie d’Eltsine : des débuts difficiles ............................................................................................. 2 A) L’échec de la thérapie de choc et du virage libéral ........................................................................ 2 B) Un repli sur ses propres conflits internes ....................................................................................... 3 C) Un niveau de vie en baisse manifeste ............................................................................................. 4 II- Sous Poutine, vers un nouveau départ ?............................................................................................. 5 A) Une expansion économique remarquable ..................................................................................... 5 B) Un retour sur la scène internationale, mais tensions persistantes au sein de l’ex-URSS ............... 6 C) Un Etat-providence limité et une démocratie remise en cause : la Russie, Etat non-occidental ... 7 III- Un retour en force sur la scène internationale .................................................................................. 8 A) Une politique d’expansion à nouveau clairement visible ............................................................... 8 B) Un nouveau statut sur la scène internationale et la construction d’un bloc eurasiatique ............. 9 C)
    [Show full text]
  • Putin: Russia's Choice, Second Edition
    Putin The second edition of this extremely well-received political biography of Vladimir Putin builds on the strengths of the previous edition to provide the most detailed and nuanced account of the man, his politics and his pro- found influence on Russian politics, foreign policy and society. New to this edition: Analysis of Putin’s second term as President. More biographical information in the light of recent research. Detailed discussion of changes to the policy process and the elites around Putin. Developments in state–society relations including the conflicts with oli- garchs such as Khodorkovsky. Review of changes affecting the party system and electoral legislation, including the development of federalism in Russia. Details on economic performance under Putin, including more discus- sion of the energy sector and pipeline politics. Russia’s relationship with Nato after the ‘big-bang’ enlargement, EU– Russian relations after enlargement and Russia’s relations with other post- Soviet states. The conclusion brings us up to date with debates over the question of democracy in Russia today, and the nature of Putin’s leadership and his place in the world. Putin: Russia’s choice is essential reading for all scholars and students of Russian politics. Richard Sakwa is Professor of Politics at the University of Kent, UK. Putin Russia’s choice Second edition Richard Sakwa First edition published 2004 Second edition, 2008 by Routledge 2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN Simultaneously published in the USA and Canada by Routledge 270 Madison Avenue, New York, NY 10016 This edition published in the Taylor & Francis e-Library, 2007.
    [Show full text]
  • Too Big, Too Quick? an Institutional and Systemic Overview of the Rise of Russian Metallurgical Transnationals
    TOO BIG, TOO QUICK? AN INSTITUTIONAL AND SYSTEMIC OVERVIEW OF THE RISE OF RUSSIAN METALLURGICAL TRANSNATIONALS Cédric DURAND, University Paris 13, Sorbonne Paris Cité, CEPN (CNRS, UMR 7234) and CEMI (EHESS) Marc LAUTIER, University Paris 13, Sorbonne Paris Cité, CEPN (CNRS, UMR 7234) Mots-clés : Transnationales, institutions, développement, crise, métallurgie, investissement direct étranger, Russie Keywords : Transnationals, Institutions, Development, Crisis, Metallurgy, Foreign Direct Investment, Russia 1. INTRODUCTION Russian outward foreign direct investment (OFDI) has expanded rapidly during the years 2000. The country has become the leading foreign inves- tor among the BRIC countries (Figure 1), but the global crisis led to a spec- tacular retreat since 2008. The rise of multinational companies from non- triadic countries has attracted growing attraction in the recent period (see Goldstein, 2007 for a review), but the Russian case has been somewhat neglected, given the scale and the speed of the phenomenon. It is also highly original as far as the sectoral concentration of these FDI is concer- ned. After the oil and gas sector, metallurgy is the second sector to parti- cipate to this foreign expansion (Liuhto and Vahtra, 2007; Kalotay, 2008; Skolkovo, 2008). REVUE D’ÉCONOMIE INDUSTRIELLE ➻ N° 142 ➻ 2 E TRIMESTRE 2013 41 TOO BIG, TOO QUICK? Russia benefits from a strong relative position in metal production. The United Company Rusal is the world’s largest producer of aluminium and alumina and Norilsk is the world’s leading producer of nickel and palla- dium. Russia is also the fourth largest steel producer and exporter in the world, with four companies ranking among the top 30 of the industry in 2009.
