Economic Insecurity and the Demand of Populism in Europe*

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Economic Insecurity and the Demand of Populism in Europe* Economic Insecurity and the Demand of Populism in Europe* L. Guiso† H. Herrera ‡ M. Morelli§ T. Sonno ¶ May 2020 Abstract This paper documents the spiral of populism in Europe and the direct and indirect role of economic insecurity shocks. Using survey data on individual voting and data on politi- cal parties manifestos in European countries, we make two contributions to the literature, namely: (1) Economic insecurity shocks had a signicant impact on the demand of pop- ulism as a direct protection demand eect and also through the induced changes in trust and attitudes; (2) A key consequence of a negative shock to economic security is a drop in turnout. The impact of this previously neglected eect is substantial: when economic inse- curity increases, almost 40% of the induced change in the propensity to vote for a populist party conditional on voting comes from the turnout incentives channel. Keywords: turnout, trust, attitudes, populism JEL: D72, F68 *Luigi Guiso and Massimo Morelli wish to thank the Italian Ministry of Research (MIUR) for the PRIN fund- ing; Massimo Morelli also wishes to thank the Dondena and Igier research centers and the European Research Council, advanced grant 694583. We thank Luca Brugnara and Nina Fluegel for excellent research assistance. The usual disclaimer applies. †Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance, and CEPR ‡Warwick University, and CEPR §Bocconi University, IGIER, and CEPR ¶University of Bologna, and CEP 1 Introduction What determined the populism wave in Europe in the 21st century? Are the common sources related to economic crises or stagnation and, if so, through what channels? This paper provides an empirical analysis of the channels through which economic insecurity aected the “demand” of populism. The focus on the common features of populist parties (left and right together rather than separate) and the focus on a broad notion of economic insecurity (rather than just globalization shocks) are necessary for a deep understanding of the phenomenon. The 21st-century external threats of globalization and migration, as well as the nancial crisis, undermined citizens’ condence in both leftist (government-based) policies and rightist (market-based) policies that respect the institutional constraints and functioning of politics.1 Global market competition, immigration and robotization are making some believers in free markets shake. At the same time, the ability of governments to keep welfare state policies is re- duced due to supranational constraints. At a time in which the crisis is two-sided, there is room for new movements and transformation of existing opposition movements in the direction of urging removal of constraining institutions.2 We argue that a negative economic security shock that aects a citizen at a time when both left and right traditional recipes are perceived as in- eective, depresses the motivation to vote for traditional parties of both left and right; the dis- appointment generates an abstention-based space for populist platforms who thus experience a massive increase in support. Figure1 lends support to this sequence. It shows a pattern familiar to several European countries: economic crisis followed by voter apathy and disaection with traditional parties, which in turn opened the space for entry of new populist parties or greatly magnied the vote share of existing ones. In the paper we oer evidence that is consistent with this chain: economic insecurity causes faith in traditional parties to diminish, inducing disillu- sioned voters to abstain; in turn, economic insecurity, disillusion and the consequent trust drop attract support for populist platforms. [FIGURE1 HERE] 1For a discussion of the specic features of the great recession, see e.g. Judis (2016). 2Various forms of exit, rejection of international treaties previously subscribed, construction of walls, and so on, are just examples of simple protection proposals that have traction today but would not have attracted votes in other decades. The simple model in section2 will clarify how the typical populist policies can appeal to disillusioned voters in our context. 1 Tosubstantiate the claim of generality of the proposed sequential argument, we rst propose a very simple theory that elucidates the channels through which a signicant economic insecu- rity shock can trigger abstention and drop in trust and then populist voting. We then show that endogenous turnout eects are key for an evaluation of the relevance of economic insecu- rity, because economic insecurity shocks aect at the same time the willingness to participate in elections as well as the willingness to switch to a populist party conditional on having decided to participate. The full extent of the impact of economic insecurity trends becomes apparent when we show that even other key drivers of populist voting - namely trust in political parties and attitudes towards immigrants - are in fact substantially inuenced by economic insecurity. For the empirical analysis we will use the PopuList created by Rooduijn et al. (2019) to iden- tify populist parties. Underlying the PopuList is the denition of populism proposed by Mudde (2004). This is widely accepted in the recent political science literature; it characterizes pop- ulism as “a political narrative that antagonizes the people and the corrupt elite, and that aims for policies that reect the will and are understood by the people” (Mudde, 2004).3 We study the determinants of the demand for populist platforms in the countries covered by the Euro- pean Social Survey. Our empirical analysis accounts for selection into electoral participation. We show that adverse shocks to economic security and trust in political parties induce