<<

Northwestern University School of Law Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons

Faculty Working Papers

2009 Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements Jonathan Koehler Northwestern University School of Law, [email protected]

Molly Mercer Arizona State University, School of Business

Repository Citation Koehler, Jonathan and Mercer, Molly, "Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements" (2009). Faculty Working Papers. Paper 198. http://scholarlycommons.law.northwestern.edu/facultyworkingpapers/198

This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Working Papers by an authorized administrator of Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. MANAGEMENT SCIENCE informs ® Vol. 55, No. 7, July 2009, pp. 1107–1121 doi 10.1287/mnsc.1090.1013 issn eissn 0025-1909 1526-5501 09 5507 1107 © 2009 INFORMS

Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements

Jonathan J. Koehler Department of Finance, W. P. Carey School of Business, and Sandra Day O’Connor College of Law, Arizona State University, Tempe, Arizona 85287, [email protected] Molly Mercer Department of Accounting, W. P. Carey School of Business, Arizona State University, Tempe, Arizona 85287, [email protected]

utual fund companies selectively advertise their better-performing funds. However, investors respond Mto advertised performance data as if those data were unselected (i.e., representative of the population). We identify the failure to discount selected or potentially selected data as selection neglect. We examine these phenomena in an archival study (Study 1) and two controlled (Studies 2 and 3). Study 1 identifies selection in mutual fund advertising by showing that the median performance rank for advertised funds is between the 79th and 100th percentile. Study 2 finds that both novice investors and financial professionals fall victim to selection neglect in a financial advertising task unless the advertisement makes the selective nature of available performance data transparent. Study 3 shows that selection neglect associated with a large well-known company can be debiased with a simple extrinsic space cue, although individual differences in statistical reasoning also matter. We argue that selection neglect results from a general tendency to ignore underlying sample spaces rather than a fundamental misunderstanding about the data selection process or the value of selected data. Key words: selection bias; financial decision making; mutual fund ads; statistical heuristics; sample space History: Received June 25, 2007; accepted January 25, 2009, by George Wu, decision analysis. Published online in Articles in Advance May 7, 2009.

1. Introduction opportunities to achieve success. But how many of Louis Rukeyser, the long-time host of Wall $treet Week, those who watched the New Year’s edition of Wall used to invite three of his two dozen regular pan- $treet Week, pen in hand, thought about the size of elists to appear on the annual New Year’s show to the set of regular panelists from which the all-stars to this article and distributed this copy as aoffer courtesy to the author(s). stock recommendations for the coming year. were selected? Would it have made a difference if Although Rukeyser’s panelists offered stock recom- they had? In a similar vein, when people learn that a mendations every other week as well, the New Year’s touted mutual fund has a history of great success, do show commanded special attention. On this night, they consider that a company that offers many mutual copyright the invited panelists were the show’s best stock pick- funds is bound to have one or more funds that per- ers based on their performance during the prior year. formed exceptionally well by sheer chance? Millions tuned in for tips from these proven seers. Mutual fund companies often advertise a subset of holds But how much confidence should investors have in the total funds they operate. A selection bias is present the recommended stocks? After all, the chance that at if the advertised funds are chosen in ways that makes least a few forecasters would have compiled terrific them atypical of the population of funds offered by performance records—even if none had any real fore- the company. Selection bias research in other fields INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. casting ability—increases as the number of forecast- often focuses on how data become unrepresentative of ers increases. Consider the following analogy. If Katie populations and the problems that result when those flips a fair coin 100 times hoping to get lots of heads, data are used in statistical analyses (e.g., Heckman there is a 3% chance that she will obtain 60 or more 1979). In contrast, we are primarily concerned with heads (“great success”). However, if she flips 50 coins how people respond to data that are or may have been 100 times each, there is a 76% chance that at least one strategically selected. We predict that people respond of those coins will yield a great success. The point is to such data as if they were unselected (i.e., represen- that even in environments where ability is minimal tative). We call this response tendency selection neglect. or nonexistent, the laws of chance alone are likely to We also predict that selection neglect can often be yield occasional great successes when there are many overcome when people have sample space knowledge

1107 Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements 1108 Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS

and access to that knowledge. The access requirement Although such effects undoubtedly occur on occa- is crucial. We argue that decision makers are likely to sion, this explanation is incomplete, because research suffer from selection neglect unless their sample space shows that people give great inferential weight to knowledge is cued or otherwise made available. sample data even when they are expressly told that We focus on selection neglect in the context of in- the data are atypical (Hamill et al. 1980). vestors’ responses to mutual fund advertisements. A second reason decision makers might rely on We begin with an archival study (Study 1) that biased data is that they recognize the potential for asks whether companies that offer multiple mutual strategic selection in available data, but do not under- funds provide biased snapshots of their success by stand how selection should affect their use of those selectively advertising better-performing funds. After data. Undoubtedly, some people fail to discount obvi- establishing that they do, we provide two selection ously selected data for this reason. However, Nisbett neglect experiments (Studies 2 and 3). Study 2 exam- et al. (1983) persuasively argue that people often pos- ines the basic selection neglect phenomenon. Consis- sess sophisticated intuitive strategies, or “statistical tent with work by Nisbett et al. (1983) on statistical heuristics” for reasoning effectively in various every- heuristics, this study shows that investors tend to day tasks including, presumably, the evaluation of appreciate selection when the sample space and/or selected data. selection process is transparent. However, when the A third reason for selection neglect is that peo- process is not made obvious, investors fall ple know that biased data should be discounted, but prey to selection neglect and fail to discount selected they fail to access and use this knowledge. An impli- data. Study 2 also shows that financial profession- cation of this explanation is that people will assign als are as susceptible to selection neglect as ordinary less weight to selected data when the data selection investors. Study 3 addresses other selection neglect process is made transparent or cued. The available issues in the context of an advertisement from a large, research is most consistent with this explanation. Peo- well-known mutual fund company. First, we show ple are prone to accept sample evidence at face value that selection neglect can be overcome by subtly cue- (Fiedler 2008), and such behavior may be automatic. ing sample space information that investors already As Daniel Gilbert and colleagues demonstrated, the know, but apparently do not access. Second, we test mental representation of a proposition has a truth a process by which selection neglect may influence value and the default presumption is that the propo- willingness to invest. Third, we consider the role sition is true (Gilbert et al. 1990). Extending this that individual differences in statistical reasoning may idea to quantitative data, the default assumption may play in selection neglect. be that available data are valid for inferential pur- poses. Of course, people sometimes reject proposi- tions and selected data. However, doing so requires 2. Reasoning with Biased Data: extra steps that the intuitive decision maker may not Selection Neglect even consider. to this article and distributed this copy as aBehavioral courtesy to the author(s). research indicates that people often use This framework is consistent with a dual process sample data inappropriately to draw inferences about theory of cognition in which an automatic, nondelib- the populations from which the samples were derived erative system (System I) quickly generates impres- (Tversky and Kahneman 1971). One reason that peo- sions of available stimuli, whereas a slower, more

copyright ple make poor inferences from sample data is that the reflective system (System II) monitors the quality of environment commonly offers up unrepresentative those impressions through a more deliberative judg- samples for their consideration (Fiedler 2000, 2008; ment process (Kahneman and Frederick 2002). How- holds Denrell 2003, 2007). For example, when informants ever, System II may not intervene to override the (such as advertisers) control the flow of information automatic acceptance of sample data that System I and have a strategic interest in how others respond yields in a data selection task. Effective System II to that information, the likely result is a selection deliberation in such tasks requires decision makers INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. and presentation of unrepresentative data. Given that to construct and consider relevant sample spaces. sample data presented in such situations are likely to Performing this task prompts decision makers to con- be biased, why would people respond to such data sider the role that sample bias may play and to as if they were unselected (i.e., suffer from “selection discount the available data accordingly, but sample neglect”)? space construction is notoriously unnatural because One reason is that people may not realize that it requires attention to nonoccurrences of the event the available data were strategically selected. This of interest (Einhorn and Hogarth 1978). As Hearst may occur when people mistakenly believe that infor- (1991) explains, “[H]uman beings and other animals mants are disinterested or have disclosed all relevant have trouble using the mere absence of something information about the sample and sampling process. as a basis for efficient and appropriate processing of Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS 1109

