WHY DO ARMED GROUPS SOMETIMES SWITCH FROM VOLUNTARY TO FORCED RECRUITMENT OF CHILDREN? A CASE STUDY OF THE DEMOCRATIC REPUBLIC OF THE CONGO

Master Thesis Political Science: International Relations

Author: Jessica Besch

Student Number: 11254114 Supervisor: Dr. Abbey Steele Second Reader: Dr. Jana Krause Date: 23 June 2017

Abstract

Why do armed groups sometimes switch from voluntary to forced recruitment of children? By extending Beber and Blattman’s (2013) theory about the costliness of punishment I argue that an increase in economic resources, being natural resources and foreign government support, leads to a change from voluntary to forced recruitment of children. My within and cross-case analysis about the RCD-Goma and the Mai-Mai, two competing armed groups in the Democratic Republic of the Congo, should test the causal effect between my independent and dependent variable. The observable implications suggest that there is some sort of correlation, but due to a lack of fine-grained data I can only partially confirm my hypotheses. This paper highlights the importance of variation when studying the recruitment of children and calls upon scholars to guide future research on this topic in order to protect children in conflict areas.

© Marcus Bleasdale, 2003

Word count: 16.557

Abbreviations

Alliance des Forces Démocratiques pour la Libération du Congo (AFDL)

Armée Nationale Congolaise (ANC)

Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC)

Forces Démocratiques Alliées, Uganda (ADF)

Forces pour la Défense de la Démocratie, Burundi (FDD)

Large-N analysis (LNA)

Lord’s Resistance Army, Uganda (LRA)

Mouvement pour la Liberation du Congo (MLC)

Rassemblement Congolais pour la Démocratie (RCD)

Rassemblement Congolais pour la Démocratie – Mouvement de Liberation (RCD-ML)

Rwandese Patriotic Army (RPA)

Small-N analysis (SNA)

Société minière des Grands Lacs (SOMIGL)

Société minière et industrielle du Kivu (SOMINKI)

United Nations (UN)

Contents

Abstract ...... Abbreviations ...... Contents ...... I. Introduction ...... 6

II. Literature Review ...... 9

III. Theory ...... 14

IV. Research Design...... 16

i. Methodology ...... 16

ii. Case Selection ...... 17

iii. Data ...... 21

iv. Historical overview ...... 23

a. Background of the conflict ...... 24

b. International involvement ...... 27

c. Natural resources ...... 28

d. Ethnicity ...... 29

e. Child soldiers ...... 30

v. Background of the armed groups ...... 30

a. RCD and RCD-Goma...... 31

b. Mai-Mai ...... 32

vi. Analysis ...... 33

a. Data collection ...... 35

vii. Results ...... 47 viii. Discussion ...... 53

V. Conclusion ...... 56

VI. Bibliography ...... 58

VII. Appendices ...... 66

I. Introduction

The recruitment and use of children as soldiers during conflict is condemned by the UN Security Council and is in violation of international law (, 1999). The Optional Protocol to the Convention on the Rights of the Child on the involvement of children in armed conflict (2002) should conduce states not to recruit children under the age of 18 and to prevent such recruitment (United Nations, 2002). However, even if agreements with governments and armed groups are being reached, they do not necessarily provide a safeguard. The “Children, Not Soldiers” campaign is advocated in order to further protect the rights of children in conflict zones (United Nations). Using children in regular and irregular armed groups can prolong negotiated settlements and harm post-conflict reconstruction (Haer and Boehmelt, 2017, p. 5). Studying the mechanisms behind the recruitment of children is therefore an important aspect to peacebuilding. The exact number of child soldiers in the world today is not known, but it is estimated at being around 10.000 and up to more than 100.000 (Child Soldiers

International). The use of children as soldiers has gained more and more attention among scholars. The literature focuses primarily on the reasons of child recruitment and their consequences (Andivg, 2006; Haer and Boehmelt, 2016; McBride, 2014; Singer, 2005). Another wave of literature tries to explain why children voluntarily join an armed group. Possible explanations include escaping poverty, taking revenge and seeking protection (Brett and Specht, 2004; Guichaoua, 2007). The reintegration process of former child soldiers is also widely studied and should push policymakers to address the importance of education and constructing rehabilitation centers (Bracken et al., 1996; Wessells, 2005; Derluyn et al., 2013). Little however is known about the forced recruitment mechanisms of armed groups. Why do they recruit children by force as opposed to voluntarily? Recruiting tactics

6 are often referred to as static, producing a gap in the literature about the recruitment of adults and children as soldiers. Eck (2014) points out the importance of variation when analyzing the recruitment of armed groups: “[…] groups are likely to shift recruitment strategies depending on the exigencies of the conflict” (Eck, 2014, p. 374). Consequently, my research question will focus on the change in the recruitment method of armed groups. In this paper I am trying to explain why armed groups sometimes change from voluntary to forced recruitment of children.

I will base my argument on Faulkner (2016) and Beber and Blattman (2013) by claiming that an armed group’s economic endowments influence their recruitment strategies. The latter suggest that a group with initial low level of civilian support and a resource base that is unresponsive to human rights abuses is more likely to recruit children by force. Thus, when an armed group relies primarily on natural resources or foreign donors to finance its organization, it does not have to be dependent on civilian support and can more easily adopt forced recruitment tactics (Beber and Blattman, 2013, p. 95).

Faulkner also argues that the decision to recruit children by force relies on whether a group has enough resources to finance warfare. Those who lack economic endowments at the beginning of their mobilization will appeal to the civilian population for support. Groups who were successful in gaining civilian support will consequently refrain from forced recruitment practices. The second part of his theory targets the variation in recruitment practices as a consequence of changes in an armed group’s access to economic resources. Here Faulkner goes a step further than Beber and Blattman by claiming that the level of forcible recruitment of children will increase when groups did not win the support of civilians but increased their resource base (Faulkner, 2016, pp. 217-218). Similarly, I propose that an increase in an armed group’s economic endowments, being natural resources and support from a foreign government, leads to a change from voluntary to forced child recruitment.

7

My findings on the case study of two armed groups in the Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC), the RCD-Goma and Mai-Mai, show that economic and social endowments indeed play a crucial role in the variation of child recruitment. The rebel group RCD-Goma changed their recruitment method during a period of increased resource wealth. Failed attempts to gain support from the population caused little voluntary recruits. The Mai-Mai militia on the other hand were initially popular and experienced a high number of recruits. Some groups however sought personal enrichment and endangered their reputation, leading to a decline in voluntary and sometimes also a switch to forced recruitment. A lack in precision in regard to the variations weakens my results but does not undermine the fact that changes in a group’s resources are connected to changes in a group’s child recruitment strategies. In the remainder of this paper, I will first give an insight into the existing literature that covers the topic of child soldier recruitment. In the second section I will develop my argument and the hypotheses I will test. The third step will be the research design, where

I will first explain which methodology I will use in order to analyze my data. I will then move to the case selection and elaborate why I chose two armed groups within the Democratic Republic of the Congo as my cases. In order to proceed, I then need to illustrate the indicators for my measurement. The background of the conflict and the armed groups will serve as an introduction into the section of my data collection. Here I will present all the observable implications that are relevant for my hypotheses, followed by a summary of the results. The evidence partially supports the theoretical expectations of the research and highlights the importance of variation when studying the topic of child recruitment. The last section concludes with a discussion of alternative explanations and opportunities for future research.

8

II. Literature Review

I will give a brief introduction into the topic of child soldiers in order to situate my paper in the broader universe of theories. How is a child soldier defined and where are children recruited most? More importantly, why do armed groups recruit them as opposed to adults? I will also give an overview of voluntary versus forced recruitment mechanisms and the main scholars involved in the discussion. UNICEF formulates a standard definition of what is called a child soldier, being any boy or girl under the age of 18 who is part of any kind of regular or irregular armed group and serves as a cook, porter, messenger or combatant (UNICEF, 2011). Child soldiers can also perform tasks such as laying explosives, spying, taking care of the logistics and domestic labor (Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2010). To get a better sense of the scope of the recruitment of children, it is important to know where child soldiers are mostly employed. Recruitment of children into the national military is still allowed in 50 countries. Around a dozen armed groups still use child soldiers today, ranging from Colombia, Somalia and Yemen to Myanmar, India and the Philippines. Wealthier states such as Canada and the United Kingdom allow children as young as 16 into their national military with consent of a parent or guardian (Child Soldiers International). All in all, I have barely found a country that has been in a civil war at any given time and where not at least one armed group was recruiting children into their ranks. Given the huge amount of armed groups that have been and still are involved in recruiting children, it is difficult to speculate which one’s are more likely to use child soldiers than others. Why are children even recruited as opposed to adults? The proliferation of small arms has made rebel groups and militias more inclined in recruiting children (Machel, 1996; Singer, 2005). Such weapons are easy to use and lightweight, making them the perfect combat tools for young soldiers. Their low cost and availability through illegal

9 markets influence the attractiveness of recruiting children into the ranks of regular and irregular armed groups (McBride, 2014, p. 9). Another explanation for the rate of child soldier participants is the easy access to refugee camps. Low protection of these camps makes children particularly vulnerable to recruiters (Achvarina and Reich, 2006). Children have also often been taken from camps to third countries for military training (Machel, 1996). One of the most elaborated theories of child recruitment consists of looking at the demand and supply factors. Demand on the one hand means looking at the decisions made by an armed group when recruiting new soldiers. Which strategies are being implemented and who are the targets? Supply on the other hand is defined by characteristics such as the number of children present in the population or the level of poverty and determines how costly or difficult the recruitment will be. There is also the distinction between forced and voluntary supply (Andvig, 2006, pp. 19-20). Furthermore, armed groups are seen as rational actors who want to maximize their probability of winning with the lowest financial costs. In that sense, children are employed if they are cheap enough to compensate for a group’s low military efficiency (idem, p. 26). There is a debate whether children are better fighters than adults. Some literature however states that the fact that they are more easily manipulated and indoctrinated ultimately transforms children into effective recruits in the long run (Beber and Blattman, 2013). Compared to adult combatants, they are more adaptable and obedient which in turn makes them easier to control and retain. These characteristics unfortunately facilitate their recruitment (Haer and Boehmelt, 2016, p. 157). Under the influence of drugs, children can be more daring and fearless in combat. Socialization into the armed group makes them acquire the values of their militant environment and thus influences their behavior (idem, p. 154). Recruiting decisions by armed groups are influenced by cost and benefit calculus. A decline in soldiers motivates group leaders to fill the quota, ideally at a low cost. Since

10 children are easy to catch due to their low mobility, they become easy targets for groups with low human resources (Lasley and Thyne, 2015, p. 291). Having summarized the main reasons for armed groups to recruit children, I will now dive into the forced recruitment mechanisms which my paper will focus on. By forced recruitment I mean the opposite of voluntarily joining an armed group. Coercion and abduction thus fall into the category of forced recruitment. Also, when a person is being threatened by members of an armed group and does not have the choice to say no without having to fear consequences, recruitment cannot be counted as voluntary. It is however not easy to completely separate the two categories because even if children claim to have joined at their own free will, indirect but coercive mechanisms could have influenced their decision. Persuasion, intimidation and social pressure can push people, especially children, to become soldiers in a regular or irregular armed group (Honwana, 2006, p. 58). These environmental push factors make a decision seem voluntary, but often children discover too late that “even if the initial act was voluntary, there is no opportunity to exercise further choice” (Brett and Specht, 2004, p. 110). Some were also being misled with false promises, making their reasons for joining an illusion (idem, p. 112). Why is it important to differentiate between voluntary and forced recruitment in general? The article “Explaining Rape during Civil War” by Dara Kay Cohen (2013) particularly comes to mind, where the author links forced recruitment (of adults) to gang rape in times of war. She argues that low social cohesion is a consequence of forced recruitment. In order to create bonds and increase the morale of the group “through inducing feelings of power and victory”, armed groups commit gang rape (Cohen, 2013, pp. 463-464). Recruitment mechanisms can thus influence a combatant’s tendency to engage in wartime rape. Andvig (2006) points to the importance of voluntary recruits in order to prevent the usage of child soldiers. He demonstrates that economic or ideological incentives of an armed group are necessary in order for people to join them. In case of a declining or initially low success rate, little voluntary recruits are expected. If this stock of

11 potential adult recruits dries out, we should observe an increase in forced recruitment and child soldier ratio (Andivg, 2006, p. 24). Cohen’s cross-national dataset reveals that 45% of all insurgencies between 1980 and 2009 recruited their adult fighters by force (Cohen, 2013, pp. 467-468). It was not surprising to see that countries such as the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Uganda and Sudan were in the tables. All three countries are known for using child soldiers and recruiting them by force on a large scale (Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2000).

