Degrees of Proportionality Proportionality of Proportional Rep

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Degrees of Proportionality Proportionality of Proportional Rep Lijphart & Grofman - Electoral Laws and their political consequences(2003) CHAPTER 10 Degrees of Proportionality of Proportional Representation Formulass Avend tt iiss aa wweellll--estatablblisishedd propositition in the liliteteraratuturere on elelectotoraral syss-- Itetems thatt proportitional representatatition (PR) iiss generarallllyy quititee cessful in achieving its principal goal --aa rreeaassoonnaabbllyy prooporrtitioonall translation ooff votes into seats--especiallyy inin comparison with plurality and majorityy formulas. One ooff RRaaee’’s ((11997711, 96)) ”differentialal proposi-- tions” isis that “proportional representation formulae tend to allocate seats more proportionally than do majority and plurality formulae.”.”ItIt isis alsoo known that different PPRR formulas are not equally proportional, but students ooff PPRR disagree aboutt which ooff ththee formulas are more and d which are less proportional. TThhee ppuurrppoossee ooff tthhiiss aannaallyyssiiss iiss ttoo eessttaabblliisshh a rraannk oorrddeer ooff tthhee principal PR formululas aaccccoorrdidinngg ttoo tthheeiirr degree oof f proportionality. II shalalll usee BBlloonnddeell’’ss ((11996699,, pp. 118866--119911)) rarankiningg ooff the ablele votete,, Saintee--LLaagguuee,, aanndd llaarrggeesstt rreemmaaiinnddeer ssyysstteemmss--ththee mosstt importrtant attttempt ttoo rarank order PPRR formululas undertakenn so far --aass mmyy pprreelliimmiinnaarryy hypotthessiiss.. IInn aaddiittiion ttoo ththee four formuulalass aannaallyyzzeedd bbyy II sshhaalll aallsso ttrry ttoo iinncclluuddee tthhee ttwwo IImmppeerriiaallii formululas iinn mmyy rarankining.g. Thee degree ooff proportitionalalitityy mmaayy be defifined in tetermss ooff two elelee-- Proportionality of PR Formulas 272 degree to which large and small parties are treated equally. It is the second element that provides a clear criterion for judging the propor - tionality of PR formulas, because deviations from proportionality are not random: They tend to systematically favor the larger and to dis- criminate against the smaller parties. Blondel's Ranking Blonde1 (1969, p. 191) ranks four PR formulas in the following de- creasing order of proportionality: 1. Single transferable vote (STV) 2. Sainte-Lague 3. 4. Largest remainders STV is therefore the most, and the largest remainder method the least, proportional formula, according to Blondel. Other, more limi- ted, attempts to determine the proportionality of PR systems tend to (1)ignore the STV method, (2) agree with Blondel's judgment that the formula is less proportional than the Sainte-Lague formula, and (3) disagree with Blondel's placement of the largest remainder formula at the bottom of the list. Loosemore and Hanby (1971)consider three of Blondel's four formu- las, and they arrive at the following rank order: 1. Largest remainders 2. Sainte-Lague 3. Their relative placement of Sainte-Lagueand is in agreement with Blondel's, but they conclude that the largest remainder formula is the most proportional of the three. Rae (1971, p. 105)also finds that the largest remainder method is more proportional than the other two lumped together. Balinski and Young (1980) confirm the Loosemore- Hanby finding that the Sainte-Lague formula, equivalent to the ster method of apportionment of the U.S. House of Representatives, yields more proportional results than the formula, which is the equivalent of the Jeffersonmethod of apportionment. Most of the literature confines itself to a comparison of the 172 Arend Lijphart est remainder formula is more proportional and more favorable to the smaller parties (Van den Bergh, 1955, pp. 24-26; Mackenzie, 1958, 78-80; 1974, 93-97; Berrington, 1975, 366-368; Nohlen, 1978, pp. 77-80; Bon, 1978, This consensus deviates from Blondel’s ranking. In the next section, I shall show that the consensus is right and that Blonde1is wrong. Comparing d‘Hondt and Largest Remainders A comparison of the d’Hondt and largest remainder for - mulas is a good starting point for our exercise because it also supplies us with the key we need for the ranking of the other PR methods. How can we explain the different results of these two basic PR formu- las? The initial difficulty is that the d’Hondt and largest remainder for - mulas appear to use completely different methods for allocating seats on the basis of the parties’ votes. Table 10.1gives a concrete illustra- tion. The largest remainder formula first calculates the electoral quota or quotient (often called the Hare quota): the total number of valid votes cast divided by the total number of seats in the district (s). The parties’ votes are divided by this quota, and each party receives a seat for every whole number in the result. The remaining seats are then awarded to the largest of the unused ”remainders” or remaining votes. The d’Hondt formula does not require the calculation