people not to vote and, if they do, to choose a populist party. Ignoring the voter participation margin would bias the estimates of the drivers of the vote underestimating the underlying demand for populist parties, but also would obscure the mechanism by which the disappointment induced by the crisis favours populists. A simultaneous Heckprobit estimation of the chance of partici- pation and of a populist vote shows that economic insecurity has statistically and economically signicant direct eects on both margins: it lowers the chances of turning out, but when a vote is cast it raises the chances of voting populist. Trust in political parties and attitudes toward immigrants matter as well. The worsening of either of these sentiments both discourage participation and encourage voting for populists. Im- portantly, negative shocks to economic security and trust increase the vote share of populist par- ties among the participants because they strongly discourage supporters of mainstream parties to participate in elections. More immigrant-averse attitudes have a milder eect through reduced 3In Guiso et al. (2017) one can nd robustness results to using a dierent continuous measure of populism. 2 participation, as the eect is overwhelmingly via switching voters preference from traditional to populist parties. Building a pseudo-panel from the individual data allows us to show that trust in politics and immigrant attitudes variables are, in fact, aected causally by changes to economic insecurity.4 Thus, we can document a large total eect (direct and indirect) of economic insecurity on the demand for populism. Weconrm the relevant causal eects of economic insecurity on trust and attitudes towards immigrants also on an Italian panel of individual respondents from 2008 to 2013. Importantly, this panel allows us to conrm the timing of our mechanism, highlighting that what matters for the choice of voting populist is the feeling of economic insecurity just before elections. Overall, our evidence suggests that cultural factors such as trust and attitudes sentiments are an important channel driving the populist support, but also probably that they are not independent factors as they are driven by economic insecurity. In a nutshell, our empirical analysis makes two important contributions to the literature: (1) Economic insecurity shocks have a signicant impact on the demand of populism not only as a direct protection demand eect but also through the induced changes in trust and attitudes; (2) A key previously neglected eect of a economic insecurity is a drop in turnout incentives – more than one third of the induced increase in the propensity to vote for a populist party rela- tive to other parties comes from a turnout eect. Ignoring the turnout (crucial) channel, one could reach the wrong conclusion (see e.g. Inglehart and Norris, 2016) that economic variables do not matter much in the decision to vote for a populist party. Indeed, failure to consider that economic security shocks signicantly aects the decision to abstain makes inconsistent any es- timate of the eects of economic insecurity on the propensity to vote populist. Some literature also emphasized indirect eects of economic insecurity on certain cultural traits or attitudes/sentiments, who thus cannot be deemed independent drivers.5 Indeed, eco- nomic insecurity may aect the populist vote in several indirect ways, as for instance fostering a 4Our nding that an economic insecurity shock signicantly aects the attitudes towards immigrants may be due to any mix of rational updating (i.e., some people may rationally expect a higher risk of substitution) and behavioural external-blaming reactions. 5Lucassen and Lubbers (2012) give evidence – for 8 of the 11 European countries they consider – that shifts towards far-right populism stemmed
Recommended publications
  • Remaking Italy? Place Configurations and Italian Electoral Politics Under the ‘Second Republic’
    Modern Italy Vol. 12, No. 1, February 2007, pp. 17–38 Remaking Italy? Place Configurations and Italian Electoral Politics under the ‘Second Republic’ John Agnew The Italian Second Republic was meant to have led to a bipolar polity with alternation in national government between conservative and progressive blocs. Such a system it has been claimed would undermine the geographical structure of electoral politics that contributed to party system immobilism in the past. However, in this article I argue that dynamic place configurations are central to how the ‘new’ Italian politics is being constructed. The dominant emphasis on either television or the emergence of ‘politics without territory’ has obscured the importance of this geographical restructuring. New dynamic place configurations are apparent particularly in the South which has emerged as a zone of competition between the main party coalitions and a nationally more fragmented geographical pattern of electoral outcomes. These patterns in turn reflect differential trends in support for party positions on governmental centralization and devolution, geographical patterns of local economic development, and the re-emergence of the North–South divide as a focus for ideological and policy differences between parties and social groups across Italy. Introduction One of the high hopes of the early 1990s in Italy was that following the cleansing of the corruption associated with the party regime of the Cold War period, Italy could become a ‘normal country’ in which bipolar politics of electoral competition between clearly defined coalitions formed before elections, rather than perpetual domination by the political centre, would lead to potential alternation of progressive and conservative forces in national political office and would check the systematic corruption of partitocrazia based on the jockeying for government offices (and associated powers) after elections (Gundle & Parker 1996).