information. They notice and recall additions much downplaying or ignoring other features. Mutual fund more readily than deletions” (pp. 432, 434). companies might advertise historical return data from In short, the third explanation for selection neglect a favorable time period or compare their performance suggests that decision makers’ failure to discount against low-performing benchmarks or index funds. selected data is due to lack of knowledge access rather Recent Security and Exchange Commission (SEC) than lack of knowledge. Although many people real- guidelines have curtailed time-period related selec- ize, in the abstract, that selected sample data should tion , but other forms remain. Product-level selec- be discounted, these same people may not discount tion bias occurs when companies advertise their most such data at all because they do not automatically successful funds. When companies embrace this strat- think about sample space and sampling matters that egy, the value of performance information in their ads draw the biased nature of the data into focus. We con- is likely minimal.1 After all, if a company offers many tend that the attention of decision makers who are funds, some are likely to outperform the benchmark invited to make inferences from selected sample data by chance alone. Our studies focus on the existence of must somehow be directed to sample space and sam- (Study 1) and reactions to (Studies 2 and 3) product- pling process considerations before people will access level selection bias in mutual fund advertisements. their statistical heuristics and discount selected data. Our selection neglect theory has implications for 3.1. Method how investors who read mutual fund ads use per- Study 1 examines whether companies selectively ad- formance data in those ads to form beliefs about vertise their better-performing stock mutual funds. the advertising company and make investment deci- We investigate this issue by comparing the recent per- sions. We predict that investors who see ads that tout formance history of advertised stock mutual funds the recent strong performance of a few funds will with the performance history of nonadvertised stock not spontaneously consider the large sample space of funds within the same management company. We unadvertised funds. Consequently, these investors are reviewed mutual fund ads that appeared between likely to be impressed by the ads because they will fail 1998 and 2001 in BusinessWeek and Fortune.We to consider that companies that operate many funds restricted our analyses to ads from companies that are bound to have some strong performers by chance operated multiple stock funds and that included per- alone. However, if the fund advertisement includes formance data. We chose this time frame because it cues related to sample space (i.e., the total number of included favorable and unfavorable market periods funds operated by the company), we expect investors and provided for a large data set. We examined these to discount the potentially selected performance data. publications because they have the largest circulations among business periodicals over the past 10 years. 3. Study 1: Selective Advertising of Our data set included 341 advertised funds from 27 Mutual Funds different companies. The ad contained perfor- Mutual fund companies spend large amounts of mon- mance data for 1.7 different funds. to this article and distributed this copy as aey courtesy to advertising the author(s). their funds (Jordan and Kass 2002), and We ranked each advertised fund’s performance rel- these expenditures are paying off. Funds that adver- ative to (a) the performance of other stock funds oper- tise attract 20% more new money than comparable ated by the same company (company stock funds), funds that do not advertise (Jain and Wu 2000), but and (b) the performance of other stock funds operated by the same company with the same objective, e.g., copyright if the advertisements suffer from selection bias, such enthusiasm may be unwarranted. growth and income (same-objective company stock Selection biases in mutual fund advertising may funds). We used the Center for Research in Security holds occur at various levels, some of which are hard to Prices (CRSP) mutual fund database to obtain rele- detect. They may occur at a company level (which vant performance data. fund companies are advertising), a content level (how SEC guidelines require that mutual fund ads that is the fund advertised), or a product level (which include performance data report 1-year, 5-year, and INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. funds are advertised). Company-level selection bias 10-year historical performance (SEC Rule 482; NASD occurs when management companies that choose to Rule 2210-3). Funds less than 10 years old must report advertise are unrepresentative of the general pop- ulation of management companies. This may occur 1 There is debate about the predictive value of mutual fund per- because small companies or companies that perform formance data even when those data are not strategically selected. poorly lack the resources for vigorous advertising Some argue that past performance provides no information about campaigns, or because strong performers are more future success (Malkiel 1995, Carhart 1997). Others find that there is short-term persistence in high-performing funds (Hendricks et al. motivated to call attention to their success. Content- 1993, Brown and Goetzmann 1995). We are not concerned with this level selection bias occurs when companies empha- debate here. We focus on investors’ use of data rather than the size the most positive features of a product while predictive value of those data. Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements 1110 Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS

performance for the life of the fund, and ads may not this practice is widespread, it is important to know report performance for periods less than one year. All whether potential investors appreciate the ads’ selec- 341 advertised funds in our data set disclosed 1-year tive nature. In Study 2, we examine the responses performance data, 237 disclosed 5-year performance, of novice and expert investors to selection bias in and 132 disclosed 10-year performance. Our analy- mutual fund ads. We compare their responses to the ses required that the advertising company operate at predictions of three simple selection bias sensitivity least two stock funds for the company stock funds theories: complete sensitivity, complete insensitivity, ranking and at least two same-objective stock funds and partial sensitivity. The complete sensitivity theory for the same-objective company stock funds ranking. holds that investors are adept at recognizing selective The ns for company stock funds rankings were 339 data when they appear, and that they attach relatively (1-year), 228 (5-year), and 121 (10-year); the ns for our less weight to selected data than to unselected data. same-objective company stock funds rankings were The complete insensitivity theory holds that investors 306 (1-year), 193 (5-year), and 86 (10-year). The mean treat samples as representative of populations regard- number of nonadvertised funds for the 1-year, 5-year, less of the process by which those samples were and 10-year time periods was 74, 34, and 21, respec- selected. Accordingly, investors make no distinction tively, for all company-operated stock funds and 12, 5, between selected and unselected data when draw- and 4 for same-objective company stocks funds. ing inferences. The partial sensitivity theory invokes a distinction between transparent and hidden selec- 3.2. Results and Discussion tion processes. Investors who are partially sensitive to We find that companies offer biased snapshots of selection bias appreciate the shortcomings of selected their success by selectively advertising their higher- data, but only when the selective nature of the data is performing funds. The median 1-year, 5-year, and transparent or otherwise cued. When the selective pro- 10-year ranks for advertised stock funds were at the cess remains hidden, partially sensitive investors give 79th, 88th, and 88th percentiles, respectively, for all little thought to selection, and value the resultant data company-operated stock funds, and at the 80th, 100th, as much as they value data that they know to be uns- and 100th percentiles for company-operated stock elected. Assuming that people are more apt to invoke funds that share a common investment objective. The statistical heuristics when the statistical aspects of the median rank of advertised funds relative to nonad- problem are clarified or cued (Nisbett et al. 1983), we vertised same-objective funds is 100% in the 5- and favor the partial sensitivity theory. 10-year periods because the top performer was adver- tised 61% and 62% of the time, respectively. The results 4.1. Method for 5- and 10-year performance are interesting because 4.1.1. Participants. We recruited 128 novice and companies tend to close poorly performing funds. ∼ 129 expert investors to read and respond to a mutual Indeed, 6.5% of funds close each year (Clements fund advertisement. We recruited novice investors 2002). The significance of this for from business classes at a top-10 ranked business our purposes is that it reduces the relative position- school in exchange for class credit. About half (46%) to this article and distributed this copy as aing courtesy to the of author(s). surviving funds. That is, if the closed funds of the novice investors had investing experience, and were still open, the advertised funds would have even a large majority (90%) planned to invest in stocks in higher relative ranks. The higher longer-term perfor- the near future. We recruited expert investors from mance percentiles are also interesting because they 30 U.S.-based financial companies with the assistance copyright reflect an advertising strategy consistent with research of 20 professional contacts who worked at major that shows investors place great weight on long-term financial institutions. Expert investors qualified for performance records (Wilcox 2003). the study if they made investment decisions for others holds Our findings are consistent with Jain and Wu in a professional capacity and had at least three years (2000), who found that advertised mutual funds out- of investing experience. Our experts were an elite performed various benchmarks immediately prior to group of professionals. They included chief financial the ad’s appearance. However, Jain and Wu’s results officers, portfolio managers, financial consulting part- INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. could be driven by company-level selection bias (i.e., ners, fund managers, corporate valuation managers, companies that had good years chose to advertise). directors, financial consultants, investment bankers, Our within-company analysis is more supportive of a traders, investment sales representatives, and ana- product-level selection bias in which companies adver- lysts. The mean expert investor had 10 years of per- tise funds that have performed particularly well dur- sonal investing experience, 6 years of professional ing the past 5- and 10-year periods. investing experience, and spends five hours per week reading financial publications and watching financial 4. Study 2: Response to Selection Bias programs on television. Our experts volunteered their Study 1 showed that investment companies selectively time to complete the task and received a chocolate gift advertise their better-performing stock funds. Because in return. Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS 1111