There may be a correlation between forced recruitment of adults and forced recruitment of children, which I will however not further elaborate on now. My aim was to point out the importance of recruiting mechanisms for further actions of an armed group and vice versa. Andvig (2006) points out that it is more beneficial to recruit children by force than adults since they are more easily framed and therefore forget more quickly that they were forcibly recruited. Ultimately, the desertion rate will be lower (Andvig, 2006, p. 31). Beber and Blattman (2010) agree with the fact that it is not beneficial for armed groups to recruit adults by force since their incentives to escape will be too high. It is thus easier to coerce children as they have low abilities and reservation utilities (Beber and Blattman, 2010, p. 2). Some scholars put their emphasis on armed groups’ economic versus social resources (Beber and Blattman, 2013; Salehyan et al., 2014; Faulkner, 2016). They argue that natural resources or support from foreign governments as a resource base can decrease an armed group’s incentive to collaborate with civilians. According to Salehyan et al. (2014), groups that receive external support are more likely to engage in one-sided violence against civilians (Salehyan et al., 2014, p. 640). Faulkner (2016) builds on this theory and adds as a consequence the rise of forced child recruitment. I will now elaborate on these ideas in more detail since I will use them as a foundation for my argument about why armed groups sometimes switch from voluntary to forced recruitment of children.

12

First, for an armed group to function and achieve its goals, it needs adequate financial support (Salehyan et al., 2014, p. 635). This resource base then further influences its way of recruitment (Faulkner, 2016). In their article “The Logic of Child Soldiering and Coercion”, Beber and Blattman (2013) argue that armed groups with initially low support from civilians and resource bases that neglect human rights, such as natural resources and foreign donors, should be more likely to employ coercion against children (Beber and Blattman, 2013, p. 95). However, in order to be effective, coercion has to be cheap. This means that by recruiting children by force armed groups should have little to lose, especially civilian support or other funding actors who could condemn them for violations against human rights (idem, p. 69). Rebel groups can become less dependent on civilians when they find alternative means of financing their violent organization, as for example external support from foreign governments or when they get the opportunity to easily extract natural resources (Faulkner, 2016). Easily extractable commodities can be sold on the black market and provide a revenue in order to keep their organization alive. With financial and material support from foreign sponsors, incentives to build or maintain a relationship with the civilian population decrease. Ultimately, this relationship, being a “[…] strategy of ideological persuasion and service provision […]”, is considered costly (Salehyan et al., 2014, pp. 636-637). Unconditional foreign support also reduces rebel groups’ accountability and lets them engage in coercive recruitment and even violence against civilians without having to fear sanctions (Beber and Blattman, 2013, p. 100). In the next section I will elaborate on my theoretical framework and present two hypotheses.

13

III. Theory

The last part of the literature review constitutes the foundation of my theory. Combining ideas from Salehyan et al. (2014), Faulkner (2016) and particularly Beber and Blattman (2013), I put an emphasis on economic and social endowments when explaining an armed group’s recruiting strategies. Civilian support on the one hand is especially important in the initial phase of an armed group’s mobilization. With their help, groups can rely on food, shelter and even fighters and thus accumulate their resource wealth. High economic endowments (natural resources and foreign sponsorship) on the other hand give a group little incentive to build up or keep a relationship with civilians. Both these variables, as well as recruitment decisions, can however vary over time. Faulkner (2016) highlights the importance of variation by saying that “[…] as a group’s access to resources change so too will their level of forcible recruitment” (Faulkner, 2016, p. 218). Moreover, he specifies that rebel leaders make the decision about forced recruitment of children as opposed to adults since they provide an easy access in an environment where local support is non-existent. He argues that groups which manage to gain local support will refrain from forcibly recruiting children (idem, p. 219). The objective of my thesis is to find out which factors help to explain why armed groups recruit children by force rather than voluntarily. Being aware of the fact that environments and relationships surrounding an armed group are never fixed and vary over time, I want to focus on change rather than only initial conditions. By paying attention to the temporal variation I will argue that a change in a group’s resource base can lead to a change in the way they recruit children. More specifically, a rise in an armed group’s economic resources will consequently lead to a change from voluntary to forced child recruitment. The causal mechanism linking my dependent and independent variable is the decline of civilian support.

14

My theory puts an emphasis on an armed group’s accumulation of resource wealth. I assume that every group first tries to recruit adults and children voluntarily. This also creates incentives to build a relationship with civilians. If they gained the support of civilians but over the time increased their financial means, a group will gradually lose this relationship. A reason for that is the fact that maintaining a relationship with the local population requires a lot of effort (Salehyan et al., 2014). Furthermore, high economic resources convey the image of greedy and criminal soldiers and consequently weaken an armed group’s reputation. As a result of this, they can no longer depend on voluntary recruitment but will turn to coerced and forced recruitment of children. An increase in economic resources (independent variable) thus leads to a decline in civilian support. Civilian support, being my causal mechanism, then has as an effect the switch from voluntary to forced recruitment of children (dependent variable). It has to be noted that I am using Beber and Blattman’s (2010) explanation about why it is more beneficial for an armed group to recruit children by force as opposed to adults. Their low abilities and reservation utilities decrease the possibility of escaping (Beber and Blattman, 2010, p. 2). Children thus represent an easy and cheap way to get recruits. Only if the number of needed combatants increased dramatically in a short period of time would a violent organization turn to forced recruitment of adults. I am aware of the fact that there may be different reasons why armed groups switch their child recruitment strategies. A sudden urge of a high number of troops can be fatal when voluntary recruitment is low and civilian support almost absent (Andvig, 2006; Lasley and Thyne, 2015). This would then rather be observed in times of multiple big attacks between two or more armed groups. I can also think of another reason for a decline in civilian support. A shift in alliances for example can ultimately alter a group’s reputation. Raúl Sánchez de la Sierra (2017) further provides us with an explanation about why some armed groups are more dependent on civilians than others. Accounting for the different ways in which coltan and gold can be taxed, he argues that armed actors in gold

15 municipalities rely heavily on the civilian population if they want to benefit from the demand shock (de la Sierra, 2017). I will further elaborate on these alternative explanations in the discussion section and indicate why I think that economic resources provide a valuable argument when trying to explain recruitment mechanisms. Coming back to my theoretical framework, I will first test Beber and Blattman’s theory about initial resource endowments and their correlation with armed groups’ recruitment strategies since I will use their cross-national dataset for my case selection.

Testing both their theory and my alternative at the same time has the advantage of finding strengths and weaknesses of the latter. My second hypothesis can be seen as a continuation of Beber and Blattman’s theory by including a temporal variation in child recruitment.

H1: Armed groups with initially low support from civilians and resource bases that neglect human rights, such as natural resources and foreign government support, should be more likely to recruit children by force.

H2: An increase in armed groups’ economic endowments (natural resources and foreign government support) leads to a change from voluntary to forced child recruitment.

IV. Research Design i. Methodology

To test my hypotheses, I will use a nested analysis, “a unified mixed method approach to comparative research” (Lieberman, 2005, p. 435). To begin with, I will look at the quantitative dataset provided by Beber and Blattman (2013). Their conducted cross- national study, which I will elaborate on in the next paragraph, narrows down the universe

16 of potential cases that could apply to my theory. This existing large-N analysis (LNA) helps me with my case selection strategy (Lieberman, 2005). Next, I will conduct a small-N analysis (SNA) in which I will test an existing as well as an alternative theory. I will evaluate Beber and Blattman’s argument by using the evidence from my case study as well as test an alternative hypothesis. By comparing two distinct cases, in my context two different armed groups within one country, I allow their distinguishing characteristics to facilitate theoretical reflections (Bryman, 2016, p. 28). I will thus conduct a within and cross-case analysis. More specifically, I will look at two opposing armed groups within the same country and observe if and how their resources and child recruitment strategies have changed over time. I will then analyze how this change differs across the two cases. The methods used for my data collection consist of analyzing briefing papers and policy documents from non-governmental organizations, as well as examining research articles and qualitative data from former child soldiers and civilians who have experienced the conflict in areas controlled by the armed groups in question. With this approach I aim to test the causal effect of an armed group’s economic resources on its child recruitment strategies. If there is an association between the relevant variables of my second hypothesis, I will further test whether or not my proposed causal mechanism is correct. The mechanism connecting X to the occurrence of Y is a decrease in civilian support. This support however is difficult to measure which is why I will expect to only partially be able to find evidence on whether the mechanism links my independent to my dependent variable.

ii. Case Selection

For my case selection I will draw on Beber and Blattman’s article “The Logic of Child Soldiering and Coercion” (2013). They first examine the incentives for armed groups to recruit children and suggest that groups who use coercive recruitment strategies are more 17 likely to recruit children. Their second statement is that low support from the civilian population and natural resources, as well as foreign government sponsorship as a resource base, makes armed groups more likely to recruit children by force (Beber and Blattman,

2013, p. 95). What is of particular importance to my paper is their cross-national dataset of rebel groups in 12 African countries, with which they want to investigate the variation in the costliness of punishment. The latter implies that forced child recruitment is only useful to armed groups when it is not costly. This means that they should solely apply this tactic when they have little civilian support or important funding actors to lose. In case donors condemn their partners for violating human rights and cease to support them, punishment is considered expensive (Beber and Blattman, 2013). This cross-national survey provides data on forced child recruitment and links them to armed groups’ sources of material support such as civilian and foreign government support, as well as access to natural resources. They were looking at all conflicts in sub-Saharan Africa that have been reported by the Uppsala Conflict Data Program and Peace Research Institute Oslo between 1980 and 2004. They stratified twelve out of forty-two conflicts by the number of conflicts reported in a country. They further collected information on all nonstate actors during that period, from which they excluded coups. Even if this random sample of African rebel groups has to be used with caution due to scarcity and inconsistency of data, it presents evidence on the variables that are relevant for my theory (Beber and Blattman, 2013, pp.

95-96). I further downloaded their supplement materials in which I found the Excel sheet with the variable coding for the cross-national survey of the African rebel groups (see Appendix A). The coding values however were not included, until I discovered them in the appendix of an earlier article by the same authors called “The Industrial Organization of Rebellion: The Logic of Forced Labor and Child Soldiering” (Beber and Blattman, 2010) (see Appendix B). This document in combination with the Excel sheet got me full access to

18 quantitative data of 10 African countries, their rebel groups, methods of recruitment and initial endowments (they removed Gambia and Burkina Faso because they were only single military coups rather than lasting insurgencies) (Beber and Blattman, 2010). First, I removed Uganda from the list of potential cases since Beber and Blattman (2013) conducted their case study on this country, finding out that “this coercive strategy came cheaply; with no civilian support to lose, and material backing coming from one of the regimes least sensitive to human rights (Sudan), the LRA [Lord’s Resistance Army] faced little penalty for its abductions and abuses” (Beber and Blattman, 2013, p. 89). I then selected the first country in the document, which is the Democratic Republic of the Congo. Being aware that child soldiers are a big issue in the conflict and natural resources abundant, I decided to take a closer look at the available literature for this topic. As expected, literature on child soldiers in the DRC, as well as information about armed groups’ access to natural resources and their cooperation with foreign governments, are adequately given. The fact that I am proficient in the French language, which is the official language in the DRC, gave me the opportunity to benefit from an even wider range of literature. My aim is to compare two armed groups within the DRC, one fighting against and one supporting the government, in order to strengthen my evidence. It is interesting to observe in how far recruitment strategies vary depending on whether a group gets support from its own or a foreign government, or maybe even no support at all. Finding similarities or differences between two groups can help future research in the area of child recruitment. In order to keep selection bias low, I chose two armed groups based on my independent variable, being their resource endowments (King et al., 1994). It is also important to highlight the timeframe of my analysis, considering the fact that the DRC has been in numerous conflicts since the 1990s. I will focus on the Second Congo War (1998- 2003) since there were numerous local and international actors at play, some of which were accused of committing human rights abuses. The war is further known for its grave

19 consequences on the Congolese population, having resulted in at least one million deaths and the internal displacement of about two million people (Nest, 2011, p. 75). The next step consisted of selecting two groups out of Beber and Blattman’s dataset. It has to be noted that the rebel groups in their dataset were selected randomly (Beber and Blattman, 2013, p. 96). Out of the five armed groups that the authors proposed for the DRC, only three were active throughout the whole Second Congo War: the Mouvement pour la Liberation du Congo (MLC), the Rassemblement Congolais pour la

Démocratie (RCD) and the Rassemblement Congolais pour la Démocratie – Mouvement de Liberation (RCD-ML). Given that the sources of each group’s financial and material resources all include natural resources and foreign governments (coded 1 and 2 respectively), I chose the group that has been active for the longest period of time, the RCD. Being involved in the conflict between 1998 and 2006, this group gives me the opportunity to observe its full evolution and hopefully to make conclusive claims about the correlation of my variables. Since Beber and Blattman do not provide me with an armed group that is supporting the Congolese government during its second war, I needed to conduct some further research. I then came across the Mai-Mai militia groups who were actively fighting against the Rwandan backed RCD, in particular the splinter group RCD-Goma, during the Second Congo War (Global Security). The Mai-Mai are particularly known for their social endowments and later on also their activities with third parties in order to accumulate their wealth (Laudati, 2013; Morvan, 2005). Having different resource endowments and being competing actors in the war, I want to see if the accumulation of resource wealth of the RCD and the Mai-Mai during the Second Congo

War has had an influence on their child recruitment strategies. It has to be noted that the Mai-Mai form a variety of groups differing in size and capacity, which is why some of them are difficult to map (Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2010). Most of the literature therefore, and all of the articles I will use, hardly differentiate between the numerous groups. Additionally, there are a few ways to spell the

20 name of the armed group and I (randomly) selected the one that I have been using so far: Mai-Mai. When it comes to the RCD, we may not forget that they were officially only active until 1999, which is when the group split into more fractions. What was then left of the initial RCD was renamed RCD-Goma (Richards, 2014). When reporting about incidents after 1999, some documents and articles still refer to the newly named RCD-Goma as RCD. Nevertheless, I decided to separately use their names according to the time period. Using the Mai-Mai for my analysis will unfortunately increase my measurement error. Since the literature in use barely specifies which group is being talked about, I can only make conclusions about the Mai-Mai in general. For example, it may be that one group is engaged in trading minerals whereas others are not. If I found evidence that some Mai-Mai groups started recruiting children by force, I will not know whether they are the ones who are also exploiting natural resources. I can thus only make conclusions about the Mai-Mai by looking at the overall effects. Without access to more detailed reports about the militia, clear distinctions between the different groups cannot be made.