    [Show full text]
  • Bulgaria – the Difficult “Return to Europe”
    European Democracy in Action BULGARIA – THE DIFFICULT “RETURN TO EUROPE” TAMARA BUSCHEK Against the background of the EU accession of Bulgaria on 1st January 2007 and the first Bulgarian elections for the European Parliament on 20th May 2007, Tamara Buschek takes a closer look at Bulgaria’s uneven political and economic transition – at its difficult “return to Europe”. Graduated from Graz University (Austria) in 2003 with a Masters in Law [magistra juris] after finishing her studies in European and international law. After gaining a grant from the Chamber of Commerce in 2000 to complete an internship at the Austrian Embassy in London, she carried out research for her dissertation in criminal law – “The Prevention of Sexual Child Abuse – Austria/Great Britain” - in 2001 at the London School of Economics. She studied European and administrative law in Paris from 2001 to 2002 as part of an Erasmus year. She is quadrilingual (German, Bulgarian, English and French). « BULGARIA – THE DIFFICULT RETURN TO EUROPE » MAY 2007 Table of Contents Introduction P. 1 2.3 The current governmental coalition, 2005-2007 and the P. 21 presidential election in 2006 I – Background Information P. 3 III - The first European Parliament elections, 20 May 2007 P. 25 1.1 Hopes and Fears P. 3 Conclusion P. 30 1.2 Ethnic Minorities P. 5 1.3 Economic Facts P. 7 Annex P. 32 II – Political Situation- a difficult path towards stability P. 9 Annex 1: Key facts P. 32 2.1 The transition from 1989 till 2001 P. 9 Annex 2: Economic Profile P. 33 2.1.1 The legislative elections of 1990 and the first P.
    [Show full text]
  • Teen Voters: the Austrian Experience
    PRZEGLĄD ZACHODNI 2018 KATARZYNA GELLES Wrocław TEEN VOTERS: THE AUSTRIAN EXPERIENCE For a democratic country general elections are a process of a fundamental na- ture. They enable all eligible citizens to participate on equal terms in shaping their country’s politics. Therefore, in the analysis of a selected party system it is not only the actors on the political stage (primarily the political parties) that are important but also the support they enjoy in society. After all, their electoral success and ability to exercise power are dependent on the electorate’s decision. Of equal merit is the issue of voter turnout, which is defined as “the ratio of votes cast to registered voters”.1 Whether the turnout is high or low, it always provokes questions about the reasons for this state of affairs as in a democratic system it is always indicative of civic maturity. In recent years in Europe there has been increasing talk of the crisis of democracy. One of its most noticeable syndromes is decreased voter turnout, which fell below 70% after 1990.2 This phenomenon occurs on a broad scale and its reasons have been analysed by political scientists and sociologists. Among the most oft-cited causes is “politics fatigue”, i.e. a lack of interest in political life displayed by citizens, for whom the differences between political groups and factions are becoming less and less clear. Voters are also losing faith in their effectiveness, often assuming that election results do not exert a visible impact on the surrounding reality. People resignedly say: “those at the top will do what they want to”.
    [Show full text]
  • Codebook Indiveu – Party Preferences
    Codebook InDivEU – party preferences European University Institute, Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies December 2020 Introduction The “InDivEU – party preferences” dataset provides data on the positions of more than 400 parties from 28 countries1 on questions of (differentiated) European integration. The dataset comprises a selection of party positions taken from two existing datasets: (1) The EU Profiler/euandi Trend File The EU Profiler/euandi Trend File contains party positions for three rounds of European Parliament elections (2009, 2014, and 2019). Party positions were determined in an iterative process of party self-placement and expert judgement. For more information: https://cadmus.eui.eu/handle/1814/65944 (2) The Chapel Hill Expert Survey The Chapel Hill Expert Survey contains party positions for the national elections most closely corresponding the European Parliament elections of 2009, 2014, 2019. Party positions were determined by expert judgement. For more information: https://www.chesdata.eu/ Three additional party positions, related to DI-specific questions, are included in the dataset. These positions were determined by experts involved in the 2019 edition of euandi after the elections took place. The inclusion of party positions in the “InDivEU – party preferences” is limited to the following issues: - General questions about the EU - Questions about EU policy - Questions about differentiated integration - Questions about party ideology 1 This includes all 27 member states of the European Union in 2020, plus the United Kingdom. How to Cite When using the ‘InDivEU – Party Preferences’ dataset, please cite all of the following three articles: 1. Reiljan, Andres, Frederico Ferreira da Silva, Lorenzo Cicchi, Diego Garzia, Alexander H.