4.1.2. Materials and Procedure. We provided each probably most representative of actual mutual fund participant, at random, with one of four versions (one advertisements. control group, three experimental groups) of an adver- After reviewing the ad, investors answered two tisement for a fictitious mid-sized investment com- questions about the quality of Allen Funds’ manage- pany called the “Allen Funds.” We told participants ment company using 1–7 Likert-type response scales. that the ad, which was modeled closely after an actual Specifically, we asked investors whether they thought ad, appeared in a popular business publication. All Allen Funds was (a) an extremely successful invest- four versions provided identical information about ment company, and (b) an investment company that Allen Funds’ research strategy, fees and expenses, deserves investors’ trust, where higher ratings indi- advisor, and risk profile. This information indicated cated more positive assessments. We asked these that Allen Funds charged a 1% management fee for questions to determine whether and when the past finding and investing in growth-oriented companies success of individual funds affected judgments about that can deliver high returns over the long term. This the provider company. Next, we informed investors was the only information about Allen Funds provided that Allen Funds plans to introduce a new growth to participants in the control group n = 60. fund that would “have the same type of quality For participants in the three experimental groups management team that you have come to expect (ns = 67–71), the ad included statements related to from our funds.” We asked investors (a) how will- past performance successes and an “Average Annual ing they would be to invest a portion of a $10,000 Total Returns” chart that documented these successes. gift in this new fund (1–7 Likert-type scale), and The charts provided historical returns for the (a) Allen (b) what percentage of the $10,000 they would be MidCap Growth Fund, (b) Allen Growth Fund, and willing to invest in this fund. We asked investors (c) S&P 500 Index. The past performance data showed about their willingness to invest in a new fund that the two featured funds outperformed the S&P rather than in the funds named in the ad because 500 index by several percentage points in both the people have wide-ranging beliefs about the depen- short term and long term. dency of fund performance across time periods. Such The experimental conditions differed from one beliefs add undesirable “noise” to our study. We also another in terms of a single statement in the ad per- asked investors to explain their willingness to invest. taining to the number of funds operated by Allen Finally, we included a manipulation check question Funds. The statement in one condition indicated that that asked investors to indicate the total number of the funds named in the chart were “the only 2 funds funds operated by Allen Funds and to complete sev- operated by Allen Funds.” We refer to this as the no- eral demographic questions that focused on investors’ selection (or “2 of 2”) condition because the advertised financial experience. funds were not selected from a larger set of funds (i.e., two advertised funds out of two funds oper- 4.2. Predictions ated by the company in total). The statement in a We predicted that investors would be partially sensitive second condition indicated that the funds were “2 of to selection bias (i.e., sensitive to bias in performance to this article and distributed this copy as a30 courtesy to funds the author(s). operated by Allen Funds,” and that perfor- data when the selective process was made transpar- mance results for the other 28 funds could be obtained ent but not otherwise). Operationally, we anticipated by contacting the company. We refer to this as the that investors in the no-selection (2 of 2) and hidden transparent selection (or “2 of 30”) condition because selection (2 of ?) conditions would judge Allen Funds copyright participants were explicitly told that the two adver- more favorably and report a greater willingness to tised funds were selected from a larger set of funds. invest than would investors in the transparent selec- The statement in a third condition did not indicate tion (2 of 30) condition. We did not expect to observe holds how many funds Allen Funds operated. Instead, it differences between the 2 of 2 and 2 of ? groups noted that “performance results for all funds may be because investors in the latter group are unlikely to obtained by contacting Allen Funds.” We refer to this discount the impressive advertised performance data as the hidden selection (or “2 of ?”) condition because without a sample space prompt. We tested the partial INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. investors were not told the total number of funds sensitivity theory with planned comparisons between that Allen Funds operated.2 This third condition is (a) the 2 of ? and 2 of 2 conditions versus the 2 of 30 condition, and (b) the 2 of ? versus the 2 of 2 condition. 2 A more technically accurate label for the hidden selection con- Regarding the role that investment expertise plays dition is the unknown selection condition because it is possible in selection neglect, prior research shows that finan- that the complete sample space of funds is identical to the number cial experts and novices often share cognitive short- of funds advertised (in which case there would be no selection). comings (Shapira and Venezia 2001, Wilcox 2003). However, Study 1 indicated that 99.4% of mutual fund companies operate more funds than they advertise, and the mean (median) One study found that financial professionals were less number of nonadvertised funds is 74 (41). We therefore refer to the likely than novices to believe that financial advertis- unknown sample space condition as hidden selection. ers would provide biased information (Diacon 2004). Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements 1112 Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS

Based on this evidence, we predict that the partial 4.3.3. Willingness to Invest. We also asked in- sensitivity pattern will hold for expert and novice vestors to assess their willingness to invest (WTI)ina investors alike. However, Barber et al. (2005) found new fund offered by the same management company that experienced investors assigned less weight to and the percent they were willing to invest (Percent). past performance data for mutual funds than novice We conducted separate ANOVAs for WTI and Percent investors. Accordingly, we also predict a main effect using Experience and Selection as independent vari- for expertise such that our experts are generally less ables. Both ANOVAs showed main effects for Expe- willing to invest than the novices. = = rience (WTI: F1 187 5603, p<001; Percent: F1 185 3737, p<001) and Selection (WTI: F = 551, 4.3. Results 2 187 p<001; Percent: F = 336, p<005). The Experience The results support the partial sensitivity theory of 2 185 main effect indicates that experts were less willing to selection bias for novice and expert investors on all invest in the company and invested a smaller percent key dependent measures. We first discuss the manip- = = than novices (WTI: MExperts 33, MNovices 45; Per- ulation check and then analyze the effects of Expe- = = rience and Selection on perceived company success, cent: MExperts 183, MNovices 373). This result follows perceived company trustworthiness, willingness to from the finding that novices perceived the fund com- invest, and percentage willing to invest. We also exam- pany as more successful and trustworthy than experts, ine the control group responses. as well as research that shows experts rely less on past performance data than novices (Barber et al. 2005). The 4.3.1. Manipulation Check. We asked investors pattern of behind the Selection main effects for in the 2 of 2 and 2 of 30 conditions how many funds the investment measures supports the partial sensi- Allen Funds operated prior to introducing the new tivity theory (see Figure 1). Specifically, investors in growth fund. All investors in the 2 of 2 condition cor- the 2 of 30 condition were less willing to invest and rectly indicated that Allen Funds operated two funds. invested a smaller percent than those in the 2 of 2 and Nine investors in the 2 of 30 condition indicated an = = 2 of ? conditions (WTI: F2 190 547, p<001, ES 05; incorrect number of funds and are excluded from the = = remaining analyses.3 Percent: F2 188 333, p<005, ES 04). Investors in the 2 of 2 condition and the 2 of ? condition did not 4.3.2. Beliefs About Fund Company: Success and Trustworthiness. We examined two facets of investors’ beliefs about the fund company: their per- Figure 1 Novice and Expert Investors’ Mean Willingness to Invest by Condition (Study 2) ceptions about the company’s success and trustwor- thiness. We conducted separate analysis of Willingness to invest 7 (ANOVAs) for success and trustworthiness with Expe- Novices 4 rience and Selection as independent variables. Both 6 Experts ANOVAs showed main effects for Experience (Suc- 4.7 = = 5 4.7 cess: F1 178 1703, p<001; Trustworthiness: F1 177 2724, p<001) and Selection (Success: F = 324, 3.9 to this article and distributed this copy as a courtesy to the author(s). 2 178 = 4 p<005; Trustworthiness: F2 177 591, p<001). There × were no significant Experience Selection interactions. 3 3.5 3.6 The Experience main effects indicates that experts 2.9 2 rated the company as less successful and less trust- 7 = completely willing) copyright worthy than novices (Success: M = 41, M = Experts Novices Rating (1 = completely unwilling, = = 1 49; Trustworthiness: MExperts 35, MNovices 45). The 2 of 2 2 of ? 2 of 30