I will now proceed by explaining how I will measure my variables and propose clear indicators.

iii. Data

Proposing clear indicators for variables that need to be measured has the intention of enhancing reliability. For both hypotheses, the dependent variable is forced child recruitment which I will measure by looking for evidence about any kind of recruitment that has not been voluntary. Threats, coercion and abduction thus fall into this category. Measuring recruiting strategies is however not always easy since the organizations and authors writing those papers rely on perceptions by former child recruits. As already mentioned in the literature review, children may think they joined voluntarily while in fact coercive measures have been used to convince them. Nonetheless, reports by

21 organizations as well as research articles all make a clear distinction between voluntary and forced recruitment, which is why I will continue using these two categories. The independent variable in the analysis is an armed group’s resource endowment. While in the alternative theory I only consider the economic resources, Beber and Blattman (2013) also highlight the importance of social endowments, being civilian support. Testing their existing theory, I will measure civilian support the way Beber and Blattman did, meaning “[…] (non-coerced) support of the population in its base region within [its] home country on which it could draw for resources, cooperation, or harbor” (Beber and Blattman, 2010, Appendix). This support can be seen when an armed group receives voluntary funds or other kind of assistance from the local community. I also try to find written proof in several documents about a group’s popularity and cooperation with the civilian population. The taxation of the population by armed groups is not included in the definition, since it hardly reveals whether this support is voluntary or coerced. Furthermore, taxation is sometimes viewed as a complex relationship between civilians and armed groups, meaning that various factors influence where and when taxation is applied (de la Sierra, 2017). The indicators for economic resources are in both hypotheses access to natural resources and support from foreign governments. For the former, I will draw on Beber and Blattman’s definition again, being that of “[…] territorial and natural resource control that is convertible into monetary resources” (Beber and Blattman, 2010, Appendix). I will further incorporate the collaboration of armed groups with, as well as taxation of companies that work with natural resources. The United Nations (2001) also gives an elaborate explanation about what they mean by the exploitation of natural resources: “[…] extraction, production, commercialization and exports of natural resources and other services such as transport and financial transactions” as well as “[…] confiscation, extraction, forced monopoly and price-fixing” (United Nations, 2001, pp. 5-6). Support from foreign governments is being measured in financial, material and human resource related reinforcement by mostly

22 neighboring countries. More specifically, if a foreign government is providing an armed group with money, weapons or soldiers, it is contributing to a group’s resource wealth. I will also need to find evidence on the increase of resources at any point of time. The indicators for civilian support unfortunately have some weaknesses. Cooperation between communities and armed groups can often only be observed when on site. When interviewing locals and asking about their relationship with a group, fear of retaliation may lead them to refrain from answering the questions. Additionally, support can also be divided into voluntary and coerced. The statement that a group relies on civilian support thus has to be treated with caution. In order to avoid measurement error, I will try to find evidence from numerous sources. By including some of the same definitions for the variables as Beber and Blattman (2010), I am trying to strengthen the validity of my measurements while also taking into account their limitations. In the next section I will introduce the background of the Congo conflict, including some important background knowledge about its international dimension, natural resources, ethnicity and the problem of child soldiers in the country. I will then turn to a more detailed description about the formation of the RCD and the Mai- Mai.

iv. Historical overview

The next paragraphs should help to understand how multiple factors shaped the conflict and the formation of the armed groups in the DRC.

23 a. Background of the conflict

Administrative map of the Democratic Republic of the Congo. Source: http://www.nationsonline.org/oneworld/map/dr_congo_map.htm

The Democratic Republic of the Congo, a country located in the heart of central Africa, is a relatively young country that gained its independence only in 1960 and has been named Zaire by its president Mobutu in 1971. Being rich in natural resources, it has been exploited by businesses, politicians, rebel groups and neighboring states ever since the Belgian colonization in the late 1800’s (BBC, 2016). The conflict is further known to be a mixture of local, national and international actors, all acting upon their own economic interests (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004). The consequences of its two wars (1996-2003) are still being felt today, with numerous armed groups constantly forming and dismantling. Joseph Mobutu became president in November 1965. During his term in office, Mobutu set up a system to control and exploit the country’s natural resource wealth for his own purposes, leaving the Congolese population in bad living conditions (Global 24

Witness, 2009, p. 5). The heterogeneous composition of the Congolese population in the East, as well as the presence of immigrant communities inhabiting the same territories, has led to regular disputes about the access to and control over land. In the 1990s, a lot of local conflicts could be explained as “the political manipulation by local politicians of the rights of access and control of land” (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 41). As of 1994, the country has experienced further instability near its boarders with Rwanda. More than one million Hutu refugees fled from the neighboring country into the

DRC as a consequence of the genocide. Among them were militias who were accused of being responsible for the horrible act and who started launching attacks from the refugee camps on Rwanda (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 54). This sudden influx of refugees “altered the existing demographic dynamic and ethnic balance in the eastern part of the Congo” (Moyroud and Katunga, 2002, p. 160). The country experienced its first civil war between 1996 and 1997. The seven months conflict came to an end when the former autocratic president Mobutu was ousted in May 1997 by the Alliance des Forces Démocratiques pour la Libération du Congo (AFDL), an armed coalition led by Laurent Kabila and supported by Rwandan and Ugandan troops, as well as various Mai-Mai groups (Richards, 2014, p. 304). Mobutu fled the country and Kabila declared himself president, renaming the country Democratic Republic of the

Congo. In 1998, Kabila replaced his second Rwandan army commander and turned his back on his former backers in Uganda, Rwanda and Burundi by ordering them to leave the country. Even though he was still dependent on the support of his external allies, Kabila did not want to be portrayed as a Rwandan puppet, which is why he distanced himself from his neighbors (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 49). As a result, Rwanda and Uganda created an anti-Kabila revolt with the goal of overthrowing him. They feared that the tensions along the eastern boarders of the DRC would hinder their goal of security and peace. Neighboring countries like Angola and Zimbabwe fortunately came Kabila to

25 the rescue. Only a few months later however, different irregular armed groups emerged and created an imbalance in the country, particularly in the East (Kisangani, 2003, pp. 52- 57). A second attempt by Rwanda, Uganda and this time also Burundi to launch a coup against the president resulted in a messy armed conflict. Troops from Angola, Chad, Namibia, Sudan and Zimbabwe were once again backing up Kabila, but the economic and infrastructural consequences were devastating (Global Security). Since 1996, the national oriented agenda transformed into a more local and individual agenda, “leading to a total fragmentation of the politico-military landscape”, all of which led to the multiplication of armed actors (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 51). Kabila was assassinated in January 2001, making his son, Joseph Kabila, the new president. In autumn 2002, he successfully negotiated the withdrawal of Rwandan troops from the eastern part of the country. With the Pretoria Accord signed only two months later, Joseph Kabila was able to set up a transitional government in July 2003, which further resulted in presidency elections in 2005 and provincial legislatures in 2006 (Global

Security). This post-transition period has however seen an increase in violence due to the state’s inability to tackle local conflicts. All the “flawed peace agreements” helped former rebels to integrate into the national army, all while preserving their illegal networks (Peace Direct, 2009). In order to get a better understanding of my results I will give an overview of the main indicators of my variables, only this time they are directly related to my unit of analysis, the Democratic Republic of the Congo. The next paragraphs will briefly introduce the international dimension of the conflict, the situation about natural resources, ethnic diversity in the country in order to understand civilian support and the problem of child soldiers in the DRC.

26 b. International involvement

The conflict in the Congo, especially during 1996 and 2003, is also known as “Africa’s World War” due to its transnational character. Not only local rebel groups, but also neighboring insurgents and African governments have participated in the conflict for numerous reasons (Williams, 2013). In order to get a better understanding of the international dimension of the First and Second Congo Wars, I will briefly introduce the foreign governments involved and their reasons for participation. Rwanda was the country that was probably most involved in the DRC. Its stated reasons were the growing insecurity and raids by the Hutu Interahamwe from eastern Congo into the country. Not only was president Kabila not able to control the attacks, but Rwandan officials gained knowledge about him training and arming their enemies. Furthermore, Congolese Tutsis were getting more and more into conflict with native opponents and Hutu refugees from Rwanda. The Rwandan Tutsi government thus saw the need to intervene for humanitarian concerns. Nevertheless, the Second Congo War increasingly demonstrated the country’s hidden motivations, being personal and national enrichment (Williams, 2013, p. 91). Uganda’s involvement can also be explained by a security dilemma concerning the attacks by the Ugandan resistance group called Forces Démocratiques Alliées (ADF), located in eastern Congo. Together with Rwanda, they shared the goal of overthrowing Kabila. Ugandan actors were furthermore driven by economic motivations, being that of benefitting from the Congo’s mineral trade (Williams, 2013, p. 92). Burundi, similar to Rwanda, experienced a local conflict between the Hutu and Tutsi population. It saw the formation of the rebel group Forces pour la Défense de la Démocratie (FDD) who used the DRC as their sanctuary and were armed by Kabila in order to resist Rwandan and Ugandan forces. Burundi thus saw itself forming an alliance with the anti-Kabila states in the interest of repelling the FDD (Williams, 2013, p. 93).

27

Angola on the other hand was considered the most important state opposing the Rwanda-Uganda alliance. Together with Zimbabwe, Namibia and Sudan, these countries supported Kabila for different personal reasons which I will not further elaborate on now (Williams, 2013). With this introduction I aim to point out not only the international dimension of the conflict, but also the complexity of interests and thus alliances of neighboring countries.

c. Natural resources

The DRC is rich in a multitude of natural resources, reaching from diamonds, gold, cassiterite (tin ore) and coltan to coffee, timber and palm oil. All of these minerals can be found in the eastern regions of the DRC, making it a perfect battlefield for local and international actors who seek to make easy economic profits (Amnesty International, 2003; United Nations, 2010). These economic interests largely contributed to the nature of the Congolese conflict, where rebel movements, businesses and foreign governments were and still are engaged in the illegal extraction of natural resources (Vlassenroot, 2008). “Thus, the quest to control natural resources have shaped the power strategies pursued by the warring parties that have increasingly been based on the territorialisation of authority around valuable resource areas and trading networks” (Vlassenroot, 2008, p. 3). The practice of resource pillaging, corruption and lack of accountability characterized Mobutu’s and later also Kabila’s regime. It has to be noted that under Mobutu, the mining and forestry sectors had been almost entirely controlled by civilians (even if some of the profits were handed to the military). With the beginning of the first war, these sectors suddenly fell into the arms of the new national army and various armed groups. This militarization of regions for important sectors triggered increasing violence against the Congolese population (United Nations, 2010, pp. 320-321). The second war then saw an even higher attractiveness for resource exploitation because it helped armed groups to finance their warfare and became a source of personal 28 enrichment for political and military leaders. The creation of so called “front” companies enabled foreign governments to extract natural resources in collaboration with violent armed organizations without even visibly participating (United Nations, 2010, pp. 321- 322).

d. Ethnicity

The DRC is the second most ethnically diverse country in the world, counting 200 diverse groups (Karbo and Mutisi, 2012, p. 382). The North and South Kivu, as well as Ituri regions, are particularly rich in different ethnic groups. During its Belgian colonial administration in the Kivus, different waves of migration highly influenced local society. Between 1937 and 1955, a large number of Hutu-Rwandans were placed in the Kivus as coffee, tea or cotton laborers. These lands were however controlled by different ethnic groups, creating the initial phase of tensions. North and South Kivu further experienced an influx in Rwandan Tutsi refugees due to its Social Revolution. The resulting disputes have been mainly about the access to and control over land (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, pp. 40-41). These disputes escalated in the early 1990s, when Mobutu encouraged local politicians to mobilize their followings according to their ethnic background. This mobilization and manipulation of entire ethnic communities led to serious levels of violence. “Local politicians and commercial interests mobilized the population on the issue of land by the use of self-serving ethnic discourse” (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 41). Traditional authorities also used these campaigns to regain or increase their control over land and political power. Local trust and cooperation thus became limited to ethnic belonging. This “stirring up of ethnic resentment” is of importance when analyzing the formation of the numerous armed groups. With this discourse, traditional authorities and politicians were able to mobilize young locals into militias. The result was a progressive proliferation of militias, all being supported by their ethnic groups (idem, pp. 42-46). 29