    [Show full text]
  • ESS9 Appendix A3 Political Parties Ed
    APPENDIX A3 POLITICAL PARTIES, ESS9 - 2018 ed. 3.0 Austria 2 Belgium 4 Bulgaria 7 Croatia 8 Cyprus 10 Czechia 12 Denmark 14 Estonia 15 Finland 17 France 19 Germany 20 Hungary 21 Iceland 23 Ireland 25 Italy 26 Latvia 28 Lithuania 31 Montenegro 34 Netherlands 36 Norway 38 Poland 40 Portugal 44 Serbia 47 Slovakia 52 Slovenia 53 Spain 54 Sweden 57 Switzerland 58 United Kingdom 61 Version Notes, ESS9 Appendix A3 POLITICAL PARTIES ESS9 edition 3.0 (published 10.12.20): Changes from previous edition: Additional countries: Denmark, Iceland. ESS9 edition 2.0 (published 15.06.20): Changes from previous edition: Additional countries: Croatia, Latvia, Lithuania, Montenegro, Portugal, Slovakia, Spain, Sweden. Austria 1. Political parties Language used in data file: German Year of last election: 2017 Official party names, English 1. Sozialdemokratische Partei Österreichs (SPÖ) - Social Democratic Party of Austria - 26.9 % names/translation, and size in last 2. Österreichische Volkspartei (ÖVP) - Austrian People's Party - 31.5 % election: 3. Freiheitliche Partei Österreichs (FPÖ) - Freedom Party of Austria - 26.0 % 4. Liste Peter Pilz (PILZ) - PILZ - 4.4 % 5. Die Grünen – Die Grüne Alternative (Grüne) - The Greens – The Green Alternative - 3.8 % 6. Kommunistische Partei Österreichs (KPÖ) - Communist Party of Austria - 0.8 % 7. NEOS – Das Neue Österreich und Liberales Forum (NEOS) - NEOS – The New Austria and Liberal Forum - 5.3 % 8. G!LT - Verein zur Förderung der Offenen Demokratie (GILT) - My Vote Counts! - 1.0 % Description of political parties listed 1. The Social Democratic Party (Sozialdemokratische Partei Österreichs, or SPÖ) is a social above democratic/center-left political party that was founded in 1888 as the Social Democratic Worker's Party (Sozialdemokratische Arbeiterpartei, or SDAP), when Victor Adler managed to unite the various opposing factions.
    [Show full text]
  • A Comparative Constitutional Analysis Between Italy and Hungary
    Department of Political Science Master’s Degree in International Relations – European Studies Chair in Comparative Public Law POPULISM IN THE FRAMEWORK OF THE EUROPEAN UNION: A COMPARATIVE CONSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS BETWEEN ITALY AND HUNGARY SUPERVISOR CANDIDATE Professor Cristina Fasone Claudia Mattei 635892 CO-SUPERVISOR Professor Giovanni Orsina Academic Year 2018/2019 1 Table of contents Introduction 6 1 CHAPTER – POPULISM 9 1.1 What is populism? A definition for a highly contested phenomenon 10 1.2 Understanding populism 14 1.2.1 Who are the people? 14 1.2.2 Who are the elites? 18 1.2.3 The real meaning of the volonté générale 19 1.2.4 The people and the general will: populism vs. democracy 20 1.3 Historical birth of populism 24 1.3.1 The American People’s Party 24 1.3.2 The Russian narodnichestvo 26 1.4 Marriage between populism and ‘host’ ideologies: different families 29 1.4.1 Right-wing populism 30 1.4.2 Left-wing populism 31 1.4.3 Populist constitutionalism 33 1.5 Why does populism develop? 36 1.5.1 The causes behind the populist rise 37 1.5.2 The cause of the cause: the auto-destruction of politics as origin of populism 39 1.5.3 Technocracy replaces politics: the case of the European Union 41 1.6 Populism in the world 44 2 CHAPTER – POPULISM IN EUROPE 48 2.1 Genesis of populism in Europe: Boulangism 48 2.2 Populism in Western Europe 51 2.2.1 Post-WW2 populist experiences in Western Europe 51 2.2.2 The rise of modern populism in Western Europe 53 2 2.3 Populism in Eastern Europe 58 2.3.1 Interwar populism in Eastern Europe 58 2.3.2
    [Show full text]
  • The Growth of the Radical Right in Nordic Countries: Observations from the Past 20 Years
    THE GROWTH OF THE RADICAL RIGHT IN NORDIC COUNTRIES: OBSERVATIONS FROM THE PAST 20 YEARS By Anders Widfeldt TRANSATLANTIC COUNCIL ON MIGRATION THE GROWTH OF THE RADICAL RIGHT IN NORDIC COUNTRIES: Observations from the Past 20 Years By Anders Widfeldt June 2018 Acknowledgments This research was commissioned for the eighteenth plenary meeting of the Transatlantic Council on Migration, an initiative of the Migration Policy Institute (MPI), held in Stockholm in November 2017. The meeting’s theme was “The Future of Migration Policy in a Volatile Political Landscape,” and this report was one of several that informed the Council’s discussions. The Council is a unique deliberative body that examines vital policy issues and informs migration policymaking processes in North America and Europe. The Council’s work is generously supported by the following foundations