of an electoral quota. As Table 10.1shows, each party’s votes are divided by the series of divisors 1, 2, 3, and so forth, and the seats are given successively to the highest of the resulting values, usually referred to as “averages.” It is possible, however, to interpret the highest average formula in such a way that it becomes comparable to the largest re- mainder formula. The purpose of the d’Hondt formula may be said to be the improvement of the largest remainder formula by finding an electoral quota, lower than the Hare quota, which allows us to allocate all of the seats exactly according to the largest remainder rule but without having to take any remaining votes into account (Van den Bergh, 1955, 68-72). This lower d’Hondt quota is equal to the last of the ”averages” to which a seat is awarded. In the example of Table 10.1, the d’Hondt quota is 14 votes. When the parties’ votes are di- vided by this quota, party A is entitled to 2 seats, to 2, C to 1,and and E to none; all of the seats have been allocated and the remaining Proportionality of PR Formulas TABLE 10.1. Hypothetical Example of the Operation of the Largest Remain- der, and Pure Sainte-Lague Formulas a District with 100 Votes, 5 Seats, and 5 Parties Largest Initial Allocation Remaining Allocation of Final Seat Parties Votes of Seats Votes Remaining Seats Allocation A 36 1 16 1 2 B 30 1 10 0 1 C 14 0 14 1 1 D 12 0 12 1 1 E 8 0 8 0 0 Parties u12 u13 Total A 36 (1) 18 (3) 12 2 B 30 (2) 15 (4) 10 2 C 14 (5) 7 1 D 12 0 E 8 0 Pure Parties u13 u15 Total A 36 (1) 12(4 ) 7.2 2 B 30 (2) 10 1 C 14 (3) 4.67 1 D 12 (5) 4 1 E 8 0 electoral quota is 10015 = 20. numbers in parentheses indicate the sequential order of the allocation of seats. The reason for the disproportionality of now becomes clear. The remaining votes that it disregards are a relatively small portion of the votes of the larger parties but a very large portion of the small parties’ votes -and, of course, the entire vote total of a party that does not receive any seats. As a result, the seat shares of the larger parties will tend to be systematically higher than their vote shares, and the smaller parties will tend to receive seat shares that are system- atically below their vote shares. In contrast, the largest remainder method treats large and small parties equally: The initial allocation of at i tl ti al and all and la rtie et fo Proportionality of PR Formulas 179 largest remainders. However, both methods suffer from a more serious weakness: They may encourage party splits. In the example of largest remainders in Table 10.1, party B could win an additional seat, at the expense of party D, if it would present two separate lists, each of which would get 15votes. Pure Sainte-Lague would have the same effect. This tendency declines as PR formulas become less proportional, and it disappears entirely under the rule-certainly a very powerful argu- ment in favor of this not maximally proportional formula (cf. Balinski and Young, 1983)..
Recommended publications
  • Who Gains from Apparentments Under D'hondt?
    CIS Working Paper No 48, 2009 Published by the Center for Comparative and International Studies (ETH Zurich and University of Zurich) Who gains from apparentments under D’Hondt? Dr. Daniel Bochsler University of Zurich Universität Zürich Who gains from apparentments under D’Hondt? Daniel Bochsler post-doctoral research fellow Center for Comparative and International Studies Universität Zürich Seilergraben 53 CH-8001 Zürich Switzerland Centre for the Study of Imperfections in Democracies Central European University Nador utca 9 H-1051 Budapest Hungary [email protected] phone: +41 44 634 50 28 http://www.bochsler.eu Acknowledgements I am in dept to Sebastian Maier, Friedrich Pukelsheim, Peter Leutgäb, Hanspeter Kriesi, and Alex Fischer, who provided very insightful comments on earlier versions of this paper. Manuscript Who gains from apparentments under D’Hondt? Apparentments – or coalitions of several electoral lists – are a widely neglected aspect of the study of proportional electoral systems. This paper proposes a formal model that explains the benefits political parties derive from apparentments, based on their alliance strategies and relative size. In doing so, it reveals that apparentments are most beneficial for highly fractionalised political blocs. However, it also emerges that large parties stand to gain much more from apparentments than small parties do. Because of this, small parties are likely to join in apparentments with other small parties, excluding large parties where possible. These arguments are tested empirically, using a new dataset from the Swiss national parliamentary elections covering a period from 1995 to 2007. Keywords: Electoral systems; apparentments; mechanical effect; PR; D’Hondt. Apparentments, a neglected feature of electoral systems Seat allocation rules in proportional representation (PR) systems have been subject to widespread political debate, and one particularly under-analysed subject in this area is list apparentments.