With this introduction into the Congo’s fractured society, I aim to point out the importance of ethnicity when analyzing civilian support for armed groups like the RCD- Goma and Mai-Mai.

e. Child soldiers

The DRC is known for its large scale recruitment of children. Of all newly recruits in the country, the UN estimates that 15-30% are under the age of 18. Child soldiers in the DRC are also called “kadogos”, meaning little ones in Swahili (Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2001, p. 144). Armed groups often justify their actions by pointing out the number of soldiers needed to overthrow the government. The lack of military training within rebel groups makes it easy for children to fight among unprofessional combatants. A lot of children in the DRC join voluntarily in order to protect themselves, defend their communities or survive economically. However, children are also frequently recruited against their will. Child recruitment in the DRC has particularly gained national and international attention since 1996 with the AFDL (United Nations, 2010, pp. 307-308). While during the first war it was mainly the AFDL who recruited large numbers of children, the second war saw a tremendous increase. After the coup against Mobutu in 1997, a large part of these children were integrated into the new government army. In 2003, according to the Report of the Secretary-General on children and armed conflict, 12 parties have been involved in recruiting children into their ranks, including the RCD-Goma and Mai-Mai (United Nations, 2010, p. 309).

v. Background of the armed groups

I will now introduce both armed groups that are relevant for my analysis and give an overview of their formation. The RCD-Goma and Mai-Mai groups constituted competing forces in eastern DRC during the Second Congo War (1998-2003). 30 a. RCD and RCD-Goma

The Rassemblement Congolais pour la Démocratie (RCD), supported by Rwanda and Uganda, was organized in Kigali, Rwanda, with the aim of ousting Kabila. “This rebellion, however, was more than a simple repetition of the AFDL campaign, as former allies now became adversaries, new coalitions proved to be fleeting and economic interests became guiding principles” (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 50). In August 1998, Ernst Wamba dia Wamba became its chairman. With Wamba being concerned about the increasing Rwandan influence, he got toppled ten months later and created the RCD- Kisangani in March 1999. After experiencing continuous fighting between Rwanda and Uganda over the control of Kisangani, Wamba relocated his office to Kampala and established the Rassemblement Congolais pour la Démocratie – Mouvement de Liberation (RCD-ML) (idem, pp. 58-60). During the last months of what was still known the RCD, in early 1999, the rebel group together with Rwandan and Ugandan forces controlled over one-third of the DRC (Global Witness, 2004, p. 10). The remaining RCD became thus known as RCD-Goma and was backed by Rwanda, whereas the RCD-ML was now supported by Uganda (Richards, 2014). RCD-Goma, the Rwandese Patriotic Army (RPA) and the Rwandese Army controlled until late 2002 most of the North and South Kivu provinces, parts of the Maniema province, Kasai Orientale and Oriental province, including Katanga and Kisangani (Amnesty International, 2003, p. 7). The RCD-Goma also had an armed wing called Armée Nationale Congolaise (ANC), which were however known to be undisciplined and badly trained. The combatants were violent, often looting and burning down whole villages in order to get food or acquire property

(United Nations, 2002, p. 16). With the beginning of the Second Congo War, ethnic communities in the Kivu provinces slowly experienced a division: those supporting and those opposing the RCD. One of the main opposing armed forces were the Mai-Mai (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers,

2004, p. 57). 31 b. Mai-Mai

Since the 1960s, eastern Congo experienced a mixture of different ethnicities. Workers from Rwanda, known as Rwandophones, a Tutsi Banyarwanda community, later called Banyamulenge, and native communities all lived in the East of the country. Years of tensions erupted into violence in North Kivu in 1993, leading to the proliferation of local defense militias by the native communities, called the Mai-Mai. They constitute a variety of groups differing in capacity and size. The constant emergence of new and the dissolution of former Mai-Mai groups makes them difficult to map (Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2010, p. 2). Their goal was to “[…] keep land and positions of traditional authority out of the hands of the Rwandan-backed rebellion […]” (Richards, 2014, p. 314). They are known for their war rituals that convey the belief of “mayi”, magic water, to protect the combatants from bullets. Their nationalist ideas are particularly attractive to young people (Jourdan, 2001, p. 90). Stearns (2011) describes the demographic of the Mai-Mai as young, unemployed and disaffected (Stearns, 2011, p.

263). In 1996, the campaign of the AFDL drove most of the Mai-Mai groups to ally with Kabila and his Rwandan and Ugandan supporters. The second war however saw a change in alliances when the Mai-Mai realized the Tutsi influence within the AFDL. The Mai-Mai soon started opposing the RCD, a rebellion considered to be a Tutsi attempt to regain Kivu, and thus allied with the government of Kabila which gave them military support (Jourdan, 2001, pp. 94-95). The last few years saw an increase in Mai-Mai groups as a response to the growing insecurity in the rural areas. While some of the groups are still providing protection and regulation in the areas they control, others are guided by violent ethnic ideologies and involved in plunder (Peace Direct, 2009).

32 vi. Analysis

Before diving into my analysis and discussing the results, I will state which observations I expect to see. By stating my expectations I set clear guidelines concerning the confirmation or rejection of my hypotheses. First, it is important to mention which kind of variation I included in my hypotheses and therefore also aspire to see in my results. My second hypothesis entails a temporal variation while observing if and when resource bases of an armed group change. If they do, can we also witness a change in a group’s child recruitment strategies? More specifically, if at one stage an armed group experiences an increase in its resource wealth, we should also observe a shift from voluntary to forced recruitment of children. This shift should appear within the next six months. One year would be too wide of a gap and something else could have provoked this change in recruitment. One or two months on the other hand would be too soon to observe such a big change in an armed group’s recruiting tactics. So, if I find evidence for example that one armed group had an increase in economic resources in the month of January, I expect to observe that by July the latest it started recruiting children by force (whereas before it only recruited voluntarily). The time frame of six months can however be subject to change in future studies about the variation in recruitment tactics. For my first hypothesis I expect to have the following observations: in case the Mai- Mai and RCD-Goma both have initial low civilian support and economic resources at their disposal (access to natural resources and/or support from foreign governments), they will consequently recruit children by force. Here I will focus on the initial resource endowments and recruitment strategies of a group. Forced recruitment should be observed during the same time where civilian support is low and economic resources rather good. I can however also confirm my first hypothesis in case a group has initial high civilian support, no good economic resource base and does not recruit children by force.

33

My second hypothesis on the other hand is correct if I observe an increase in the economic endowments of both armed groups, which will then as an effect have a switch from voluntary to forced child recruitment. Ideally, I will also observe a decrease of civilian support as causal mechanism. This means that after an increase in resources we should find evidence soon after about the decline of civilian support due to this development. Here again, I set a timeframe of six months. This decline of support then also needs to affect forced recruitment of children. With a higher resource base independent from civilians, armed groups do not feel accountable for their actions anymore and will turn to a more cost-effective way of recruitment. In order for my findings to be generalizable, I need to be able to confirm my hypotheses for both armed groups. The ultimate goal of this research is to place my case study within the context of a broader universe of units. It is, on the other hand, also important to mention how I would know that I can falsify my hypotheses. For Beber and Blattman’s theory, I would reject the hypothesis if initial low civilian support and a good economic resource base did not lead to forced recruitment of children. Furthermore, if I only observe low civilian support but no economic resources or vice versa, I would have to refute the theory, no matter the outcome on the recruitment strategy. The second hypothesis can be falsified if I observe an increase in the economic resources of an armed group but no change in their method of child recruitment (meaning from voluntary to forced). Should I observe a change in recruitment but no increase in economic resources, I know that my theory does not hold and other factors are responsible for the variation. I will further proceed by summarizing my observations for both cases. I will link the key findings of my causal mechanism, independent and dependent variables to each armed group in the following order: foreign government support, access to natural resources, child recruitment strategies and civilian support.

34 a. Data collection 1. RCD-Goma

Foreign government support The reliance of the armed group on foreign governments, particularly on its neighbor Rwanda, has been highlighted in numerous articles and policy documents (Richards, 2014; Amnesty International, 2003). According to reliable sources, Rwanda and Burundi both supplied RCD-Goma combatants with arms and training. The former included “[…] rocket launchers, armoured cars, machine guns, light artillery, mortars and landmines” as well as various helicopters and aircrafts (Amnesty International, 2003, p. 8). Besides military equipment and troops, Rwanda also appointed the rebels with oil and petrol (United Nations, 2001, p. 28). In 2002, RCD-Goma claimed around 25.000 soldiers, 15.000 of which were well- trained combatants provided by the Rwandan army. These foreign soldiers constituted an essential part of the armed group’s army, without which it could not have survived

(Kisangani, 2003, p. 59). Rwanda even set up a “Congo Desk” within its borders in order to administer the finances needed for the war in the DRC, but also to handle the wealth from the natural resources and other revenues from the neighboring country. The Congo Desk thus contributed to Rwanda’s military expenses, which in turn benefited its ally, the RCD-Goma (Amnesty International, 2003, p. 12). In exchange for weapons, RCD-Goma repeatedly provided the Rwandan government with direct payments. To finance these arms, the rebel group collected taxes on mineral exports (Kisangani, 2003, p. 67). Since the beginning of the second war in 1998, a huge amount of cassiterite concessions have been sold by RCD and later also RCD-Goma to Rwanda on a daily basis. The allies even set up an efficient network to transport these resources by planes or trucks (Global Witness, 2004, p. 22). This interdependence between demand and supply benefited both Rwanda and the RCD-Goma. A more detailed

35 explanation about the extraction of natural resources and its taxation by the rebel group will follow in the next section. The movement is however also often portrayed as being militarily weak if it would not have been for the numerous superior forces of the Rwandese army. “The RCD are the allies of the RPA [Rwandan Patriotic Army], not the other way around” claims a Congolese human rights defender (Amnesty International, 2003, p. 7). Claiming to be the true political as well as military authority in the provinces it controls by undertaking local administrative functions, it has nonetheless constant backup from Rwandese officials. A lot of policies that needed to be implemented were decided upon and approved in Kigali, Rwanda, instead of eastern Congo (ibid.). As we see, the RCD-Goma, as well as its RCD predecessors, depended highly and continuously on their allies in Rwanda and Burundi. Without their financial, military and material support, the rebel group would have probably either been defeated in a small amount of time or it had to look for different donors.

Access to natural resources Evidence shows that the Rwandan army and the RCD-Goma gained significant revenue from the trading of diverse natural resources around Kisangani (United Nations, 2001; United Nations, 2002; United Nations, 2010). The rebel group also focused on mineral rich areas in the Kivu-provinces and adopted a strategy called the “archipelago” approach to economic accumulation (Vlassenroot, 2008, p. 5). The illegal activities with the country’s natural resources can be divided into two phases: during the first year resource stockpiles were looted, while after that period one could observe the direct extraction of minerals as well as taxation of mineral companies (United Nations, 2001, pp. 9-10). During the first two years of the second war in 1998 and 1999, the RCD took control of the company SOMINKI (Société minière et industrielle du Kivu) and claimed 6 tons of

36 coltan and 200 tons of cassiterite worth around 722.000 dollars (United Nations, 2001, p. 8). In order to manage the finances and transfers of resources that have been collected, RCD-Goma established SONEX in 1999. The year 2000 saw a change in this administration when the group saw the establishment of the company SOMIGL (Société minière des Grands Lacs), from which it granted monopoly on all coltan exports within the rebel territory control. This monopoly helped to finance the group’s war efforts (Global Witness,

2004, pp. 21-22). In the year 2000, an RCD-Goma leader reported that the group raises around 200.000 dollars a month from diamonds and some one million dollars monthly from coltan (Kisangani, 2003, p. 69). The extractions were higher in that year than in 1999. In 2000, 100kg of gold and 29 tons of coltan a month instead of 60kg of gold and 27 tons of coltan were extracted. Even though more exact figures are not available, evidence suggests that the financial situation of the RCD-Goma has been improving since late 2000 (United Nations, 2001, p. 32). These increased profits can be explained by a boom in coltan in the year 2000 due to a high demand of cell phones and the Christmas release of the Sony PlayStation console. The price of tantalum, the processed form of coltan, was growing and numerous comptoirs (mineral trading houses) opened up in Bukavu and Goma. Thus, between June 2000 and July 2001, the RCD-Goma, the Rwandan government and their business partners experienced record profits (Stearns, 2001, pp. 299-300). Not only did the armed group exploit and trade with the country’s natural resources, but it also collected taxes on businesses who were engaged in such activities: “[…] for economic agents, connection with the rebels was a necessary condition to continue or expand their activities and to increase the predictability of commercial activities in terms of logistics and revenues” (Vlassenroot, 2008, p. 8). The relationship between the rebels and businessmen meant money for the armed group in return for military protection and a reduction of taxes (Vlassenroot, 2008, p. 9).