holds pattern of means on the Selection main effects sup- Selection condition ports the partial sensitivity theory of selection bias. Percent willing to invest Follow-up contrasts show that investors in the 2 of 50 30 condition viewed the company as less successful 40.7 40.3 and trustworthy than those in the 2 of 2 and 2 of ? 40 INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. = conditions (Success: F2 181 552, p<001, Effect Size 29.3 = = = 30 (ES) 04; Trustworthiness: F2 180 319, p<005, ES 05). Investors in the 2 of 2 and 2 of ? conditions did = 20

not differ on these measures (Success: t 017, n.s.; Percentage 122 21.6 = 19.3 Trustworthiness: t121 108, n.s.). 10 14.1 3 The results are similar when data from these nine investors are not excluded. 0 4 We obtained similar results and identical inferences with a multi- 2 of 2 2 of ? 2 of 30 variate analysis. Selection condition Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS 1113

= differ on either of the investment measures (WTI: t131 pany and were less willing to invest in the company’s = 011, n.s.; Percent: t130 025, n.s.). latest fund. This may reflect a general skepticism that 4.3.4. Control Group. Investors in the control goes with working in the field. Nevertheless, experts group read an ad for Allen Funds but did not receive exhibited the same selection neglect tendencies that information about past performance or number of we observed in novice investors. Apparently, exper- funds operated. These investors responded similarly tise is an insufficient antidote to selection neglect. to those in the 2 of 30 condition on all four dependent A skeptic might argue that the pattern of data we measures (all ps > 010). Control condition investors report arose because investors in the hidden selec- also gave lower ratings to the company and were less tion condition mistakenly assumed that Allen Funds willing to invest than investors in the 2 of 2 and 2 of ? only operated two funds, but this is unlikely. First, conditions (all ts > 20, p<005 for all). The finding most investors in the hidden selection condition esti- that control condition responses closely parallel 2 of 30 mated that Allen Funds operated more than two = condition responses supports the claim that investors funds (M 15 funds). Second, investors in the hid- in the 2 of 30 condition gave little weight to the excel- den selection condition who did presume that Allen lent (but selected) performance data that they saw in Funds operated just two funds gave responses that the ad. were similar to others in this condition. For example, those who assumed that there were two funds were 4.3.5. Written Explanations. Marginally, more in- not more willing to invest (M = 41, M = vestors in the 2 of 30 condition than the 2 of ? con- 2 funds >2 funds 42, t = 024, n.s.), nor did they invest a greater per- dition spontaneously commented on the absence of 64 cent (M = 300, M = 326, t = 042, n.s.) performance information on other funds operated by 2 funds >2 funds 63 than other investors in this condition. This finding Allen Funds (34% versus 16%, Z = 197, p<010). supports the claim that investors in the hidden selec- This result suggests that investors are more likely to tion condition gave little, if any, thought to the total be concerned about selection bias when the selective number of funds when they were evaluating the qual- nature of the data is transparent. ity of the fund company and the attractiveness of the 4.4. Discussion investment opportunity. If they had, then those who Study 2 indicates that novice and expert investors assumed that there were many funds would have respond to selection bias in advertised mutual fund responded with less enthusiasm. performance data when the selection process is obvi- We contend that selection neglect is a genuine phe- ous, but treat nonobviously selected data as if it were nomenon that arises because people do not ordinarily not selected at all. We made the data selection pro- think about the sample space from which available cess obvious or not obvious by providing investors data were chosen. In the absence of appropriate cues, with fund performance data that either did or did not people accept data without handicap and draw infer- include information that directed readers’ attention ences accordingly. We do not necessarily contend that to the sample space of funds operated by the com- cued investors respond with the appropriate amount to this article and distributed this copy as apany. courtesy to the author(s). When the advertisements revealed that the com- of enthusiasm. Even investors in our 2 of 30 condi- pany operated many funds, investors appeared to pay tions may have been too enthusiastic about the fund more attention to the possibility that the advertised company after viewing the ad. Such a result would funds had been strategically selected. These investors be consistent with Cain et al. (2005), who found that copyright treated the favorable performance data as if they had people fail to discount advice from a biased source as little, if any, value. This is as it should be. Data that are much as they should, even when the source’s conflict- selected from a broad sample space by parties who of-interest bias is fully disclosed. Our point is that, holds are motivated to communicate a positive image are in the investment context, people who see ads that less diagnostic than unselected data. tout the performance of a few funds do not spon- Investors were less likely to recognize selection bias taneously consider the larger sample space of funds in the more realistic condition in which the ads did and selection process. However, when the ad includes INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. not include sample space information. Investors in cues related to sample space or sampling, people are this hidden selection condition were just as enthusias- more likely to invoke their statistical heuristics and tic about investing in the company’s newest fund as recognize that selected data should be discounted. investors who knew that the company operated exactly two funds, both of which were successful. Apparently, investors in the hidden selection condition did not 5. Study 3: Debiasing Selection spontaneously consider the possibility that the stellar Neglect data they saw may have been unrepresentative. The weight of neglected decision variables can often Overall, our financial experts were less impressed be increased by drawing attention to them (Kahneman than novices by the quality of the advertising com- and Frederick 2002). Study 2 suggested that sample Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements 1114 Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS

space is such a decision variable. The transparent included financial advertisements. To test whether the selection manipulation demonstrated one way to draw effects of our manipulations vary by investing expe- attention to sample space in a financial advertising rience, we conducted ANOVAs for each of our six task: Include this information in the ad. However, dependent variables, using investing experience as a mutual fund companies are not required to disclose covariate. We observe an insignificant experimental the number of funds they operate in their ads. Conse- condition by investing experience interaction term for quently, selection is hidden rather than transparent in each dependent variable (all p>010). This result sug- real-world ads. In Study 3, we test whether an extrin- gests that investing experience did not influence the sic sample space cue may debias selection neglect. We effects of the experimental manipulations. hypothesize that when investors consider the sample 5.1.2. Materials and Procedure. The stimuli and space, they are more likely to access their statistical procedure in Study 3 were similar to those used in heuristics, recognize the selection bias, and discount Study 2 with five key changes. First, we changed the the available data accordingly. name of the advertising company from Allen Funds We also explore a more global model that describes a process by which selection neglect might affect (a hypothetical company) to Fidelity Investments (an investment intentions. We propose that beliefs about actual company). We chose Fidelity because it is a the quality of the fund company and expectations large, well-known mutual fund that operates approx- about future performance mediate the relationship imately 30 growth-oriented mutual funds. Second, we between selection condition and willingness to invest. provided performance data from two Fidelity growth In support, we offer a path analysis. Because path funds (Midcap Growth Fund and Growth Fund) that analyses have limited ability to identify causal rela- actually did outperform the S&P 500 index over tions (Holland 1988), we also provide separate indi- the benchmark periods shown in the ad. Third, we vidual analyses of the influence of selection condition updated the time frame and benchmark data (from the on fund company beliefs, performance expectations, S&P 500 index) in the performance chart. Fourth, we and willingness to invest. assigned investors to one of two conditions—the hid- Study 3 also examines whether individual differ- den selection (2 of ?) and transparent selection (2 of 30) ences in statistical reasoning affect efforts to debias conditions. The no-selection (2 of 2) condition is inap- selection neglect. We have argued that selection plicable here because Fidelity operates many funds. neglect occurs when investors fail to access their Fifth, half the participants were asked to estimate the statistical heuristics. However, people vary in their total number of growth funds Fidelity operates before reliance on statistical principles (Stanovich and West answering the primary dependent measures (extrinsic 2000, 2008). Consequently, cues that draw attention cue). Participants in the uncued conditions were asked to a neglected sample space variable will not be uni- this question at the end of the task. The experimental versally effective. In this study, we test the idea that design is 2 (selection: hidden, transparent) × 2 (extrin- sample space cues are more likely to influence the sic cue: yes, no) between subjects. investment judgments of participants who embrace Following the experimental manipulations, partici- to this article and distributed this copy as astatistical courtesy to the author(s). reasoning than those who do not. pants answered questions related to their (a) beliefs Finally, Study 3 asks whether the partial sensitiv- about the quality of Fidelity (success and trustworthi- ity to selection observed in Study 2 will persist when ness), (b) expectations for future performance (Fidelity investors are familiar with the company and know overall and new fund), (c) willingness to invest copyright that it operates multiple funds. On the one hand, (how willing to invest and percent willing to invest), knowledge that a fund operates multiple funds is (d) beliefs about how Fidelity decides which funds information that investors need to overcome selection to advertise, (e) statistical reasoning, and (f) demo- holds neglect. On the other hand, this knowledge is unlikely graphics and familiarity with Fidelity. As before, we to be used unless attention is directed to it. There- used 7-point Likert-type scales for most questions. fore, we expect to observe selection neglect even for The performance expectation questions, advertising a large, well-known company. questions, and statistical reasoning questions were INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. new. The performance expectation questions assessed 5.1. Method participants’ beliefs about whether Fidelity’s mutual 5.1.1. Participants. A total of 180 business stu- funds overall, and their new growth fund in particu- dents from a large state university read and res- lar, were likely to outperform the S&P 500. The adver- ponded to a mutual fund advertisement. Of these tising questions assessed participants’ beliefs about participants, 36% had prior investing experience, and how Fidelity selects funds to advertise. One question, 91% expected to invest in stocks within the next five which appeared on a separate page prior to the oth- years. Participants spent an average of two-and-a- ers, asked “How do you think Fidelity Investments half hours per week reading business-related peri- decides which mutual funds to advertise?” A scale odicals and watching business television shows that question that followed asked participants whether Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS 1115