and governments: the Open Society Foundations, Carnegie Corporation of New York, the Barrow Cadbury Trust, the Luso- American Development Foundation, the Calouste Gulbenkian Foundation, and the governments of Germany, the Netherlands, Norway, and Sweden. For more on the Transatlantic Council on Migration, please visit: www.migrationpolicy.org/ transatlantic. © 2018 Migration Policy Institute. All Rights Reserved. Cover Design: April Siruno, MPI Layout: Sara Staedicke, MPI No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopy, or any information storage and retrieval system, without permission from the Migration Policy Institute. A full-text PDF of this document is available for free download from www.migrationpolicy.org. Information for reproducing excerpts from this report can be found at www.migrationpolicy.org/about/copyright-policy.
    [Show full text]
  • The Mainstream Right, the Far Right, and Coalition Formation in Western Europe by Kimberly Ann Twist a Dissertation Submitted In
    The Mainstream Right, the Far Right, and Coalition Formation in Western Europe by Kimberly Ann Twist A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Political Science in the Graduate Division of the University of California, Berkeley Committee in charge: Professor Jonah D. Levy, Chair Professor Jason Wittenberg Professor Jacob Citrin Professor Katerina Linos Spring 2015 The Mainstream Right, the Far Right, and Coalition Formation in Western Europe Copyright 2015 by Kimberly Ann Twist Abstract The Mainstream Right, the Far Right, and Coalition Formation in Western Europe by Kimberly Ann Twist Doctor of Philosophy in Political Science University of California, Berkeley Professor Jonah D. Levy, Chair As long as far-right parties { known chiefly for their vehement opposition to immigration { have competed in contemporary Western Europe, scholars and observers have been concerned about these parties' implications for liberal democracy. Many originally believed that far- right parties would fade away due to a lack of voter support and their isolation by mainstream parties. Since 1994, however, far-right parties have been included in 17 governing coalitions across Western Europe. What explains the switch from exclusion to inclusion in Europe, and what drives mainstream-right parties' decisions to include or exclude the far right from coalitions today? My argument is centered on the cost of far-right exclusion, in terms of both office and policy goals for the mainstream right. I argue, first, that the major mainstream parties of Western Europe initially maintained the exclusion of the far right because it was relatively costless: They could govern and achieve policy goals without the far right.
    [Show full text]
  • Austrian Populism and the Not-So-Great Recession. the Primacy of Politics1
    Austrian populism and the not-so-great Recession. The primacy of politics Kurt Richard Luther [email protected] Keele European Parties Research Unit (KEPRU) Working Paper 38 © Kurt Richard Luther, 2014 2 ISSN 1475-15701 ISBN 1-899488-77-6 KEPRU Working Papers are published by: School of Politics, International Relations and Philosophy (SPIRE) Keele University Staffs ST5 5BG, UK Fax +44 (0)1782 73 3592 www.keele.ac.uk/kepru Editor: Prof Kurt Richard Luther ([email protected]) KEPRU Working Papers are available via KEPRU’s website. ___________________________________________________________________ Launched in September 2000, the Keele European Parties Research Unit (KEPRU) was the first research grouping of its kind in the UK. It brings together the hitherto largely independent work of Keele researchers focusing on European political parties, and aims: • to facilitate its members' engagement in high-quality academic research, individually, collectively in the Unit and in collaboration with cognate research groups and individuals in the UK and abroad; • to hold regular conferences, workshops, seminars and guest lectures on topics related to European political parties; • to publish a series of parties-related research papers by scholars from Keele and elsewhere; • to expand postgraduate training in the study of political parties, principally through Keele's MA in Parties and Elections and the multinational PhD summer school, with which its members are closely involved; • to constitute a source of expertise on European parties and party politics for media and other interests. Convenor KEPRU: Prof Kurt Richard Luther ([email protected]) Kurt Richard Luther is Professor of Comparative Politics at Keele University 3 Austrian populism and the not-so-great Recession.