    [Show full text]
  • A Canadian Model of Proportional Representation by Robert S. Ring A
    Proportional-first-past-the-post: A Canadian model of Proportional Representation by Robert S. Ring A thesis submitted to the School of Graduate Studies in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts Department of Political Science Memorial University St. John’s, Newfoundland and Labrador May 2014 ii Abstract For more than a decade a majority of Canadians have consistently supported the idea of proportional representation when asked, yet all attempts at electoral reform thus far have failed. Even though a majority of Canadians support proportional representation, a majority also report they are satisfied with the current electoral system (even indicating support for both in the same survey). The author seeks to reconcile these potentially conflicting desires by designing a uniquely Canadian electoral system that keeps the positive and familiar features of first-past-the- post while creating a proportional election result. The author touches on the theory of representative democracy and its relationship with proportional representation before delving into the mechanics of electoral systems. He surveys some of the major electoral system proposals and options for Canada before finally presenting his made-in-Canada solution that he believes stands a better chance at gaining approval from Canadians than past proposals. iii Acknowledgements First of foremost, I would like to express my sincerest gratitude to my brilliant supervisor, Dr. Amanda Bittner, whose continuous guidance, support, and advice over the past few years has been invaluable. I am especially grateful to you for encouraging me to pursue my Master’s and write about my electoral system idea.
    [Show full text]
  • Another Consideration in Minority Vote Dilution Remedies: Rent
    Another C onsideration in Minority Vote Dilution Remedies : Rent -Seeking ALAN LOCKARD St. Lawrence University In some areas of the United States, racial and ethnic minorities have been effectively excluded from the democratic process by a variety of means, including electoral laws. In some instances, the Courts have sought to remedy this problem by imposing alternative voting methods, such as cumulative voting. I examine several voting methods with regard to their sensitivity to rent-seeking. Methods which are less sensitive to rent-seeking are preferred because they involve less social waste, and are less likely to be co- opted by special interest groups. I find that proportional representation methods, rather than semi- proportional ones, such as cumulative voting, are relatively insensitive to rent-seeking efforts, and thus preferable. I also suggest that an even less sensitive method, the proportional lottery, may be appropriate for use within deliberative bodies, where proportional representation is inapplicable and minority vote dilution otherwise remains an intractable problem. 1. INTRODUCTION When President Clinton nominated Lani Guinier to serve in the Justice Department as Assistant Attorney General for Civil Rights, an opportunity was created for an extremely valuable public debate on the merits of alternative voting methods as solutions to vote dilution problems in the United States. After Prof. Guinier’s positions were grossly mischaracterized in the press,1 the President withdrew her nomination without permitting such a public debate to take place.2 These issues have been discussed in academic circles,3 however, 1 Bolick (1993) charges Guinier with advocating “a complex racial spoils system.” 2 Guinier (1998) recounts her experiences in this process.
    [Show full text]
  • Who Gains from Apparentments Under D'hondt?
    Manuscript Who gains from apparentments under D’Hondt? Daniel Bochsler, Centre for the Study of Imperfections in Democracies (DISC), Central European University, [email protected] - www.bochsler.eu 13 November 2009 Apparentments – or coalitions of several electoral lists – are a widely neglected aspect of the study of proportional electoral systems. This paper proposes a formal model that explains the benefits political parties derive from apparentments, based on their alliance strategies and relative size. In doing so, it reveals that apparentments are most beneficial for highly fractionalised political blocs. However, it also emerges that large parties stand to gain much more from apparentments than small parties do. Because of this, small parties are likely to join in apparentments with other small parties, excluding large parties where possible. These arguments are tested empirically, using a new dataset from the Swiss national parliamentary elections covering a period from 1995 to 2007. Keywords: Electoral systems; apparentments; mechanical effect; PR; D’Hondt. Apparentments, a neglected feature of electoral systems* Seat allocation rules in proportional representation (PR) systems have been subject to widespread political debate, and one particularly under-analysed subject in this area is list apparentments. Theoretical work and studies based on simulation models has shown that the division allocation rule with rounding down (the most frequently applied PR allocation rule, referred to as the D’Hondt or Jefferson method) strongly favours large parties over small parties (see, among many others, Pennisi, 1998; Elklit, 2007; Schuster, Pukelsheim, Drton, and Draper, 2003). Other common seat allocation rules, such as Hamilton’s or Hare/Niemayer’s largest remainder method, or the Sainte- Laguë/Webster divisor method with standard rounding are unbiased with regards to party size.