37

RCD-Goma demanded mining licence fees, non-refundable deposits and various export taxes from companies (Amnesty International, 2003, p. 33). Another important way of increasing their revenue was by shipping gold, diamonds and timber from the DRC through Dar es Salaam in Tanzania, their financial and logistical network. From there, the minerals were sold on to the international market. In exchange, the armed group received cash, arms, medicines, food or other logistical needs (United Nations, 2001, p. 32).

Rwanda’s increase in its mining profits slowly had consequences for the RCD-Goma in that the rebel group’s share then decreased. Rwanda continuously deprived its ally of significant shares and prerogatives. A 2001 Panel report by the United Nations however reported that the RCD-Goma was gradually becoming autonomous in that it was capable of raising big amounts of cash, purchasing its own equipment and using its own networks (United Nations, 2001, p. 32).

Child recruitment strategies The RCD and later also the RCD-Goma were among the groups who recruited most children into their ranks. At first, and with the beginning of the second war in summer 1998, the armed group started recruiting children on a voluntary basis by publicly announcing their awareness raising campaign directed at the parents (United Nations, 2010, p. 310). They did this particularly through broadcasts on the local radio station (, 2001). A year later in 1999, forced recruitment strategies already started to be applied. A former RCD instructor explained: “I was sent to certain zones to recruit people for the RCD army. Because none would volunteer, the RCD forced people into joining its army. In 1999, I was involved in the recruitment of children aged eleven to fifteen in the localities of Kasongo and Kalima in Maniema province. The RCD would usually recruit children from local schools, but the

38

school were closed down because parents feared the campaign. The RCD sent recruiters on a Sunday to wait for children who were on their way to church. A total of 500 children

were rounded up that day in the two localities” (Human Rights Watch, 2001, p. 11). The strategy of voluntary recruitment failed, forcing the RCD soldiers to modify their method of recruitment (United Nations, 2010). A campaign of forced recruitment of children (and also adults) begun in the last quarter of 2000 (Human Rights Watch, 2001). There were however some children who enlisted due to peer-assurance mechanisms, claiming that they joined because there were already many children present in the armed group (Richards, 2014, p. 319). All in all, “unable to encourage large-scale voluntary recruitment and with little popular support to lose, RCD-Goma resorted to more coercive tactics and eventually, forcibly conscriptions” (idem, p. 320). Another reason for forcibly recruiting children besides the absence of voluntary recruits was manpower deficit, particularly when the Mai-Mai were launching new offensives (ibid.). It has to be highlighted that the rebel group got a lot of assistance from its allies in

Rwanda. Not only did the latter send children they recruited in their homeland to the DRC as reinforcement, but they also helped with the recruitment strategies and military training of minors in the neighboring country (Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2001, p. 147). The Rwandese army and RCD-Goma officials further used coercive tactics called Ulinzi, meaning security in Swahili. Children sometimes as young as 13 were being asked to give up by their families in order to carry out basic security patrols (Amnesty

International, 2003, pp. 14-15). The rebel group did not only recruit children by force, but it also found a way to make profit out of it. In summer 2001 for example, RCD-Goma leaders, with the help of soldiers from Rwanda, abducted around 50 children aged 15 to 17. Later on, the group agreed to release some of them in return for money. Some of the children however, and in particular their parents, did not have the financial means to purchase their freedom

(Amnesty International, 2003, p. 42).

39

In 2002, out of 25.000 soldiers, the RCD-Goma claimed an estimated 4.000 teenagers (Kisangani, 2003, p. 59). Until at least June 2003, forced recruitment strategies kept being used by the rebels (United Nations, 2010, p. 310).

Civilian support With the beginning of the second war in 1998 and the gain of military control over the most strategic areas in the Kivu regions, RCD leaders needed to plan the stabilization of their dominant position. Instead of administrating the territories it controlled, the rebel group rather pursued a “largely extractive approach by collecting taxes and exploiting natural resources” (Vlassenroot, 2008, p. 6). On top of that, its leaders made no attempts to integrate the population into local politics. Key local political posts like administrators or governors were thus distributed to prominent members of the RCD, all ultimately leading to a lack of civilian support (idem, p. 7). Overall, the insurgents lacked popular support from the very beginning not only from the non-Rwandophone communities but from a whole population tired of war (Richards, 2014, p. 318). The Kivu regions were particularly characterized by ethnic fragmentation. The RCD- Goma lacked a broad ethnic base and constantly had to rely on Rwandan forces when it came to human and material resources. This aspect led to the fact that the movement was portrayed by civilians as a simple group of greedy foreigners who did not care about the Congolese people. In 2000, this local exasperation turned into a wave of church-led civil disobedience campaigns in the areas the rebel group controlled (Kisangani, 2003, p. 59). Civil unrest was also observed in 2001, where local discontent led children to demonstrate in the streets against policy decisions by the rebels (Amnesty International, 2003, p. 21). On the other hand, with a big stock of economic endowments at their disposal, the rebels had little incentive to mobilize the population. Instead of providing them services, they rather concentrated on military activities (Richards, 2014, p. 319). The overall situation can be explained as following:

40

“The heavy presence of foreign armies, coupled with the fierce exploitation of the natural resources and gross violations of human rights have plunged the majority of the population into a state of hopelessness and helplessness while the rebels (the RCD- Goma in particular) lack clear popular support because of its close association with a

foreign army, that of Rwanda” (Moyroud and Katunga, 2002, p. 180). As of 2001, the RCD-Goma has repeatedly stolen food that was intended for the desperate civilian population in the area of South Kivu. These pillaging operations over a wide geographical area were always carefully planned. Not only food but also hospitals were looted with the help of their Rwandan allies. They also built roadblocks that had to be paid by civilians in order to pass or forced people to perform manual labor. Resistance was often treated with violence, torture or death (Amnesty International, 2003, pp. 16-17). Some authors also talk about “une alliance force d’interêt”, an alliance between civilians and the rebel group which is forced but serves the interests of both. One example can be given for the RCD’s first attack in 1998, where many people fled the areas and were waiting for a chance to return home. The RCD, needing the local workforce in order to profit from the mining sites, called out to the people and invited them home. Here the armed group relied on civilians to continue their economic activities while the people only wanted to live in a secure environment without further attacks (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 141). Coerced relationships, looting and continuous violence all consequently led to an even higher disapproval of the RCD and their successors the RCD-Goma. All of the available literature made clear that the movement lacked popular support from the beginning.

41

2. Mai-Mai

Foreign government support The Mai-Mai were generally not known to be supported by any foreign government during the second war. Some sources however found evidence of the contrary (Amnesty International, 2003; Autessere, 2010). In the territories of Walikale and Masisi, the Rwandese army reportedly allied with armed groups that it usually opposed, such as the Mai-Mai, in order to extract natural commodities. In 2002, leaders from the militia were incorporated into the Rwandese political administration in the province of South-Kivu (Amnesty International, 2003, p. 13). In how far the Mai-Mai benefited from this alliance is not clear, but evidence shows us that even this local defense group has sometimes had some form of foreign government support. Some Mai-Mai groups also got support from their own government. Kinshasa provided them with weapons and ammunitions, but without any training. This national government assistance led to an even further militarization of the eastern countryside

(Stearns, 2011, p. 250). Kabila could not only count on the local militia for support against the RCD-Goma and Rwanda, but he relied also on the Rwandan Hutu rebels located in the DRC. Both armed groups were often fighting side by side against the common enemies and the Hutu rebels even helped train and arm the Mai-Mai (Autesserre, 2010, p. 143). All in all, separating allies from enemies was not always so clear during the Second Congo War. Local agendas influenced collaborations. Some Mai-Mai groups allied with RCD-Goma or Rwandan troops not out of support for their political goals but in order to advance their grassroots agenda (Autesserre, 2010, p. 144).

42

Access to natural resources At the beginning of the second war, the Mai-Mai were generally not involved in the illegal extraction and trade of natural resources. They relied more on non-mineral sources of revenue such as taxation. Roadblock taxes for example constituted a more or less stable source of income. Others in South Kivu benefited from taxes on cattle ranchers (Laudati, 2013, pp. 35-38). Some Mai-Mai groups also obliged the families who live in their controlled territories to provide them with basic food (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers,

2004). Theft was further considered an easy way of enrichment (Nest, 2011). After some time however, various Mai-Mai groups were linking up with other militias and became involved in arms and gold smuggling. Some were also controlling gold, diamond and coltan mines in the East and thus became quite powerful (IRIN News, 2006). Even though Rwanda was seen as the enemy who exploited the people and minerals of the DRC, Mai-Mai groups in the territories of Walikale and Masisi allied with the neighboring country with the goal of easily extracting coltan. In 2002, leaders from the

Mai-Mai mundundu 40 were incorporated into the political administration of Rwanda in

South-Kivu (Amnesty International, 2003, p. 13). Some Mai-Mai groups also created a partnership with the RCD-Goma in order to control columbo-tantalite and cassiterite in Walikale territory in North Kivu. This cooperation started during the second war and continued until early 2004. The militia benefited by taxing the trade at the mines itself whereas the rebel group was taxing the minerals that were being transported out of the area (Autesserre, 2010, p. 154). All in all, even if the Mai-Mai were not involved in the extraction of natural resources from the beginning of the second war, they gradually cooperated with anti-government forces to increase their wealth. “While political and strategic objectives were important at the start of the conflict, all armed groups turned to revenue-raising activities to finance their costly military campaign” (Nest, 2011, p. 76). The table below summarizes the major armed groups during the Second Congo War and their sources of mineral revenue.

43

Being aware that I do not include the taxation of roadblocks, cattle or individuals into my measurement, I nevertheless mentioned the activities above in order to point out which other sources of non-mineral revenue some Mai-Mai groups were dependent on.

Source: Nest, 2011, p. 77

Child recruitment strategies The Mai-Mai already started recruiting children during the First Congo War, particularly in North Kivu. Not only boys but also girls were recruited (United Nations, 2010; Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2001). Ethnicity is not only important for civilian support, as mentioned in the introduction, but also for local recruitment strategies. Thus, “to be successful in military terms and uphold their grip on the local population, armed groups [particularly the Mai-Mai] have progressively recruited along ethnic lines” (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 20). With the beginning of the second war, the militia mobilized young volunteers to fight against their enemies, the RCD. Their recruitment strategy relied at first mostly on persuasion. Former Mai-Mai combatants revealed that those who did not want to join the 44 fight were not forced to do so. Others also reported that they joined the movement voluntarily in order to protect themselves and because they heard rumors about the RCD- Goma recruiting children by force (Richards, 2014, pp. 314-315). Another explanation for children’s decision to join and remain in various militias in the DRC is household security, permitting them to send money and food home (Laudati, 2013, p. 42). After some Mai-Mai leaders noticed that they will not be held accountable for their actions by either the government in Kinshasa or the international community, and as the need for manpower arose while popular support declined, the militia started resorting to force (Richards, 2014, pp. 316-317). The Mai-Mai of Modohu for example did not maintain a peaceful relationship with the population. They stole and forced people to pay taxes in the form of food or at barriers along the streets. Other Mai-Mai groups were also known to recruit children by force from time to time. “When they go to villages to pillage they also kidnap kids, they tattoo them and they sprinkle them with water and after that they send them to fight” (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 162). The Padiri-led Mai-Mai also forcibly recruited children by arguing that the whole population should contribute to the salvation of the country (Hoffmann, 2010, p. 350). In 2002, the estimated amount of children among the ranks of the Mai-Mai was 50 percent of all combatants. Between 2001 and 2003, most of the recruited children were used to carry munitions, serve as cooks and guards or act as sex slaves. Others were of course also used as soldiers (United Nations, 2010, p. 311). Even after the Second Congo War, various Mai-Mai groups at times recruited children by force. Amnesty International found evidence that between 2006 and 2008, children were forcibly recruited and violently punished, sometimes even executed, when they did something wrong (Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2010, p. 10).

45

Civilian support The Mai-Mai generally had high social endowments and diffused a strong community sentiment (Richards, 2014; Vlassenroot, 2008). The relationship between civil society and the Mai-Mai is interdependent. For the militia, civilians are considered to assure the continuation of the movement by providing the combatants with food and human resources, as well as to legitimize their fight. For the people on the other hand, the armed group guarantees their security against opposing forces (Morvan, 2005, p. 48).