    [Show full text]
  • R01545 0.Pdf
    Date Printed: 11/03/2008 JTS Box Number: IFES 2 Tab Number: 10 Document Title: The 1990 Bulgarian Elections: A Pre-Election Assessment, May 1990 Document Date: 1990 Document Country: Bulgaria IFES ID: R01545 ~" I •••··:"_:5 .~ International Foundation fo, Electo,al Systems I --------------------------~---------------- ~ 1101 15th STREET. NW·THIRD FLOOR· WASHINGTON. D.C. 20005·12021 828-8507·FAX 12021 452-0804 I I I I I THE 1990 BULGARIAN ELECTIONS: A PRE-ELECTION ASSESSMENT I I MAY 1990 I I Team Members Dr. John Bell Mr. Ronald A. Gould I Dr. Richard G. Smolka I I I I This report was made possible by a grant from the National Endowment for Democracy. Any person or organization is welcome to quote information from this report if it is attributed to IFES. I 8CWlD OF DIREQORS Barbara Boggs Maureen A. Kindel WilHam R. Sweeney. Jr. Randal C. Teague Counsel Charles T. Manatt Patricia Hutar Frank 1. Fahrenkopf Jr. Jean-Pierre Kingsley leon). Weir I Chairman SecretaI)' Judy Fernald Peter M(Pher~On DIREQORS EMERITI Richard W. Soudricne David R. Jones Joseph Napolitan James M. Cannon Director I Vice Chairman Treasurer Victor Kamber Sonia Picado S. Richard M Scammon I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I ii I TABLE OF CONTENTS I Part I. overview I Mission 3 Executive Summary 4 I The Historical context 6 I Current Political Scene 13 I Part II. Election Law and procedures Constitutional and Legal Foundations of Electoral Law 20 I The Law on Political Parties The Election Act I Analysis of the Law I The Electoral system 30 structure and Procedures I Comments and Analysis I Electoral Needs 38 I Team Recommendations 41 I I Appendices A.
    [Show full text]
  • English Version of This Report Is the Only Official Document
    Office for Democratic Institutions and Human Rights THE ITALIAN REPUBLIC PARLIAMENTARY ELECTIONS 4 March 2018 ODIHR Election Assessment Mission Final Report Warsaw 6 June 2018 TABLE OF CONTENTS I. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY .......................................................................................................... 1 II. INTRODUCTION AND ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ............................................................... 3 III. BACKGROUND ........................................................................................................................... 3 IV. LEGAL FRAMEWORK ............................................................................................................. 4 V. ELECTORAL SYSTEM .............................................................................................................. 5 VI. ELECTION ADMINISTRATION .............................................................................................. 6 VII. VOTER REGISTRATION .......................................................................................................... 8 VIII. CANDIDATE REGISTRATION ................................................................................................ 9 IX. ELECTION CAMPAIGN .......................................................................................................... 11 X. CAMPAIGN FINANCE............................................................................................................. 12 XI. MEDIA .......................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Information Guide Euroscepticism
    Information Guide Euroscepticism A guide to information sources on Euroscepticism, with hyperlinks to further sources of information within European Sources Online and on external websites Contents Introduction .................................................................................................. 2 Brief Historical Overview................................................................................. 2 Euro Crisis 2008 ............................................................................................ 3 European Elections 2014 ................................................................................ 5 Euroscepticism in Europe ................................................................................ 8 Eurosceptic organisations ......................................................................... 10 Eurosceptic thinktanks ............................................................................. 10 Transnational Eurosceptic parties and political groups .................................. 11 Eurocritical media ................................................................................... 12 EU Reaction ................................................................................................. 13 Information sources in the ESO database ........................................................ 14 Further information sources on the internet ..................................................... 14 Copyright © 2016 Cardiff EDC. All rights reserved. 1 Cardiff EDC is part of the University Library
    [Show full text]