    [Show full text]
  • Comparative Table on Proportional Electoral Systems
    Strasbourg, 28 November 2014 CDL(2014)058 Study No. 764/2014 Or. bil. EUROPEAN COMMISSION FOR DEMOCRACY THROUGH LAW (VENICE COMMISSION) COMPARATIVE TABLE ON PROPORTIONAL ELECTORAL SYSTEMS: THE ALLOCATION OF SEATS INSIDE THE LISTS (OPEN/CLOSED LISTS) This document will not be distributed at the meeting. Please bring this copy. www.venice.coe.int CDL(2014)058 - 2 - Proportional systems, Proportional systems: Electoral systems, Proportional systems, methods of allocation of Country Legal basis System of representation closed or open party main relevant provision(s) methods of allocation of seats seats list system? inside the lists Constitution Proportional system: Constitution Largest remainder Closed Party List No preference Article 64 All the 140 members of the Article 64 (amended by Law no. d'Hondt, then Sainte-Laguë system Not indicated in the law but Parliament are elected through 9904, dated 21.04.2008) formulas No preference implicitly clear that there is Electoral Code a proportional representation 1. The Assembly consists of 140 no preference. (approved by Law system within constituencies deputies, elected by a proportional See the separate document for no. 10 019, dated 29 corresponding to the 12 system with multi-member electoral Articles 162-163. December 2008, administrative regions. zones. and amended by The threshold to win 2. A multi-member electoral zone According to the stipulations in Law no. 74/2012, parliamentary representation is coincides with the administrative Articles 162 and 163 of the Electoral dated 19 July 2012) 3 percent for political parties division of one of the levels of Code, the number of seats is Articles 162 & 163 and 5 per cent for pre-election administrative-territorial calculated for each of the coalitions coalitions.
    [Show full text]
  • Submission of Labour Party to the Committee on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (CESCR) on the Implementation of the Interna
    Submission of Labour Party to the Committee on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (CESCR) on the implementation of the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (ICESCR) in the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, China Introduction 1. Labour Party was established in December 2011. We are committed to promoting democracy, justice, sustainability and solidarity in Hong Kong. We campaign for the provision of adequate means and conditions to all, for making the most of their lives and participating in political, economic, social and cultural affairs. Labour Party has secured 4 seats in the Legislative Council elections in 2012. Article 2: Factors impeding the realization of economic, social and cultural rights (Fiscal policy as a major hindrance) 2. The Government’s conservative fiscal policy has over the years been a major hindrance to Hong Kong people’s full enjoyment of economic, social and cultural rights as enshrined in the Covenant. We submit that the Government’s deliberate policy choice of limiting public expenditure to the provision of essential social services is not in line with Article 2(1) of the Covenant, under which the Government is obliged to make use of its maximum available resources to achieve progressively the full realization of the rights recognized in the Covenant. 3. Hong Kong’s social spending is among the lowest in advanced economies. In financial year 2012 – 13, the total recurrent and capital expenditure on education, welfare, health and housing was just over HKD 200 billion, less than 10% of GDP. The Government’s refusal to spend where spending is due has resulted in chronic shortage in the provision of essential social services.