they thought Fidelity deliberately advertises funds contrast explains all significant observed between- that have better-than-average historical performance. group (Rosnow and Rosenthal 1996). Finally, The purpose of these questions was to determine we predict that participants with lower composite sta- whether participants know that large companies like tistical reasoning scores will give relatively high rat- Fidelity do not provide representative fund perfor- ings on the dependent measures regardless of whether mance data in their advertisements. or not they receive the sample space cue. Finally, half of the participants answered six sta- tistical reasoning questions. The questions asked for 5.2. Results levels of agreement with the following statements: We find that the explicit sample space cue debi- (1) investigators who think in terms of statistical prob- ases selection neglect on the six key dependent mea- abilities are more likely to catch criminals than those sures. We also find that those with lower statistical who do not; (2) if 10 people predict the score of a reasoning scores were less likely to be influenced lottery game and one gets the numbers exactly right, by our debiasing manipulations than those with we should rely more on that person’s predictions in higher scores. Before providing details, we discuss the future lottery games; (3) even an unskilled economist manipulation checks. will occasionally make accurate predictions; (4) in a game of darts, a person who scores 6 bulls-eyes 5.2.1. Manipulation Check and Related Tests. in 6 attempts is more likely to get a bulls-eye in Participants in all conditions indicated how many her next attempt than one who scores 8 bulls-eyes funds they believed Fidelity operated prior to the in 30 attempts; (5) a customer can learn more about introduction of the new growth fund. When asked the overall quality of fruit in a store by examining prior to the key dependent measure, this question was 10 boxes of berries selected by the store manager our selection neglect debiasing mechanism. This ques- than by examining 10 boxes of berries selected at ran- tion also served as a manipulation check for partici- dom; and (6) a randomly selected professor at a uni- pants in the 2 of 30 condition. Eleven participants in versity is more likely to be 40–45 years old than to the uncued 2 of 30 condition and 18 participants in be 70–75 years old. We reverse-coded responses to the cued 2 of 30 condition indicated an incorrect num- questions 2 and 5 so that higher responses always ber of funds. These participants are excluded from the indicate a greater propensity toward statistical rea- remaining analyses. Three participants in the 2 of ? soning. After assessing the reliability of the underly- conditions who gave responses that were more than 10 ing construct (Cronbach’s alpha = 07), we averaged standard deviations above the mean are also excluded. responses to the six questions to form a composite Among the remaining participants in the 2 of ? con- statistical reasoning score for each participant. ditions, the mean estimated number of funds was 36 5.1.3. Predictions and Analyses. We predict that in the uncued condition and 41 in the cued condition. selection neglect can be overcome with an extrinsic The mean estimated number of funds in both the cued sample space cue. Operationally, investors in the cued and uncued 2 of 30 conditions was 30. The similarity to this article and distributed this copy as ahidden courtesy to the author(s). selection (2 of ?) condition (i.e., those who esti- of estimates across the four experimental conditions = mate the number of funds Fidelity operates prior to (F3 140 033, n.s.) suggests that introduction of the cue answering the key questions) will have lower beliefs did not affect participants’ beliefs about how many about the company, lower performance expectations, funds Fidelity operates. It also rules out differential beliefs about the number of funds Fidelity operates as copyright and be less willing to invest than those in the uncued hidden selection (2 of ?) condition. We also predict an explanation for differences on the dependent mea- that investors in the transparent selection (2 of 30) sures across experimental conditions. holds conditions will be unaffected by the absence or pres- We also asked investors how they think companies ence of the cue because sample space transparency decide which funds to advertise. Study 1 showed that within their advertisement already triggers their sta- companies advertise their better-performing funds. tistical heuristics. If investors believe otherwise, then selection neglect INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. In short, we predict the following relations on may be more about financial advertising naiveté than

all of the key dependent measures: MUncued 2 of ? > . However, the data are inconsistent = = MCued2of? MUncued 2 of 30 MCued2of30. We test with naiveté. In response to an open-ended ques- this pattern with planned contrasts (Buckless and tion, 77% of participants mentioned that Fidelity Ravenscroft 1990), using a contrast coefficient of 3 advertises their highest-performing stocks. No other for the uncued hidden selection condition and −1 factor was mentioned by more than 10% of partici- for the other three conditions. We include a test of the pants. Moreover, all but one participant agreed with between-group variance that is unexplained by the con- this statement: “When deciding which growth funds trast. A lack of significance on this residual noncon- to advertise, Fidelity probably chooses funds with trast between-group effect indicates that the planned better-than-average historical performance.” Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements 1116 Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS

Figure 2 Investors’ Performance Expectations and Willingness to Invest by Condition (Study 3)

Panel A: Mean perceived performance expectations Fidelity performance expectations New fund performance expectations 7 7 2 of ? 6 6 5.0 2 of 30 5.1 5 5 4.1 4.2 4 4 4.2 4.0 4.1 4.0 3 3 7 = very high) 7 = very high) 2 2 Rating (1 = very low, Rating (1 = very low,

1 1 Uncued Cued Uncued Cued Condition Condition Panel B: Mean perceived willingness to invest Willingness to invest Percent willing to invest 7 60 47.8 6 50 4.9 5 40 34.4 3.9 4 30 32.7 33.5 4.0 3.8