Other sub-groups however proved to have different goals in the end. One example is the Mai-Mai militia in South Kivu, which was headed by General Padiri Bulenda. Here, the regions were controlled by a militarized authoritarian government (Vlassenroot, 2008, p. 11). Even though total freedom was preached as a way of life to the population, ideological seminars and repressive justice mechanisms were put in place: “Once military control over a certain territory was secured, local traditional authorities

were solicited, state representatives replaced by local agents loyal to the armed movement, violent regulation mechanisms introduced, economic transactions put under strict control and local population mobilized through shared discourses of collective

protection” (Vlassenroot, 2008, p. 9). The bureaucratic apparatus of the armed group was told to be financed by the taxes and economic activities of the population, yet in the end it rather led to the militarization of mining sites and trading activities. When this Padiri-led Mai-Mai group was offered military assistance in 1998 by the government for its alliance against the opposing RCD rebels, the militia gradually lost its dependence on the civilian population (Vlassenroot, 2008, p. 12). With this support from the capital of Kinshasa, some groups were finally able to control territories rich in natural resources and thus introduced economic endowments. Over time, this increase of economic resources contributed to the growing judgement by

46 some civilians that the combatants are simply bandits and thieves. As a consequence, the Mai-Mai movement experienced a considerable decrease in civilian support by 2004 (Richards, 2014, pp. 316-317). In 2002, the overall perception was still about strong and fearless warriors, whereas the years before they were seen as invincible. In 2004, the Mai- Mai were generally ill reputed (Vlassenroot and Raeymaekers, 2004, p. 172). Local perceptions about an armed group are considered to be connected to their behavior, which demonstrates that over the course of the years the militia started pursuing different goals than solely protecting their population.

vii. Results

Given the observable implications I presented in the previous paragraphs, I will now test whether the data is consistent with my theory and comprises the variation I expect. First, I will recap the hypotheses and then summarize the results for each armed group. In the end I will present a table that should display whether or not I can confirm my hypotheses.

H1: Armed groups with initially low support from civilians and resource bases that neglect human rights, such as natural resources and foreign government support, should be more likely to recruit children by force.

This hypothesis is accurate when observing the armed group RCD-Goma. The rebels lacked civilian support from the very beginning, even dating back to the times when they were still called RCD. This could be seen in the numerous local resistance movements against the group and the image they had among the population, being that of foreign bandits (Amnesty International, 2003). Looting and violence against civilians further show us that they did not need to maintain a relationship with the local population. The rebel group was also known to have had relatively high initial economic endowments (Richards, 2014). With Rwanda as their ally, they not only gained continuous

47 foreign support with combatants and weapons, but they also had a partner with whom they could engage in the extraction and trading of the DRC’s natural resources. These conditions had, as Beber and Blattman (2013) suggest in their theory, an effect on the group’s child recruitment strategy. Indeed, RCD-Goma had the reputation not only to recruit children into their ranks, but also to do this by force. As some interviews with locals in the area under rebel control indicate, voluntary recruitment was absent due to their low prominence, leading to coercion and abduction of children in order to fill their ranks (Human Rights Watch, 2001). The Mai-Mai, contrary to the RCD insurgents, initially had high social endowments. Promoting security and community sentiments along ethnic lines, the militia had a broad base of support at the beginning (Richards, 2014). Most important for the people was that they were fighting the RCD-Goma and their allies, who were considered the biggest enemies of the country. The militia’s initial resource base did generally not consist of support from foreign governments or control over natural resources. The Mai-Mai were very dependent on the population and needed their material, financial (in the form of taxes) and human resource support. Only later can we observe that some groups and leaders were trying to enrich themselves by controlling mining sites and switching alliances (Amnesty International, 2003). Even though the local defence group recruited children during the First and Second Congo War, it was said to be only voluntarily at the beginning. Instead of recruiting by force, the Mai-Mai relied mostly on persuasion. I unfortunately also found some evidence of groups who, after some time, started resorting to force. Particularly after the second war, as of 2006, forced recruitment mechanisms of children became more and more prominent among some Mai-Mai groups (Coalition to Stop the Use of Children, 2010).

48

H2: An increase in armed groups’ economic endowments (natural resources and foreign government support) leads to a change from voluntary to forced child recruitment. As already noted in regard to the first hypothesis, RCD-Goma has always had a good economic resource base. The Rwandan support to the rebels has, according to my data, at no point been disrupted nor did I find evidence that it has at any time increased. However when it comes to the revenues from natural resource extraction, the United

Nations (2001) confirms that there has been a slight increase from 1999 to the year 2000. The monthly extraction of gold and coltan by RCD-Goma rose and thus ameliorated their overall financial situation by late 2000 as opposed to previous years (United Nations, 2001). All in all, the rebel group, its allies and business partners, thanks to the coltan boom, experienced record profits during June 2000 and July 2001 (Stearns, 2001). As mentioned above, RCD-Goma never really recruited voluntarily, they only tried to. Their awareness raising campaign for voluntary recruits started in 1998, but did not succeed. The systematic forced recruitment of children and adults only started in the last quarter of the year 2000. Nevertheless, there were some exceptions, as for example in 1999 where 500 children were abducted in one day (Human Rights Watch, 2001). Since civilian support has always been absent for the group, my causal mechanism does not apply here. The armed group’s increase in economic resources in late 2000 did not have a consequence on its social endowments since it has always been lacking. Some Mai-Mai groups did not content themselves with social endowments alone. In 2002, some leaders from the militia entered an alliance with officials from Rwanda, with the aim of gaining some profit from the gold and coltan industries (Amnesty International, 2003; Nest, 2011). Some groups also gained support from the local government in Kinshasa and the Rwandan Hutu rebels. As of 2006, more and more groups became involved in the trading of minerals and weapons, thus accumulating their wealth.

49

Analyzing the recruitment strategies of the Mai-Mai over the course of the years, we can see a change in the behavior of some groups. When they realized that they cannot be held accountable for their actions and popular support already declined, some groups started resorting to force (Richards, 2014). Padiri’s Mai-Mai justified their forced recruitment strategies by pointing to the conflict and the obligation to save the country (Hoffmann, 2010). There is evidence that between 2006 and 2008 other Mai-Mai groups have also recruited children by force.

Some Mai-Mai groups saw a notable drop in civilian support by the end of the second war. With an increase in its economic resources (support from the government in Kinshasa and the control of mineral rich territories), the Padiri-led group was slowly perceived as a group of bandits, thus experiencing a decline in support. Even though I found evidence that the same Mai-Mai group was forcibly recruiting children, it is not clear due to a lack of more precise dates whether the recruitment strategies were influenced by my independent variable and causal mechanism. I further could not identify if this particular Mai-Mai group initially recruited on a voluntary basis. Even if there was a variation in resource wealth and civilian support, we cannot be sure if this is also the case for their recruitment strategies. However, since all the literature I used mentioned that the Mai-Mai initially recruited children and adults voluntarily, we can assume that this is also the case for the Padiri-led group.

50

Table 1. Hypotheses and results

RCD-Goma Mai-Mai

Hypothesis 1 Low initial civilian YES NO support Good initial YES NO economic resource base Forced child YES NO recruitment Hypothesis 2 Increase in YES SOME** economic resource base Switch from SORT OF* SOME voluntary to forced child recruitment Decrease in civilian NO SOME support (causal mechanism) *Voluntary recruitment of children was indeed the initial goal but could not be accomplished due to lack of civilian support

** Since the Mai-Mai are composed of numerous small groups and no detailed data is available, I cannot account for all of them. “Some” thus means that there is evidence that some groups were involved in illegal trading activities and forced recruitment tactics, but I could not determine which ones and if they are correlated.

The table shows that I find support for Beber and Blattman’s (2013) theory and can thus confirm my first hypothesis for both armed groups. Even though I have to be careful when concluding that all Mai-Mai groups had initially high civilian support and low economic resources, my sources were rather clear and coherent about the initial conditions of the local militia. My second hypothesis is more complex due to a lack of precise data in regard to the variations. Even though I cannot entirely confirm my theory, we can nevertheless

51 observe some kind of correlation between the wealth increase of the armed groups, their level of civilian support and their recruitment strategies. The RCD-Goma saw an increase in their overall financial situation in June 2000 and only a few months later, in the last quarter of the same year, they started their forced recruitment campaign. The fact that they also recruited a large number of children by force in 1999 however lets us believe that there have been individual incidents of forced recruitment before their campaign in 2000. Confirming my hypothesis is problematic since the rebel group never really recruited voluntarily but only intended to. Nevertheless, even the intention should be considered at least partially as voluntary recruitment. We should also not forget that their forced recruitment campaign was not only directed at children, but also adults. The Mai-Mai on the other hand are difficult to track down due to their number of sub-groups. There have been situations where some groups increased their economic resources through sources of mineral revenue, but we do not know if those are also the ones who were engaged in the forced recruitment of children or if those were the ones losing civilian support. Only the Padiri-led Mai-Mai gives us more detailed information about the variation in resources, civilian support and recruitment strategies. More precise dates, as well as information about the initial child recruitment mechanisms of this particular Mai-Mai group, were needed in order to confirm my second hypothesis. By collecting all these data on the armed groups, we notice however that over time their endowments and recruitment strategies changed and that we can thus at least consider a correlation between these variables. My results highlight the complexity of armed groups and their strategies. All in all, I do not find enough detailed evidence to fully support my second hypothesis nor my causal mechanism. There is nevertheless some evidence that the armed groups switched from voluntary to forced child recruitment and we can assume that this correlates to some degree with an increase in their resource wealth. A lack or decrease in civilian support, whether it occurs before or after the rise of a group’s economic resources, appears to always have an effect on recruitment strategies.

52 viii. Discussion

After having presented my results, I want to account for alternative explanations of the observed outcome. Besides an increase in its resource wealth, there is one other possible reason why an armed group may switch from voluntary to forced recruitment of children. When there is a troop shortage in times of high conflict, and in particular if rebels do not have civilian support to rely on voluntary recruits, forced recruitment strategies may seem like the only option. Richards (2014) clearly highlights this for the case of the RCD-Goma. When the Mai-Mai were launching new attacks and the rebels experienced manpower deficit, they resorted to the forced recruitment of children (Richards, 2014). A sudden lack of voluntary recruits (which may have been brought about by an unforeseen decline in civilian support), with the combination of an urge to recruit a high number of soldiers, leaves armed groups with no other alternative than to abduct children, who represent the easiest and cheapest form of recruits (Andvig, 2006; Lasley and Thyne, 2015). The decline in civilian support as causal mechanism also deserves an alternative explanation than only being the cause of an armed group’s increase in resources. During my data collection I noticed how alliances influence armed groups’ reputation among civilians. Moyroud and Katunga (2002) emphasize this by describing that the RCD-Goma lacked popular support because of its close relationship with Rwanda. Some Mai-Mai groups on the other hand gradually lost civilian support because a shift in alliances also meant an increase in economic resources (Richards, 2014). Whether alliances are connected to economic resources is not of importance. I would rather like to point out that some cooperations between armed groups or governments produce a negative image and can have consequences on their popular support. It is also possible that a change in alliance increases civilian support and establishes a good image upon the group. In my case however, the allies of both armed groups helped them to secure and even increase their economic resources, consequently leading to a loss of popular support. Alliances, resource wealth and civilian support are thus closely correlated in this research. 53

Beber and Blattman (2013) mention the diversity of natural resources when accounting for their effect on child recruitment strategies. They argue that some resources are not as easily extracted without the cooperation of civilians (Beber and Blattman, 2013, p. 99). Raúl Sánchez de la Sierra (2017) brought up this topic by looking at how a demand shock for coltan and gold influenced the behavior of armed actors in regard to the civilian population in the DRC. Coltan, a bulky commodity, is easy to tax and leads armed groups to provide protection at coltan-producing locations. Gold on the other hand can easily be hidden in order to avoid output tax. As a response, armed groups form monopolies of violence in the territories in which gold miners work and raise different forms of taxes (de la Sierra, 2017, pp. 1-4). These so-called stationary bandits “[…] will be tempted to protect in order to provide incentives to invest and trade, since they benefit from it at least through the taxes they collect” (idem, p. 13). Armed groups that are active in coltan mines depend less on taxing and administrating civilians at the support village since they are taxing the mineral trade (idem, p. 33). This theory may also explain why in some areas children are forcibly recruited whereas in others they are not. Armed actors in gold municipalities are much more dependent on civilians than groups that are located in coltan rich areas. According to Faulkner (2016) and Beber and Blattman (2013), armed groups that rely on civilian support are more likely to refrain from forcibly recruiting children. Overall, one alternative explanation about why some groups experience a rise in economic resources but do not switch their recruitment strategies may be their dependence on civilians in the form of taxes. One possible hypothesis could be that armed actors controlling gold municipalities are less likely to recruit children by force. Since Beber and Blattman’s (2013) theory about initial endowments proved right for my case, I believe that economic resources highly influence an armed group’s recruitment decisions. As already mentioned in the theory section, I assume that initially every group at least tries to have a good relationship with the local population in order to legitimize their fight and control the territories they live in. After some time, in case a

54 movement grows bigger and wealthier, their image among civilians declines. We can observe this for both armed groups who were subsequently seen as greedy foreigners or simple bandits after having increased their resource wealth (Kisangani, 2003; Richards, 2014). Individual interests thus become the dominant incentive in the conflict. Since maintaining a relationship with the local population requires a lot of effort, groups gradually become independent when they gained enough resources (Salehyan et al., 2014). All in all, the fact that an increase in an armed group’s resources portrays such a bad image onto the population and accountability of the former decreases due to higher independence, makes me think that a rise in economic resources is the main reason for forced child recruitment strategies. However, I could have strengthened my results by choosing a different armed group than the Mai-Mai, which is composed of diverse small groups. I would have found more concrete evidence with a homogeneous group. But because the Mai-Mai and RCD- Goma are opposing groups with different initial endowments, an analysis of their development throughout the Second Congo War and observation of their distinguishing characteristics seemed like an interesting approach. My findings could have also changed if I chose a rebel group which did not initially have high economic resources and low civilian support as is the case for the RCD-Goma. More variation concerning their resource wealth, civilian support and recruitment strategies would have enabled additional observations and consequently more conclusive correlations. Also, a different methodology could have helped with the collection of more fine- grained data. Field research on the various Mai-Mai groups may have permitted more precise correlation between my variables. The finding of more specific dates about the increase of a group’s wealth or change in recruitment strategies would have facilitated the identification of correlations. The decline of civilian support as causal mechanism was hard to measure since the evidence I found did not make it clear whether it happened before or after the group’s increase in economic resources. Additionally, I could have included

55 non-mineral sources of revenue to my variable “economic resources”. Especially for the Mai-Mai, who were only later partially involved in the extraction of natural resources, other sources of income like the trading of wildlife, taxation and looting could have accounted for more evidence on the increase of resources. I did mention some of these sources in my data collection but did not account for them in my results. All these last points weaken my internal validity but they do not eliminate the fact that increased resources and a change in child recruitment are somewhat correlated.