    [Show full text]
  • ELECTOOL. Some Tools for the Analysis of Electoral Systems∗
    ELECTOOL. Some Tools for the Analysis of Electoral Systems∗ Antonio M. Jaime-Castillo Department of Sociology, University of Granada E-mail: [email protected] February, 2010 This document describes electoral formulas and indicators used by the electool package for Stata1. The package contains two different programs: v2seats and electind. This document is intended to be used only in conjunction with the electool package and only describes the procedures used by v2seats and electind. For assistance with syntax, use man v2seats and man electind, after installation, as usual. 1 Electoral formulas (v2seats) This section describes electoral formulas used by the v2seats command. It only provides information about how each formula works. For assistance with syntax, use man v2seats, after installation, as usual. Most of the electoral formulas used by v2seats are well known and have been documented in the literature. Please, refer to academic as well as official sources for further explanation and details about the foundations and mathematical properties for each formula. See for instance, Benoit (2000), Blais and Massicotte (1997), Gallagher (1992), and Golder (2005) for a concise review. Electoral formulas are designed to allocate seats to parties. Many formulas have been proposed in the literature and there are many different implementations of each formula in real electoral systems. This document only describes formulas used by v2seats, which covers most of the formulas in use around the world. There are two main different types of electoral formulas: majority and proportional methods. Ma- jority methods are intended to select one single winner, while proportional methods allocate seats proportionally to the number of votes for each party.
    [Show full text]
  • Democratic Electoral Systems Around the World, 1946-2011
    Democratic Electoral Systems Around the World, 1946-2011 Nils-Christian Bormann ETH Zurich Matt Golder Pennsylvania State University Contents 1 Introduction 1 1.1 Data ............................................... 1 1.2 Case Selection .......................................... 2 1.3 Missing Data .......................................... 2 1.4 Variables ............................................ 2 1.4.1 ID Variables ...................................... 2 1.4.2 Legislative Elections .................................. 5 1.4.3 Presidential Elections .................................. 10 1.5 Glossary ............................................. 10 References 34 ii Chapter 1 Introduction This document provides information about the data described in the following article: • Bormann, Nils-Christian & Matt Golder. 2013. “Democratic Electoral Systems Around the World, 1946-2011,” Electoral Studies . To obtain the data, please click here. In total, the data contain information on 1,197 legislative and 433 presidential elections that occurred in democracies from 1946 (or independence) through 2011. 1.1 Data There are three data sets: 1. es_data-v2_0.dta 2. es_data-v2_0.csv 3. es_data-v2_0_comments.xls The first two data sets differ only in terms of their format: Stata or comma separated. The third data set, es_data-v2_0_comments.xls, adds (very brief) comments about specific variables for particular cases and indicates the sources that were consulted. The comments in this third data set will be expanded and incorporated into a much more detailed codebook as time permits. 1 1.2 Case Selection The data focus on national-level (lower house) legislative and presidential elections in democratic regimes. A regime is classified as a democracy at the time of an election if (i) the chief executive is elected, (ii) the legislature is elected, (iii) there is more than one party competing in elections, and (iv) an alternation under identical electoral rules has taken place.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Representation of the Poor
    The Political Representation of the Poor by Karen Long Jusko A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy (Political Science) in The University of Michigan 2008 Doctoral Committee: Professor John E. Jackson, Co-Chair Professor Christopher H. Achen, Princeton University, Co-Chair Professor Robert J. Franzese Jr. Professor James M. Lepkowksi Karen Long Jusko c All rights reserved. 2008 For my Mum and Dad, and for Ryan, with love and gratitude. ii Acknowledgements The offices and charges of the society should be apportioned for the good of the society itself, and in such mode that difference in degree or standing should not interfere with unanimity and good-will. It is most important that office bearers be appointed with due prudence and discretion, and each one’s charge carefully mapped out, in order that no members may suffer harm. The common funds must be administered with strict honesty, in such a way that a member may receive assistance in proportion to his necessities. Rerum Novarum (1891) Christopher Achen encouraged me to pursue questions about the common good with rigor and clarity, and it is because of Chris’s early enthusiasm for my research question – how do electoral rules affect the poor? – that I have found my research agenda. I am most grateful for his guidance and support, and hope that my research reflects the best of his mentorship. I would also like to acknowledge a few others who have contributed to this project in important ways. I hope they recognize their contributions in the pages that follow, and that I’ve competently reflected their insights and addressed their questions.