    [Show full text]
  • Left-Of-Center Govem- Public Does Not Want to Go Back to the of a Startling Buildup of Consumer Ment
    Public Disclosure Authorized ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Vlm;.;, Nu;.- ;- M,c -. - .. ;.... i. TransitionEconomicsDivision * PolicyResearchDepartment * TheWorldBank Postcommunist Parties and the Politics of Entitlements by Jeffrey Sachs Public Disclosure Authorized I nnationalelectionsthispastMarch, Theseexplanationslargelymissthepoint. of the shortages prevalent in the old Estonia's reform govenmmentwas * Opinion surveys in Central and East- regime). Indeed, in many countries in- unceremoniously toppled from em Europe repeatedly show that the cludingEstonia,thepublicisinthe midst power by a new left-of-center govem- public does not want to go back to the of a startling buildup of consumer ment. This would seem a rather un- old regime, nor does it view the left- durables-cars, refrigerators,videocas- grateful act of the Estonian voters in wing parties as instrumentsto undo the sette recorders, and the like-that were light of the accomplishments of the new market economy. long unavailable under the old regime. former government.By the enclof 1994 * The living standards ofthe population inflation was down to an annual rate of did not really drop, if one examines ac- In most countries of Eastem Europe, around 20 percent, the lowest among tual household consumption behavior social spending has not only remained countries of the former Soviet Union (rather than changesin crude indexes of an unusually high proportion of GNP, it (FSU). Economic growth was around 5 real wages, which do not give a picture has actuallysoared.Thepostcommunist Public Disclosure Authorized percent in 1994, the highest in the FSU, t *i. with forecasts of even higher growth in What's nside 1995. Privatizing Profits of Bulgaria's State somneiniprovementsintheCubaneconomy, Enterprises In Bulgaria,private wealth but a significantturnaround would re- Why then was the Estonian government has been createdvia syphoningoff prof- quire broad politicaland economicre- toppled? Why, indeed, have left-wing its from state enterprises,rather than forms,suggests J.F.Perez-Lopez.
    [Show full text]
  • Corruption in Russia – Historic Legacy and Systemic Nature Günther G
    6864 2018 January 2018 Corruption in Russia – Historic Legacy and Systemic Nature Günther G. Schulze, Nikita Zakharov Impressum: CESifo Working Papers ISSN 2364‐1428 (electronic version) Publisher and distributor: Munich Society for the Promotion of Economic Research ‐ CESifo GmbH The international platform of Ludwigs‐Maximilians University’s Center for Economic Studies and the ifo Institute Poschingerstr. 5, 81679 Munich, Germany Telephone +49 (0)89 2180‐2740, Telefax +49 (0)89 2180‐17845, email [email protected] Editors: Clemens Fuest, Oliver Falck, Jasmin Gröschl www.cesifo‐group.org/wp An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded ∙ from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com ∙ from the RePEc website: www.RePEc.org ∙ from the CESifo website: www.CESifo‐group.org/wp CESifo Working Paper No. 6864 Category 1: Public Finance Corruption in Russia – Historic Legacy and Systemic Nature Abstract This paper argues that corruption in Russia is systemic in nature. Low wage levels of public officials provide strong incentives to engage in corruption. As corruption is illegal, corrupt officials can be exposed any time, which enforces loyalty towards the powers that be; thus corruption is a method of governance. We trace the systemic corruption back to the Mongolian empire and demonstrate its persistence to the current regime. We show the geographic distribution of contemporary corruption within Russia, survey the literature on the causes, consequences, and cures of corruption in Russia, and discuss entry points to fighting it. JEL-Codes: D730, H110, H730, K420, N400, P370. Keywords: corruption, governance, institutions, political economy, history, Russia. Günther G. Schulze Nikita Zakharov* University of Freiburg University of Freiburg Institute of Economics Institute of Economics Platz der Alten Synagoge Platz der Alten Synagoge Germany – 79085 Freiburg i.Br.
    [Show full text]
  • William R. Spiegelberger the Foreign Policy Research Institute Thanks the Carnegie Corporation for Its Support of the Russia Political Economy Project
    Russia Political Economy Project William R. Spiegelberger The Foreign Policy Research Institute thanks the Carnegie Corporation for its support of the Russia Political Economy Project. All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopy, recording, or any information storage and retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publisher. Author: William R. Spiegelberger Eurasia Program Leadership Director: Chris Miller Deputy Director: Maia Otarashvili Edited by: Thomas J. Shattuck Designed by: Natalia Kopytnik © 2019 by the Foreign Policy Research Institute April 2019 COVER: Designed by Natalia Kopytnik. Photography: Oleg Deripaska (World Economic Forum); St. Basil’s Cathedral (Adob Stock); Ruble (Adobe Stock); Vladimir Putin (kremlin.ru); Rusal logo (rusal.ru); United States Capitol (Adobe Stock; Viktor Vekselberg (Aleshru/Wikimedia Commons); Alumnium rolls (Adobe Stock); Trade War (Adobe Stock). Our Mission The Foreign Policy Research Institute is dedicated to bringing the insights of scholarship to bear on the foreign policy and national security challenges facing the United States. It seeks to educate the public, teach teachers, train students, and offer ideas to advance U.S. national interests based on a nonpartisan, geopolitical perspective that illuminates contemporary international affairs through the lens of history, geography, and culture. Offering Ideas In an increasingly polarized world, we pride ourselves on our tradition of nonpartisan scholarship. We count among our ranks over 100 affiliated scholars located throughout the nation and the world who appear regularly in national and international media, testify on Capitol Hill, and are consulted by U.S.
    [Show full text]