My results are unfortunately not generalizable to other cases since I could not confirm both hypotheses for both groups. However, since we can observe some kind of weak correlation between the variables of my second hypothesis, and considering the fact that my two cases are more complex than expected, my theory still might find confirmation with easier cases. My findings could be generalizable to other cases if I only chose homogeneous groups and the results were clearer.

V. Conclusion

This research has examined the question of what contributes to the variation in armed groups’ child recruitment strategies. Relying on Beber and Blattman’s (2013) theory about why violent actors forcibly recruit children in the first place, I intent to point to the shift from voluntary to forced recruitment practices. The comparison of the RCD-Goma rebels and Mai-Mai militia groups during the Second Congo War highlights the influence of accumulation of resource wealth and diminishing civilian support on recruitment strategies. My findings show that an increase in economic resources and cooperation with a national or foreign government can have a negative impact on a group’s reputation and thus decline civilian support. This support is crucial for voluntary recruits and has leverage on armed groups’ future recruitment activities. Evidence from the RCD rebels also lets us believe that forced recruitment of children is never the first option.

56

Understanding the reasons and timing of violent organization’s shift in child recruitment strategies could help to reduce the number of children falling victim to forced recruitment campaigns. This research aims to raise awareness about the fact that armed groups which have refrained from using coercive recruitment tactics do not necessarily do so in the future. Cooperation with armed groups that are engaged in the illegal extraction and trading of natural resources, as well as the funding of rebel groups, should be more severely condemned by the international community. The findings in this paper contribute to the study of child soldiers and to the resource curse literature (Bannon and Collier, 2003). This research further leans on theories by Salehyan et al. (2014), Faulkner (2016) and Beber and Blattman (2010, 2013) by looking at forced recruitment mechanisms but also incorporating an initial phase of voluntary recruitment campaigns. The existing scholarship has demonstrated that child recruitment can have multifactorial explanations. This paper took these under consideration and enhanced the complexity of armed groups. One way to extend my research could be to adopt Raúl

Sánchez de la Sierra’s (2017) theory about the different taxation methods of gold and coltan during a demand shock. Armed groups’ dependence on civilians due to the benefit of taxation illustrates one possible explanation about why forced recruitment may happens in some places rather than others. Future research can thus try and focus more on the weaknesses of violent organizations in order to educate the people at risk about possible ways to protect themselves. Additionally, better access to valid and detailed data can help to overcome the challenge of data collection and improve generalizability. All in all I think that scholars, organizations, businesses and policymakers should work together to break the vicious circle that a lot of children have to experience, an experience that includes poverty, civil war, recruitment into armed groups and consequently posttraumatic stress disorders that can have grave consequences on their future lives. National governments should be more inclined to protect its people and target goals that reach far beyond personal enrichment and power.

57

VI. Bibliography

Achvarina, V. & Reich F. S., 2006. No Place to Hide: Refugees, Displaced Persons, and the Recruitment of Child Soldiers. International Security, 31(1), pp. 127-164. Available at: http://www.jstor.org.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/stable/pdf/4137541.pdf?refreqid=excelsior:72 3bbdef507a4bc9ccc0c23f74ce07d0 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Amnesty International, 2003. Democratic Republic of the Congo. "Our brothers who help kill us". Economic exploitation and human rights abuses in the east. Available at: https://www.amnesty.org/en/documents/afr62/010/2003/en/ [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Andvig, J. C., 2006. Child Soldiers: Reasons for variation in their rate of recruitment and standards of welfare. Norwegian Institute of International Affairs, Issue 704, pp. 7-40. Available at: https://brage.bibsys.no/xmlui/bitstream/handle/11250/2395409/WP_nr704_06_Andvig.p df?sequence=3&isAllowed=y [Accessed 10 June 2017].

Autesserre, S., 2010. The Trouble with the Congo. Local Violence and the Failure of International Peacebuilding. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Bannon, I. & Collier, P., 2003. Natural Resources and Violent Conflict: Options and Actions. Washington: The World Bank. Available at: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/578321468762592831/pdf/282450Natural0 resources0violent0conflict.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017).

BBC, 2016. Democratic Republic of Congo profile- Timeline. Available at: http://www.bbc.com/news/world-africa-13286306 [Accessed 19 June 2017].

Beber, B. & Blattman, C., 2010. The Industrial Organization of Rebellion: The Logic of Forced Labor and Child Soldiering. HiCN Working Papers, Issue 72, pp. 1-45.

Beber, B. & Blattman, C., 2013. The Logic of Child Soldiering and Coercion. International Organization, 67(1), pp. 65-104. Available at: https://www-cambridge- org.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2443/core/services/aop-cambridge- core/content/view/EB8CC2FE13CC49C2846EEDE4FFD432FE/S0020818312000409a.pdf/lo gic_of_child_soldiering_and_coercion.pdf [Accessed 4 April 2017].

58

Bleasdale, M., 2003. A child soldier rides back to his base in Ituri Province. Children are routinely recruited as soldiers in Congo by all sides. Photograph. Available at: https://www.hrw.org/news/2015/10/01/dispatches-obama-still-arms-governments- using-child-soldiers [Accessed 14 June 2017].

Bracken, P. J., Giller, J. E. & Ssekiwanuka, J. K., 1996. The rehabilitation of child soldiers: Defining needs and appropriate responses. Medicine and War, 12(2), pp. 114-125. Available at: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/13623699608409268 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Brett, R. & Specht, I., 2004. Young Soldiers: Why They Choose To Fight. London: Lynne Rienner Publishers.

Bryman, A., 2016. Social Research Methods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Child Soldiers International. Where are there Soldiers? Available at: https://www.child- soldiers.org/where-are-there-child-soldiers [Accessed 6 June 2017].

Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2000. The Use of Children as Soldiers in Africa. A country analysis of child recruitment and participation in armed conflict. Available at: http://reliefweb.int/sites/reliefweb.int/files/resources/C157333FCA91F573C1256C130033 E448-chilsold.htm [Accessed 6 June 2017].

Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2001. Global Report on Child Soldiers, London: Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers. Available at: https://www.child- soldiers.org/Handlers/Download.ashx?IDMF=adc88bff-1916-4317-b184-d9079e7b0bb8 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2010. Child rights international network. Available at: https://www.crin.org/en/docs/Mai_Mai_child_recruitment_and_use_in_the_DRC_- _February_2010.pdf [Accessed 4 June 2017].

Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers, 2010. Democratic Republic of the Congo. Mai Mai Child Solider Recruitment and Use: Entrenched and Unending, London: Coalition to Stop the Use of Child Soldiers. Available at: http://www.refworld.org/docid/4b8b7c492.html [Accessed 13 June 2017].

59

Cohen, D. K., 2013. Explaining Rape during Civil War: Cross-National Evidence (1980- 2009). American Political Science Review, 107(3), pp. 461-477. Available at: https://www- cambridge-org.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2443/core/services/aop-cambridge- core/content/view/30FC323D6DA7E923547156CC0E947213/S0003055413000221a.pdf/e xplaining_rape_during_civil_war_crossnational_evidence_19802009.pdf [Accessed 9 June 2017].

Cohen, D. K., 2013. Supplement Materials for "Explaining Rape During Civil War: Cross- National Evidence (1980-2009)", Harvard: American Political Science Review. Available at: https://static-cambridge- org.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2443/resource/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20161018115912443- 0342:S0003055413000221:S0003055413000221sup001.pdf [Accessed 9 June 2017].

De la Sierra, R. S., 2017. On the origins of the state: Stationary bandits and the taxation in eastern Congo. Available at: https://raulsanchezdelasierra.files.wordpress.com/2013/09/revised-manuscript.pdf [Accessed 8 June 2017].

Derluyn, I., Sofie, V. & De Haene, L., 2013. Toward a Relational Understanding of the Reintegration and Rehabilitation Processes of Former Child Soldiers. Journal of Aggression, Maltreatment & Trauma, 22(8), pp. 869-886. Available at: http://www- tandfonline- com.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/doi/pdf/10.1080/10926771.2013.824058?needAccess=true [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Eck, K., 2014. Coercion in Rebel Recruitment. Security Studies, 23(2), pp. 364-398. Available at: http://www-tandfonline- com.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/doi/pdf/10.1080/09636412.2014.905368?needAccess=true [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Estefanía, L., Awazi, A. & Salcedo-Albarán, E., 2016. Trafficking of Coltan in the Democratic Republic of Congo No. 4, Bogotá: Vortex Foundation. Available at: http://globalinitiative.net/wp- content/uploads/2016/12/522e46_bee14894ac2a4354a2ae49710c88bdd0.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

60

Faulkner, C. M., 2016. Money and Control: Rebel Groups and the Forcible Recruitment of Child Soldiers. African Security, 9(3), pp. 211-236. Available at: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/19392206.2016.1208472 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Global Witness, 2004. Same Old Story. A background study on natural resources in the Democratic Republic of Congo. Available at: https://www.globalwitness.org/en/archive/same-old-story/ [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Global Witness, 2009. Natural Resource Exploitation and Human Rights in the Democratic Republic of Congo 1993 to 2003. Available at: https://www.globalwitness.org/sites/default/files/pdfs/drc_exploitation_and_human_right s_abuses_93_03_en.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Global Security. Congo Civil War/First Congo War- 1996-1998. Available at: http://www.globalsecurity.org/military/world/war/congo-1.htm [Accessed 19 June 2017].

Global Security. Second Congo War (1998-2003). Available at: http://www.globalsecurity.org/military/world/war/congo-2.htm [Accessed 19 June 2017].

Guichaoua, Y., 2007. Who Joins Ethnic Militias? A Survey of the Oodua People's Congress in South western Nigeria, Oxford: Centre for Research on Inequality, Human Security and Ethnicity. Available at: http://www.hicn.org/wordpress/wp- content/uploads/2012/06/wp26.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Haer, R. & Boehmelt, T., 2016. The impact of child soldiers on rebel groups' fighting capacities. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 33(2), pp. 153-173. Available at: http://journals.sagepub.com.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/doi/pdf/10.1177/0738894215570424 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Haer, R. & Boehmelt, T., 2017. Could rebel child soldiers prolong civil wars? Cooperation and Conflict, pp. 1-28. Available at: http://journals.sagepub.com.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/doi/pdf/10.1177/0010836716684880 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Hoffmann, K., 2010. The ethics of child-soldiering in the Congo. Young, Nordic Journal of Youth Research, 18(3), pp. 339-358. Available at: http://journals.sagepub.com.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/doi/pdf/10.1177/1103308810018003 06 [Accessed 11 June 2017].

61

Honwana, A., 2006. Child Soldiers in Africa. Pennsylvania: University of Pennsylvania Press.

Human Rights Watch, 2001. Democratic Republic of the Congo. Reluctant recruits: Children and adults forcibly recruited for military service in North Kivu. Available at: https://www.hrw.org/reports/2001/drc3/Goma.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Integrated Regional Information Networks (IRIN), 2006. IRIN News. Available at: http://www.irinnews.org/report/58443/drc-protection-insurgency-history-mayi-mayi [Accessed 5 May 2017].

Jourdan, L., 2011. Mayi-Mayi: Young Rebels in Kivu, DRC. Africa Development, 36(3 & 4), pp. 89-111. Available at: https://www.ajol.info/index.php/ad/article/view/74117/64777 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Karbo, T. & Mutisi, M., 2012. Ethnic Conflict in the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC). In: D. Landis & R. D. Albert, Handbook of Ethnic Conflict. Springer US, pp. 381-402.