    [Show full text]
  • Elections and Electoral Systems Democracies Are Sometimes Classified in Terms of Their Electoral System
    Elections and Electoral Systems Democracies are sometimes classified in terms of their electoral system. An electoral system is a set of laws that regulate electoral competition between candidates or parties or both. Elections are increasingly used to fill legislative and executive offices around the world. 185 of the world's 193 independent states now use direct elections to elect people to their lower house of parliament. Electoral integrity refers to the extent to which the conduct of elections meets international standards and global norms concerning `good' elections. These norms and standards are usually set out in treaties, conventions, and guidelines issued by international and regional organizations. Violations of electoral integrity are referred to as electoral malpractice. MAP 13.1 Electoral Integrity across the World in 2016 Source: Data come from the Perceptions of Electoral Integrity expert survey (PEI 4.5) and are based on national-level elections that have taken place between July 1, 2012, and June 30, 2016 (“Perceptions” 2016). Darker colors indicate higher levels of electoral integrity. 13: Elections and Electoral Systems 527 FIGURE 13.2 Electoral Integrity in Four Countries Source: Data for the star-plots come from the Perceptions of Electoral Integrity expert survey (PEI 4.5; “Perceptions” 2016). The gray star-plots indicate how the four countries score on each of the eleven categories of electoral integ- rity. They also show each country’s overall PEI score. The black dashed line indicates the average global score across the same categories of electoral integrity. each of the eleven categories of electoral integrity as well as their overall PEI score.
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral System Design: the New International IDEA Handbook
    Electoral System Design: The New International IDEA Handbook Electoral System Design: The New International IDEA Handbook Andrew Reynolds Ben Reilly and Andrew Ellis With José Antonio Cheibub Karen Cox Dong Lisheng Jørgen Elklit Michael Gallagher Allen Hicken Carlos Huneeus Eugene Huskey Stina Larserud Vijay Patidar Nigel S. Roberts Richard Vengroff Jeffrey A. Weldon Handbook Series The International IDEA Handbook Series seeks to present comparative analysis, information and insights on a range of democratic institutions and processes. Handbooks are aimed primarily at policy makers, politicians, civil society actors and practitioners in the field. They are also of interest to academia, the democracy assistance community and other bodies. International IDEA publications are independent of specific national or political interests. Views expressed in this publication do not necessarily represent the views of International IDEA, its Board or its Council members. The map presented in this publication does not imply on the part of the Institute any judgement on the legal status of any territory or the endorsement of such boundaries, nor does the placement or size of any country or territory reflect the political view of the Institute. The map is created for this publication in order to add clarity to the text. © International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance 2005 Reprinted 2008 Applications for permission to reproduce or translate all or any part of this publication should be made to: Information Unit International IDEA SE -103 34 Stockholm Sweden International IDEA encourages dissemination of its work and will promptly respond to requests for permission to reproduce or translate its publications. Graphic design by: Magnus Alkmar Cover photos: © Pressens Bild Printed by: Trydells Tryckeri AB, Sweden ISBN: 91-85391-18-2 Foreword The Universal Declaration of Human Rights states that ‘everyone has the right to take part in the government of his country, directly or through freely chosen representatives’.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Questions About the Electoral System for the 2004 Indonesian General Elections Answered
    SOME QUESTIONS ABOUT THE ELECTORAL SYSTEM FOR THE 2004 INDONESIAN GENERAL ELECTIONS ANSWERED Jakarta July 2003 Revised January 2004 IFES Indonesia INDEX Why Change the Electoral System Used in the 1999 Elections? 2 What Is the Date for the 2004 General Elections? 2 What Is the System of Representation to Be Used in the 2004 2 General Elections? What Are the Electoral Districts and How Are They Determined? 3 Which Political Parties May Participate in the 2004 Elections? 5 Who May Be a Candidate and How Are Candidates Selected? 5 What Will the Ballot Paper Look Like? 7 How Will Voters Vote? 7 How and Where Are Votes Counted? 8 Which Votes Are Valid? 8 How Are the Winning Candidates Determined? 9 How Are Seats Allocated to Political Parties in Each DPR/DPRD 9 Electoral District? When Will the Count of DPR and DPRD Votes Be Completed? 10 How Are Candidates Assigned to Seats Won by Political Parties in Each 12 DPR/DPRD Electoral District? When Will the Election Results Be Known? 13 How Is a Candidate Determined to Have Won a Seat in the DPD? 14 For further information, please contact: Alan Wall Project Manager, IFES Indonesia Ph: 570 4884 Email: [email protected] Adhy Aman Legal Policy Coordinator, IFES Indonesia Ph: 570 4884 Email: [email protected] 1 IFES Indonesia WHY CHANGE THE ELECTORAL SYSTEM USED IN THE 1999 ELECTIONS? There was a perception that representation was not being performed well, specifically that the people had little control over or links with their representatives. The electoral system was blamed by many for this, though
    [Show full text]