3 Percentage 20 7 = very high) 2 Rating (1 = very low, 10

1 0 Uncued Cued Uncued Cued Condition Condition

= 5.2.2. Beliefs About Fidelity: Success and Trust- residual noncontrast F2 141 004, n.s.; New Fund Expec- = worthiness. Consistent with expectations, partici- tations: contrast F1 141 1437, p<001; residual non- = pants in the uncued 2 of ? condition believed that contrast F2 141 029, n.s.). As predicted, participants Fidelity was more successful than did participants in the cued 2 of ? condition had lower expectations = in the other three conditions (MUncued 2 of ? 54 ver- for Fidelity overall and for the new growth fund than = = = sus MCued2of? 46, MUncued 2 of 30 49, MCued2of30 those in the uncued 2 of ? condition (Fidelity Expecta- = = = 44; contrast F1 141 1236, p<001; residual non- tions: t76 330, p<001; New Fund Expectations: t76 = contrast F2 141 219, n.s.). We observed similar 3534, p<001). = results for trustworthiness (MUncued 2 of ? 50 versus We observed a similar pattern in our willingness = = = MCued2of? 45, MUncued 2 of 30 45, MCued2of30 43; to invest measures (see panel B of Figure 2). Par- to this article and distributed this copy as a courtesy to the author(s). = contrast F1 141 707, p<001; residual noncontrast ticipants in the uncued 2 of ? condition were more = F2 141 034, n.s.). In particular, participants in the willing to invest and invested a greater percent than cued 2 of ? condition judged Fidelity as less success- those in the other three conditions (WTI: contrast = = ful and trustworthy than those in the uncued 2 of ? F1 141 1259, p<001; residual noncontrast F2 141 = = copyright condition (Success: t76 315, p<001; Trustworthiness: 139, n.s.; Percent: contrast F1 141 1172, p<001; = = t76 201, p<005). These results suggest that our residual noncontrast F2 141 006, n.s.). Finally, as extrinsic sample space cue made the selection process expected, participants in the cued 2 of ? condition holds more transparent for participants in the 2 of ? condi- were less willing to invest and invested a smaller per- tion. When participants were cued to think about sam- cent than those in the uncued 2 of ? condition (WTI: = = ple space, those in the 2 of ? condition were no more t76 371, p<001; Percent: t76 265, p<001). These impressed with Fidelity than were those in the 2 of 30 results support our contention that an extrinsic sam- INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. conditions. ple space cue can help debias selection neglect by 5.2.3. Performance Expectations and Willingness leading investors to think about the broader sample to Invest. Participants also indicated whether they space and access their statistical heuristics. expected Fidelity stock funds overall and the new 5.2.4. Path Analysis. Thus far, we have exam- growth fund in particular to beat the S&P 500 index ined selection neglect and a debiasing technique on (see panel A of Figure 2). Participants in the uncued investors’ (a) beliefs about the fund company, (b) per- 2 of ? condition were much more likely to believe that formance expectations, and (c) willingness to invest.5 both Fidelity and its new fund would outperform the S&P 500 than participants in the other three conditions 5 To ensure that the questions that measure beliefs about the = (Fidelity Expectations: contrast F1 141 1464, p<001; fund company, performance expectations, and willingness to invest Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS 1117

Figure 3 Path Analysis (Study 3)

–0.06

–0.01

Beliefs Experimental Performance Willingness about Fund Condition Expectations to Invest –0.28 Company 0.75 0.79

0.87 0.80 0.95 0.93 0.86 0.84

Success Trustworthiness Fidelity New Fund WTI Percent

Notes. This figure reports the standardized regression coefficients from our path analysis. Bold lines indicate significant paths (all p<001). Dashed lines indicate insignificant paths (all p>010).

We now offer a test of the relations among these are included, the Condition → Willingness to Invest link variables using the AMOS structural equation mod- is not significant (coefficient =−006, n.s.). Thus, our eling program. We have already demonstrated that manipulated variables affect willingness to invest via investors’ beliefs about the fund company differ by their effects on performance expectations and beliefs experimental condition. Specifically, participants who about Fidelity. were in the three conditions that were cued to think 5.2.5. Individual Differences in Statistical Rea- about sample space rated Fidelity as less successful soning. Because the sample space cue was designed and trustworthy than those in the remaining condi- to improve access to statistical heuristics, it follows tion. We expect these beliefs about Fidelity to drive that nonstatistical reasoners are less likely to benefit participants’ performance expectations. This predic- from its introduction. We test this idea by examin- tion assumes that at least some investors believe in ing whether participants’ statistical reasoning scores a “hot hand” model of mutual fund returns (i.e., predict their willingness to invest. We expect that rel- past success predicts future success) rather than a atively high statistical reasoners will fit the pattern random walk model. Research confirms that this is M >M = M = M what investors believe (Capon et al. 1996) and that Uncued 2 of ? Cued2of? Uncued 2 of 30 Cued2of30 on both the willingness to invest and percent willing they act on those beliefs (Jain and Wu 2000).6 We to invest measures. Relatively low statistical reasoners expect participants’ performance expectations to then are less likely to fit this pattern because the sample drive willingness to invest. Figure 3 provides a graph- space cue is less likely to trigger statistical heuristics. ical summary of this model. The data fit the model to this article and distributed this copy as a courtesy to the author(s). The data support these predictions. We perform a well. The model’s comparative fit index is 0.99. Val- median split on statistical reasoning scores to iden- ues greater than 0.95 indicate a good model fit (Hu tify those who are relatively more or less inclined and Bentler 1999). to reason this way. We then conduct ANOVAs with The individual path coefficients are also as ex-

copyright Statistical Reasoning Experimental Condition pected. Specifically, we find that the Condition → and as WTI Percent Beliefs about Fund Company link (coefficient =−028), independent variables, and and as depen- → dent variables. We observe a significant Statistical Rea-

holds the Beliefs about Fund Company Performance Expec- = soning by Experimental Condition interaction term in tations link (coefficient 075), and the Performance = → = both ANOVAs (WTI: F3 60 563, p<001; Percent: Expectations Willingness to Invest link (coefficient = = 079) are significant (p<001 for all). Importantly, F3 60 275, p 005), suggesting the statistical rea- the Condition → Willingness to Invest link is signifi- soning has a greater effect on WTI and Percent in INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. cant when we omit Beliefs about Fund Company and some experimental conditions than others. Follow-up Performance Expectations from the model (coefficient = tests show that, among participants with above-the- −025, p<005); but when these mediating variables median statistical reasoning scores, the investment pattern was identical to the general finding: Investors in the uncued 2 of ? condition were more will- capture three separate underlying constructs, we conducted a fac- ing to invest than those in the other conditions tor analysis on the six questions. The resulting three-factor rotated component matrix shows that each question has its primary load- that promoted access to statistical heuristics (WTI: = = ing on the expected construct (all coefficients > 0.75). MStat. heuristics not accessed 54, MStat. heuristics accessed 26, = = 6 Our predictions depend on investors’ beliefs about the correct t34 529, p<001; Percent: MStat. heuristics not accessed = = model rather than which model actually describes returns. 513, MStat. heuristics accessed 173, t34 555, p<0001). Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements 1118 Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS

This pattern did not appear among participants with may also be useful for debiasing selection neglect below-the-median statistical reasoning scores (WTI: in other settings. For example, when medical per- = = MStat. heuristics not accessed 47, MStat. heuristics accessed 44, sonnel or drug representatives tout the success of a = = t35 064, n.s.; Percent: MStat. heuristics not accessed 485, new treatment with before-and-after pictures, treat- = = MStat. heuristics accessed 417, t35 074, n.s.). ment evaluators might be asked to consider how Correlations between statistical reasoning scores many people in total received the treatment. Impor- and WTI in each of the four conditions also illus- tantly, Study 3 also showed that it may be harder trate the effects of individual differences in statistical to debias selection neglect with such prompts among reasoning in our task. The data show that statistical people who are less inclined to reason statistically. reasoning scores are negatively correlated with WTI and Percent for the three conditions that enhanced 6. General Discussion = access to statistical heuristics (WTI: rCued2of? Financial magazines and advisors frequently coun- − =− =− 046, rUncued 2 of 30 085, rCued2of30 069, all sel investors to consider the track record of mutual =− = p<005; Percent: rCued2of? 055, rUncued 2 of 30 funds before investing (Chamberlain et al. 2009). − =− 071, rCued2of30 049, all p<005). This is the However, this seemingly prudent advice can back- expected result if people who have lower statistical fire if (a) companies selectively advertise their most reasoning tendencies do not access corrective statis- successful funds, and (b) investors fail to appreciate tical heuristics that dampen enthusiasm for invest- this fact. We investigated these issues in three studies ing with Fidelity. But what about the lone condition and found selection bias in mutual fund advertise- that was not conducive to accessing statistical heuris- ments and selection neglect in investors. The finding tics (the uncued 2 of ? condition)? Here the negative that mutual fund companies provide biased snap- relationship between statistical reasoning scores and shots of their success by selectively advertising their = better-performing funds (Study 1) comes as no sur- WTI disappears (WTI: rUncued 2 of ? 025, n.s.; Percent: =− prise. More surprising, perhaps, is that the judgments rUncued 2 of ? 002, n.s.). This result provides further support for the theory that investment enthusiasm in and decisions of novice and professional investors the uncued 2 of ? condition arises because people alike are influenced by advertised performance data that almost certainly arose through a selective (i.e., do not automatically think about sample space. Even biased) process. Unless cued to attend to sample the high statistical reasoners in this condition did not space, investors apparently gave little thought to access their statistical heuristics. selection bias and relied on potentially biased data Finally, the results suggest that selection neglect is (Studies 2 and 3). It may seem surprising that pro- not confined to hypothetical situations or to situations fessional investors’ knowledge and experience fail to in which investors are unfamiliar with the advertis- inoculate them from selection neglect. However, expe- ing company. Even though investors knew that the rience is an insufficient teacher (Einhorn and Hogarth advertising company operated numerous funds, those 1978), and cognitive errors may not yield to expertise, who were not explicitly reminded of this fact were particularly in the financial realm (Wilcox 2003). to this article and distributed this copy as amore courtesy to the author(s). impressed with the company and more will- We had success debiasing selection neglect with ing to invest than those who received the reminder subtle manipulations, although the bias persisted in the advertisement itself. Apparently, one’s back- among those who scored lower in statistical reason- ground knowledge about the number of funds oper- ing. This group might benefit from a stronger and copyright ated by a company provides insufficient protection more direct debiasing manipulation. For investors against the perils of selection neglect. who scored higher in statistical reasoning, enthusiasm for the company and its offerings dampened when holds 5.3. Discussion their attention was directed to the broader sample People are relatively insensitive to selection bias space from which the advertised funds were selected. unless the sample space or sampling process is called This finding supports our conclusion that there is a to their attention. Sometimes task stimuli contain suf- disconnect between investors’ understanding of the limited INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. ficient sample space or sampling cues. These cues value of selected data and their ability to access and apply help many people recognize a data selection situation, this understanding in situations where the sample space or access statistical heuristics, and discount accordingly. selection process is not expressly cued. However, when data providers have an interest in Research on statistical reasoning finds a similar dis- the inferences others draw from those data, sample connect in other areas. For example, most people space cues may not be available. In Study 3 we found understand that base rates (i.e., background proba- that, for many people, a simple extrinsic sample space bilities) provide relevant information for case predic- cue (asking people to estimate the total number of tions. However, people sometimes give little weight to funds a company operates) debiased selection neglect base rates (for a review, see Koehler 1996). Similarly, in a financial advertising setting. This cuing technique people may give great weight to anecdotes and vivid Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS 1119

testimonials in reasoning tasks at the expense of more of strategic behavior. We provided 94 business stu- systematic evidence (Nisbett and Ross 1980). Con- dents similar to those in Study 3 with a list of the sider, for example, quotes from satisfied customers 25 U.S. mutual funds with the highest returns over on a company flier or examples of successful stock the last 3-, 5-, and 10-year periods. Participants were picks on a financial adviser’s website. Such informa- informed that the list was compiled by Morningstar (an tion disconfirms extreme, but irrelevant, hypotheses independent company that tracks mutual fund perfor- such as “all customers are dissatisfied,” or “none of mance). Reliance on this source eliminated concerns the advisor’s recommendations were winners.” How- about strategic selection and presentation by a particu- ever, the value of this information for assessing qual- lar fund company. The list showed that Fidelity Invest- ity is indeterminate because the data may consist of ments had a significant number of top-performing self-serving . This is not a complicated or con- mutual funds over each time period. Fidelity is one troversial point, yet it merits attention because studies of the largest mutual fund companies in the United show that untutored intuition commonly treats sam- States, and thus could have a significant number ple data as near-perfect representations of the popula- of funds on the list by chance alone. However, if tions from which they were derived (Rabin 2002). This investors fall prey to selection neglect, they will not error does not arise from a conscious belief that sam- access their knowledge about Fidelity’s large sample ples are perfectly representative of populations (Fiske space of funds unless prompted. To test this idea, we and Taylor 1991). Instead, questions of sample space and asked all participants to estimate the total number of sample adequacy simply do not surface in the minds of mutual funds that Fidelity operates and to express decision makers absent an appropriate cue. their willingness to invest in a new Fidelity fund. We varied the order of these questions: Half of the 6.1. Selection Neglect or Strategic participants indicated their willingness to invest after Behavior Neglect? estimating the total number of Fidelity funds (Cued One might argue that investors’ failure to discount condition), and half indicated their willingness to the selected performance data contained in mutual invest before estimating the number of funds (Uncued fund ads is due to strategic behavior neglect (i.e., condition). Whereas a theory of strategic behavior a failure to appreciate the strategic nature of adver- neglect does not predict differences between the Cued tisements) rather than selection neglect (i.e., a failure and Uncued conditions in terms of their willingness to appreciate the larger sample space of funds). To to invest, the selection neglect theory does. In support rule out this possibility, we asked Study 3 participants of selection neglect, participants in the Cued condition an open-ended question about how managers decide were significantly less willing to invest and invested a smaller percentage than those in the Uncued condi- which funds to advertise. Most participants (77%) = = = tion (WTI: MeanCued 42, MeanUncued 55, t 467, spontaneously mentioned that Fidelity advertises its = = p<0001; Percent: MeanCued 375, MeanUncued 523, highest-performing stocks. This result is inconsistent = with a claim that investors’ ignorance about advertis- t 328, p<001). to this article and distributed this copy as aers’ courtesy to the strategic author(s). behavior drives our effects. Further, our 6.2. Lessons and Solutions effects do not seem to arise from a failure to access The lessons of partial sensitivity to selection bias (i.e., knowledge about advertisers’ strategic behavior. Par- sensitivity to selection bias when the biased sam- ticipants who received performance data that were not pling process is made transparent, but not otherwise) copyright strategically selected (i.e., those in the 2 of 2 condition) depend on whether one is the provider or recipient of were less willing to invest than those who received information. The lesson for information providers is data that were strategically selected (i.e., those in the that selective advertising works. By advertising selec- holds 2 of 30 condition). If participants failed to access their tively, information providers may find it easier to pro- knowledge about strategic behavior, judgments in the mote a positive image and make a persuasive case for two conditions would have been the same. Instead, its products and services. In the mutual fund world, participants in the 2 of 30 condition apparently recog- companies might also exploit investors’ insensitivity INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. nized that a company that operates 30 funds is likely to hidden selection bias by increasing the number of to advertise its top performers rather than its typi- funds they operate, increasing the volatility of the cal performers, and they discounted the advertised individual funds, and decreasing performance cor- data accordingly. These results suggest that investors relation across funds. This strategy would improve understand the strategic nature of fund advertise- companies’ chances of having a few funds that per- ments and can access this knowledge when judging form well above the benchmarks by chance alone. the fund company. These funds could then be advertised selectively. As further evidence that selection neglect rather If markets are efficient, no lesson is necessary for than strategic behavior neglect best explains our data, information recipients, because those who mistak- we demonstrated selection neglect in a setting devoid enly rely on the selected data in mutual fund ads Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements 1120 Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS

will not incur any real costs. However, prior studies have minimal diagnostic value? How can we remind show that markets are not efficient in this setting. jurors that they are hearing a strategically selected set Jain and Wu (2000) find that advertised mutual funds of evidence (Koehler and Thompson 2006)? How can underperformed the S&P 500 by an average of 7.9% we remind readers everywhere that the phrase “for in the year subsequent to the advertisement. If this example”—which we use five times in this paper— result persists, investors who are more willing to signals a forthcoming illustration that is more likely to invest in a fund after viewing its advertised per- be extreme than typical? Selection bias may be every- formance will be worse off, on average. This sug- where, but the tendency to fall victim to its unwel- gests that when evaluating advertised performance come influence is treatable. data, investors should consider the (typically undis- closed) number of chances the advertising company Acknowledgments had to portray favorable data. They should consider The authors thank Kenworthey Bilz, Bill Goldstein, Nick how many funds a company operates and how those Schweitzer, and Laura Starks for helpful comments. funds performed in different time frames. The more opportunities a company has to present positive out- References come data, the more skeptical investors should be of Barber, B. M., T. Odean, L. Zheng. 2005. Out of sign, out of advertisements that depict outstanding performance. mind: The effects of expenses on mutual fund flows. J. Bus. 78 In sum, the lesson for information recipients is that 2095–2119. they should consider advertisers’ incentives to manip- Brown, S. J., W. N. Goetzmann. 1995. Performance persistence. ulate available cues (Daniel et al. 2002) and the ease J. Finance 50 679–698. with which they are able to do so. Buckless, F. A., S. P. Ravenscroft. 1990. Contrast coding: A refine- ment of ANOVA in behavioral analysis. Accounting Rev. 65 From a regulatory standpoint, it may be appropri- 933–945. ate to modify the rules that dictate financial adver- Cain, D. M., G. F. Loewenstein, D. A. Moore. 2005. The dirt on tising practices. Rules 482 and 34b-1 of the SEC coming clean: Perverse effects of disclosing conflicts of interest. and Rules 2210 and 2211 of the National Association J. Legal Stud. 34 1–26. of Securities Dealers (NASD) regulate mutual fund Capon, N., G. J. Fitzsimmons, R. A. Prince. 1996. An individual level analysis of the mutual fund investment decision. J. Finan- advertising. Companies that advertise must provide cial Serv. Res. 10 59–82. “a sound basis for evaluating the facts in regard to Carhart, M. M. 1997. On persistence in mutual funds performance. any particular security,” and may not “omit any rel- J. Finance 52 57–82. evant material fact or qualification if the omission, in Chamberlain, J., S. DeCarlo, B. Zajac. 2009. Mutual fund survey. Forbes (January 14), http://www.forbes.com/2009/01/14/ light of the context of the material presented, would mutual-fund-investing-funds109-pf-ii_jc_sd_bz_0114intro.html. cause the communications to be misleading” (NASD Clements, J. 2002. Rewriting history: How mutual funds hide Rule 2210(d)(1)(A)). Although none of the companies mistakes by closing bad performers. Wall Street Journal in our study disclosed the total number of funds it (July 10) D1. offers in its ads, we submit that such disclosure is a Daniel, K., D. Hirshleifer, S. H. Teoh. 2002. Investor relevant material fact. Failure to disclose this informa- in capital markets: Evidence and policy implications. J. Mon. to this article and distributed this copy as a courtesy to the author(s). Econom. 49 139–209. tion may mislead potential investors. Denrell, J. 2003. Vicarious learning, undersampling of failure, and the myths of management. Organ. Sci. 14 227–243. 6.3. Future Research Denrell, J. 2007. Adaptive learning and risk taking. Psych. Rev. 114 This paper focused on product-level selection bias and 177–187. copyright selection neglect in a financial advertising context. Diacon, S. 2004. Investment risk perceptions: Do consumers and Future researchers may wish to examine other forms advisors agree? Internat. J. Bank Marketing 22 180–199. of selection bias such as which companies advertise Einhorn, H. J., R. M. Hogarth. 1978. Confidence in judgment: Per- holds sistence of the illusion of validity. Psych. Rev. 85 395–416. in the first place (company-level selection bias) or Fiedler, K. 2000. Beware of samples! A cognitive-ecological sam- which product features companies reveal (content- pling approach to judgment biases. Psych. Rev. 107 659–676. level selection bias). Recent SEC rulings have clamped Fiedler, K. 2008. The ultimate sampling dilemma in experience- down on one form of selection bias by requiring a uni- based decision making. J. . Psych: Learn., Memory, INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/. form set of disclosures for advertised products. Still, Cognition 34 186–203. Fiske, S. T., S. E. Taylor. 1991. Social Cognition, 2nd ed. McGraw-Hill, creative companies will find ways to draw attention to New York. selected funds and time frames without violating SEC Gilbert, D. T., D. S. Krull, P. S. Malone. 1990. Unbelieving the unbe- standards. lievable: Some problems in the rejection of false information. Researchers interested in selection neglect more J. Personality Soc. Psych. 49 601–613. broadly may wish to investigate ways to sensitize Hamill, R., T. D. Wilson, R. Nisbett. 1980. Insensitivity to sample bias: Generalizing from atypical cases. J. Personality Soc. Psych. people to sample space in contexts where regulatory 39 578–589. agencies are unlikely to help. How can we convince Hearst, E. 1991. Psychology and nothing. Amer. Sci. 79 432–443. admissions committees that letters of recommenda- Heckman, J. J. 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification error. tion provided by persons of a candidate’s choosing Econometrica 47 153–161. Koehler and Mercer: Selection Neglect in Mutual Fund Advertisements Management Science 55(7), pp. 1107–1121, © 2009 INFORMS 1121

Hendricks, D., J. Patel, R. Zeckhauser. 1993. Hot hands in Malkiel, B. G. 1995. Returns from investing in equity mutual funds mutual funds: Short-run persistence of relative performance, 1971 to 1991. J. Finance 50 549–572. 1974–1988. J. Finance 48 93–130. Nisbett, R. E., L. Ross. 1980. Human Inference: Strategies and Short- Holland, P. W. 1988. Causal inference, path analysis, and recursive comings of Social Judgment. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. structural equations models. Sociol. Methodology 18 449–484. Nisbett, R. E., D. H. Krantz, C. Jepson, Z. Kunda. 1983. The use Hu, L., P. M. Bentler. 1999. Cutoff criteria for fit indexes in covari- of statistical heuristics in everyday inductive reasoning. Psych. ance structure analysis: Conventional criteria versus new alter- Rev. 90 339–363. natives. Structural Equation Model. 6 1–55. Rabin, M. 2002. Inference by believers in the law of small numbers. Jain, P. C., J. S. Wu. 2000. Truth in mutual fund advertising: Evi- Quart. J. Econom. 17 775–816. dence on future performance and fund flows. J. Finance 55 Rosnow, R. L., R. Rosenthal. 1996. Contrasts and interactions redux: 937–958. Five easy pieces. Psych. Sci. 7 253–257. Jordan, J., K. P. Kass. 2002. Advertising in the mutual fund business: Shapira, Z., I. Venezia. 2001. Patterns of behavior of professional The role of judgmental heuristics in private investors’ evalua- managed and independent investors. J. Banking Finance 25 tion of risk and return. J. Financial Serv. Marketing 7 129–140. 1573–1587. Kahneman, D., S. Frederick. 2002. Representativeness revisited: in intuitive judgment. T. Gilovich, Stanovich, K. E., R. F. West. 2000. Individual differences in reason- D. Griffin, D. Kahneman, eds. Heuristics and Biases: The Psy- ing: Implications for the rationality debate. Behavioral Brain Sci. chology of Intuitive Judgment. Cambridge University Press, 23 645–665. New York, 49–81. Stanovich, K. E., R. F. West. 2008. On the relative independence of Koehler, J. J. 1996. The reconsidered: Normative, thinking biases and cognitive ability. J. Personality Soc. Psych. descriptive and methodological challenges. Behavioral Brain Sci. 94 672–695. 19 1–53. Tversky, A., D. Kahneman. 1971. Belief in the law of small numbers. Koehler, J. J., W. C. Thompson. 2006. Mock jurors’ reactions to Psych. Bull. 76 105–110. selective presentation of evidence from multiple-opportunity Wilcox, R. T. 2003. Bargain hunting or star gazing? Investors’ pref- searches. Law Human Behav. 30 455–468. erences for stock mutual funds. J. Bus. 76 645–663. to this article and distributed this copy as a courtesy to the author(s). copyright holds INFORMS Additional information, including rights and permission policies, is available at http://journals.informs.org/.