King, G., Keohane, R.O., Verba, S., 1994. Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Kisangani, E. F., 2003. Conflict in the Democratic Republic of Congo: A Mosaic of Insurgent Groups. International Journal on World Peace, 20(3), pp. 51-80. Available at: http://www.jstor.org.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/stable/pdf/20753410.pdf?refreqid=excelsior:7 4f8c685ed39442b7814ad6224596659 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Lasley, T. & Thyne, C., 2015. Secession, legitimacy and the use of child soldiers. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 32(3), pp. 289-308. Available at: http://journals.sagepub.com.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/doi/pdf/10.1177/0738894214526541 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Laudati, A., 2013. Beyond minerals: broadening ´economies of violence` in eastern Democratic Republic of Congo. Review of African Political Economy, 135(40), pp. 32-50. Available at: http://www-tandfonline- com.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/doi/pdf/10.1080/03056244.2012.760446?needAccess=true [Accessed 13 June 2017].

62

Lieberman, E. S., 2005. Nested Analysis as a Mixed-Method Strategy for Comparative Research. American Political Science Review, 99(3), pp. 435-452. Available at: https://www-cambridge-org.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2443/core/services/aop-cambridge- core/content/view/D4FF59D175D761C20BD6CE440AFD700B/S0003055405051762a.pdf/ nested_analysis_as_a_mixedmethod_strategy_for_comparative_research.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Machel, G., 1996. Impact of armed conflict on children, New York: United Nations. Available at: http://www.un.org/documents/ga/docs/51/plenary/a51-306.htm [Accessed 13 June 2017].

McBride, J., 2014. The War Crime of Child Soldier Recruitment. The Hague: T.M.C. Asser Press. Available at: http://web.b.ebscohost.com.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/ehost/ebookviewer/ebook/bmxlYmtf XzY2MDA5M19fQU41?sid=def0dcd7-9cc3-4b80-9f7e- bf2dae20e638@sessionmgr103&vid=0&format=EB&rid=1 [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Morvan, H., 2005. Réinventer le quotidien. La cohabitation des populations civiles et des combattants mai-mai au Kivu, Östervala: Life & Peace Institute. Available at: http://www.life-peace.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/06/reinventer.pdf [Accessed 25 May 2017].

Moyroud, C. & Katunga, J., 2002. Coltan Exploration in Eastern Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC). In: J. Lind & K. Sturman, Hrsg. Scarcity and Surfeit: The Ecology of Africa's Conflicts. Pretoria: Institute for Security Studies, pp. 159-181. Available at: https://issafrica.s3.amazonaws.com/site/uploads/SCARCITYCHAPTER4.PDF [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Nest, M., 2011. Coltan. Cambridge: Polity Press.

One World Nations Online. Administrative Map of the Democratic Republic of the Congo. Available at: http://www.nationsonline.org/oneworld/map/dr_congo_map.htm [Accessed 17 May 2017].

Peace Direct, 2009. Democratic Republic of the Congo: Conflict profile. Available at: https://www.insightonconflict.org/conflicts/dr-congo/conflict-profile/ [Accessed 19 June 2017].

63

Richards, J., 2014. Forced, coerced and voluntary recruitment into rebel and militia groups in the Democratic Republic of Congo. Journal of Modern African Studies, 52(2), pp. 301-326. Available at: https://www-cambridge- org.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2443/core/services/aop-cambridge- core/content/view/6842D5D8E2A4725A2A994D168D66C167/S0022278X14000044a.pdf/ forced_coerced_and_voluntary_recruitment_into_rebel_and_militia_groups_in_the_democ ratic_republic_of_congo.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Salehyan, I., Siroky, D. & Wood, R. M., 2014. External Rebel Sponsorship and Civilian Abuse: A Principal-Agent Analysis of Wartime Atrocities. International Organization, Issue 68, pp. 633-661. Available at: https://www-cambridge- org.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2443/core/services/aop-cambridge- core/content/view/7B8C7423A615E804A829E95AEE9E4A39/S002081831400006Xa.pdf/e xternal_rebel_sponsorship_and_civilian_abuse_a_principalagent_analysis_of_wartime_atro cities.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Singer, P. W., 2005. Children at War. New York: Pantheon Books.

Stearns, J. K., 2011. Dancing in the Glory of Monsters. The Collapse of the Congo and the Great War of Africa. 1. New York: PublicAffairs.

UNICEF, 2011. Child recruitment by armed forces or armed groups. Available at: https://www.unicef.org/protection/57929_58007.html [Accessed 5 June 2017].

United Nations, 1999. Security Council strongly condemns targeting of children in situations of armed conflict, including their recruitment and use as soldiers. Available at: http://www.un.org/press/en/1999/19990825.sc6716.html [Accessed 5 June 2017].

United Nations, 2001. Report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources and Other Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo. Available at: http://www.securitycouncilreport.org/atf/cf/%7B65BFCF9B-6D27-4E9C- 8CD3-CF6E4FF96FF9%7D/DRC%20S%202001%20357.pdf [Accessed 19 June 2017].

United Nations, 2002. Final report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources and Other Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo. Available at: https://www.srwolf.com/reports/UNCONGO.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

United Nations, 2010. Democratic Republic of the Congo, 1993-2003. Available at: http://www.genocidewatch.org/images/DRC10_06_xx_Report_Draft_Democratic_Republic _of_the_Congo_1993-2003.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

64

United Nations. Children, Not Soldiers. Available at: https://childrenandarmedconflict.un.org/children-not-soldiers/ [Accessed 19 June 2017].

Vlassenroot, K., 2008. Armed Groups and Militias in Eastern DR Congo. Lecture Series on African Security.

Vlassenroot, K. & Timothy, R., 2004. Conflict and Social Transformation in Eastern DR Congo. Gent: Academia Press. Available at: file:///C:/Users/Jessica/Downloads/boek_crg.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Weinstein, J. M., 2003. Resources and the Information Problem in Rebel Recruitment. The Center for Global Development and Stanford University. Available at: http://www- personal.umich.edu/~satran/Ford%2006/Wk%207- 2%20Terrorism%20background%20insurgency%20Weinstein.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Wessells, M., 2005. Child Soldiers, Peace Education, and Postconflict Reconstruction for Peace. Theory Into Practice, 44(4), pp. 363-369. Available at: http://www-tandfonline- com.proxy.uba.uva.nl:2048/doi/pdf/10.1207/s15430421tip4404_10?needAccess=true [Accessed 13 June 2017].

Wiliams, C., 2013. Explaining the Great War in Africa: How Conflict in the Congo Became a Continental Crisis. The Fletcher Forum of World Affairs, 37(2), pp. 81-100. Available at: https://static1.squarespace.com/static/579fc2ad725e253a86230610/t/57ec7c4abe659480 8a456999/1475116113924/Williams-37-2.pdf [Accessed 13 June 2017].

65

VII. Appendices

A. Cross national survey of African rebel groups, Beber and Blattman (2013)

This cross national survey provides quantitative data of 10 African countries, their rebel groups, methods of recruitment and initial endowments and has been used for the case selection strategy.

90pp 1980pp p a c p d g

374 374 374 374 374

275 275 275 275 275 275 275 275 275 130 130 130 130 130 130 130 130 130 267 267 346 346 346 680 544

693 693 275 275 130

3.884

1.154 1.154 1.154 1.154 i 1980 p a c p d g l a min o n 93 93 93 93 93 93 93 93 93

93

562 562 562 562 562

367 367 367 367 367 367 367 367 367

190 190 268 268 268 588 278

885 885 367 367

2.764

1.205 1.205 1.205 1.205 tne fict um td c nfli o ntensec i

1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 esur mt a e rc sou re

2 2 2 1 3 3 1 1 2 1 2 2 3 1 1 1 1 3 2 3 3

2

1 1 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 3

2 1 2 3 esur 4 e rc sou re

5 6

5 6

7 7 6

4 esur 3 e rc sou re

4 5

2 6

4 5 4 4 5

4

2

6 6

6 2

6 6 4

4 4 4 2

4

2 esur 2 e rc sou re

2 3 2 2 1 2

2 3 4 2 2 3

2 4 6 5 5 2

5 4

7 4 4 3

1 1 1 1

5 4 1 6 esur 1 e rc sou re

1 1 1 1

3 2 3 2 3

2 4 6 6 5 4 2 5

4 6 3 3 4 2 3 1 5

5 1 3

5

other other

none none

future pay future future pay future future pay future future pay future

future pay future emnert n o rati e mun re

arms

none none

arms arms

none none

none

none

none

none none none none none none none

none

none

none

other

other

other

other

future pay future future pay future

future pay future

monetary wage monetary monetary wage monetary

monetary wage monetary

monetary wage monetary

monetary wage monetary monetary wage monetary monetary wage monetary monetary wage monetary

monetary wage monetary

monetary wage monetary a oupsze siz p u ro g max 300 400

800

6.500

7.000

8.500

5.000

1.000 3.000

5.500 7.000 3.000 7.000 8.000 2.500

3.000 2.300

7.000

4.000 1.000 8.000

17.500

30.000 20.000

18.000

21.000

40.000

42.500

12.000

100.000 utinact 1yr v ti c a n sustai

1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 utinact 2yr v ti c a n sustai

1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1

1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 sct e v ti rsac a e y

5

3 8 6

1 4 8 5 6 8

2 7 2

3

5 6

3

4 8

1

2 2 2 3

3 6

28

20

10

13

16

16 defnct c fun e rd a e y

2003

1999 2006 2005 1990 1987 1999 2004 1992 1986 2004 2007 1982 1986

1991

1998

2006

2002 2004 1991 1997

1995 1996

1999

2004 2004 2004 2004

1988 1986 1998 funded e d n rfou a e y

1998 2006 1996 1998 1999 1962 1986 1995 1996 1987 1980 1996 1987 1980 1979 2008 1981 2007 1981 2004 2000 1989 1989 2001 1975 1991 2007 1991 1988 1982 1998 2002 2002 2002 2002 2001 2003 1985 1979 1982 oadspport o p sup d a ro b

1 2 0 0 1 2 2 0 1 1 2 0 0 2

1 2 1

1 2

2

1 2 0 1 2 2 2 1 0 0

2 2 1 1 2 asm ion o ti rassump a v y e k

0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 1 o asm ion o ti rassump e i d sol

0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 1 0 1 ecr mnt tmen i ru c re

0 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 ildsldieroung n u ryo e i d sol d l hi c

0 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 ildsldier e i d sol d l hi c

1 1 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 4 0 1 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 0 1 oupname a n p u ro g

FN

UIC

ASJ

ALF

LRA

ARS

USC

MJP

RCD

UPA

ADF

HRK

SPM

AIAI

NRA

UFM

FIAA MPA

MLC MLC

HSM

SNM

AFDL

SSDF

SRRC

MPCI

UNRF

UPDA FUNA

WNBF

MFDC

CNDP CNDP

ARDUF

MPIGO

NDPVF

UNRF II UNRF

SWAPO

ATNMC

MJCDPJ

RCD–ML

Al-Shabaab try n u o c

DRC DRC DRC DRC DRC

Mali Mali Mali

Nigeria Nigeria

Uganda Uganda Uganda Uganda Uganda Uganda Uganda Uganda Uganda

Uganda Uganda

Somalia Somalia Somalia Somalia Somalia Somalia Somalia Somalia Somalia

Senegal

Somalia

Ethiopia Ethiopia

South Africa South

Cote d'Ivoire Cote Cote d'Ivoire Cote Cote d'Ivoire Cote Cote d'Ivoire Cote

Guinea-Bissua fict d i t_ c nfli o c

86 86 86 86 86

101 118 118 118 118 118 118 118 118 118 141 141 141 141 141 141 141 141 141 168 168 177 177 177 180 216 225 225 225 225 250 250 118 118 141 id

861 862 863 864 865

1011 1181 1182 1183 1184 1185 1186 1187 1188 1189 1411 1412 1413 1414 1415 1416 1417 1418 1419 1681 1682 1771 1772 1773 1801 2161 2251 2252 2253 2254 2501 2502

11810 11811 14110

B. Variable coding of cross national survey, Beber and Blattman (2010)

Here I only present the codes of the variables that are relevant for my theory, namely child recruitment, civilian support and resources. I used the exact same definitions as the authors but reduced them to their main significance.

recruitment [Forced Recruitment]

This variable measures how the rebel group recruited soldiers.

0- mostly voluntary, defined as less than 20% of recruits forcibly recruited

1- mixed, defines as more than 20% of recruits and less than 80% forcibly recruited

2- mostly forced, defined as more than 80% of recruits forcibly recruited childsoldier [Percentage recruits under 18]

0- less than 5%

1- 5-19%

2- 20-39%

3- 40-59%

4- 60-80% childsoldieryoung [Recruits under 15]

0- Less than 5% of recruits are under the age of 15

1- More than 5% of recruits are under the age of 15 broadsupport [Degree of initial civilian support]

This variable measures whether the group had the (non-coerced) support of the population in its base region within home country on which it could draw for resources, cooperation, or harbor.

2=YES

1=MIXED (combination of yes and no, or experiencing a shift in support over time)

0=NO resourcetype

This variable measures the group’s resources by type and aims to measure the primary sources of each group’s financial and material resources. Importantly, this coding captures categories but not magnitudes.

1- natural resources

2- foreign governments

3- local community

4- seizure/looting coercive taxation

5- private wealth domestic

6- private wealth foreign

7- smuggling-not natural resource resourceamt [Initial material resources]

This variable measures the group’s resources by amount.

1- resource low

2- resource medium

3- resource high