Quick viewing(Text Mode)

Public Policies and Education, Economic Browth and Income Distribution

Public Policies and Education, Economic Browth and Income Distribution

,N+, NWV,+5WAv W5AWANA, #,+A,A 6 ,W5

,NW `Lh!?} @Tih , L bb%e M*U L*Uit @?_ ,_U@|L?c ,UL?L4U BhL| @?_ W?UL4i #t|hM|L?

B?|ih -j6j

#W 6W,5wc 5 #,W E6W ** h}|t hitihi_ L T@h| Lu |t T@Tih 4@) Mi hiThL_Ui_ ? @?) uLh4 |L| Tih4ttL? Lu |i @|Lh

U bbb B?|ih +i4i h?|i_ ? W|@*) ? Th* bbb ,hLTi@? N?iht|) W?t|||i @_@ 6itL*@?@ WDffS 5@? #L4i?UL E6W W|@*)

Public Policies and Education, Economic



Growth and

y

Gunther Rehme

Technische Universitat Darmstadt

February 1999



This pap er is taken from Chapter 4 of my dissertation defended at the EUI in

December 1998. I would like to thank Tony Atkinson, , and Rob ert

Waldmann for helpful advice and stimulating suggestions. Ihave also b ene tted from

comments byFrank Cowell, Jean-Yves Duclos, Lavan Mahadeva, Eugene Smolensky,

and participants of the conferences SSCW98 in Vancouver, EEA98 in Berlin and

I IPF98 in C ordoba, Argentina. Of course, all errors are myown. Financial supp ort by

the Deutscher Akademischer Austauschdienst DAAD, grant no. 522-012-516-3, and

an Erasmus grant for Nueld College, Oxford, in 1995 are gratefully acknowledged.

y

Correspondence: TU Darmstadt, FB 1/VWL 1, Schloss, D-64283 Darm-

stadt, Germany. phone: +49-6151-162219; fax: +49-6151-165553; E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

This pap er provides an analysis relating economic growth, hu-

man capital comp osition, income distribution and public educa-

tion p olicies. In the mo del human capital is 'lumpy' and only the

high skilled carry it. The government cho oses capital to -

nance education, which directly a ects growth, the number of high

skilled p eople and wages. Growth and income equality dep end

p ositively on the pro ductivity of the education sector. Analyzing

various p olicies I show that e.g. the preferred p olicy of the un-

skilled is growth maximizing, whereas that of skilled lab our leads

to less education, lower growth and more wage inequality. The pa-

p er's public p olicy analysis provides an explanation for the recent

observation of high growth and relatively low income inequality

in some highly comp etitive economies.

Keywords: Growth, Distribution, Human Capital, Public Ed-

ucation, Public Policy

JEL Classi cation: O41, I2, H2, D3, D6 2

1 Intro duction

As markets b ecome more integrated 'globalization', human capital is

assuming a pivotal role in p olicy debates esp ecially in OECD countries

on the maintenance of international comp etitiveness. The exp erience of

some East Asian, high growth countries suggests that empirically there

is a p ositive link from the provision of education to income equality and

1

growth. This pap er o ers a theoretical explanation of the stylized fact

and contributes to the p olicy debates, by recourse to three issues that

have b een put on the agenda by growth theorists. One of the issues

is that human capital formation may explain long term patterns of eco-

nomic growth very well. See, for instance, Lucas 1988, Tamura 1991,

Glomm and Ravikumar 1992 or Caball e and Santos 1993.

A second issue concerns population. For instance, Kremer 1993,

Deardor 1994 or Romer 1996 show that p opulation size and its

growth explain patterns of economic growth, if one lo oks at very long

time horizons Kremer's is more than one million years!. In those mo d-

els the larger the p opulation is, the more likely technological progress and

so higher growth is. Furthermore, Becker, Murphy and Tamura 1990

or Rosenzweig 1990 show that economically driven fertilitychoices and

human capital investments may lead to growth.

Thirdly, the pap er considers the theory of distribution and growth

which has b een analyzed in a vast numberofcontributions. Just to name

a recent few suce it to mention Bertola 1993, Alesina and Ro drik

1994 or Garcia-Pe~nalosa 1995b who derive interesting conclusions on

the relationship between re-distribution and growth, mainly showing

that the relationship is negative if resources are distributed to the non-

accumulated factor of pro duction.

The pap er takes as its starting p oint the stylized fact that high

growth economies have larger or more ecient public education systems

and may show low degrees of income inequality. Even in countries such

1

For discussions of this issue see e.g. Deininger and Squire 1996, B enab ou 1996,

Bertola 1998 or Aghion and Howitt 1998, chpt. 9. 1

2

as the US a very signi cant fraction of education is carried out publicly.

The p opulation in the mo del is made up of high skil led or low skil led

workers. So the mo del argues that the p opulation composition matters

in the growth pro cess by assuming that human capital can be identi ed

with 'degrees'. Thus, education is taken to be 'lumpy' in that p eople

are hired as high skilled workers in the lab our market only if they have

obtained a degree.

In the pap er the agents own the initial capital sto ck equal ly. In the

literature on human capital investment, it is usually shown that given

some distribution of innate abilities and costly education, optimizing

agents sort themselves into high and low skilled workers dep ending on

the path of the wage rates and the . See, for

instance, Mincer 1958 or Findlay and Kierzkowski 1983. If markets

work p erfectly, the sorting will see to it that the lifetime utility of a high

and a low skilled worker is equalized, and that there is no inequality

in the present value of lifetime earnings. However, should the capital

market not function p erfectly so that agents wishing to fund education

cannot b orrow against future earnings, the sorting will be distorted and

one would observe inequality in the present value of lifetime earnings.

The assumption of equal capital ownership eliminates that e ect on the

p eople's choice of education. Instead, in the pap er the source of wage

inequality lies in the pro duction pro cess itself. High skilled p eople carry

human capital that enables them to p erform all the tasks a low skilled

p erson can do and more. E ective labour dep ends on basic skil ls and

high skil ls in pro duction. By assumption basic skil ls and high skil ls are

imperfect substitutes in pro duction, but low and high skil led people are

perfect substitutes in basic skil ls. Thus, high skilled p eople may always

p erform the tasks of low skilled p eople, but low skilled p eople can never

execute tasks that require a degree. In a p erfectly comp etitive lab our

market this entails that the high skilled workers get a wage premium

over and ab ove what their low skilled colleagues receive.

2

Notice that governments have scal and institutional instruments other than di-

rect provision of education at their disp osal that have a signi cant b earing on the

working of private education systems. For a discussion of public vs. private education

see Glomm and Ravikumar 1992. 2

The wage premium is shown to dep end negatively on the p ercentage

of high skilled p eople, which captures an imp ortant and realistic asp ect

in the explanation of wage rate inequality. For empirical studies on this

issue see, for instance, Freeman 1977, Katz and Revenga 1989, Bound

and Johnson 1989, Tilak 1989 or Londono ~ 1990.

The government's task is to provide and nance education. Re-

sp ecting the right of private prop erty, the government nances education

3

by raising a on the wealth of all individuals. So even those who

have not received education contribute to nancing it. That is realis-

tic in most public education systems and - as shown b elow - is in the

low skilled p eople's interest. The mo del p ostulates a simple relationship

between government revenue and education output, by which the p er-

centage of high skilled p eople in p opulation is directly related to the tax

rate. Ex ante every agent would like to and may get a degree so that

4

innate ability di erences are not imp ortant in the set-up. That is so

5

b ecause I assume that education is provided as a public good.

3

The command optimum would involve expropriation of the capital sto ck. As that

is not common in the real world, it is ruled out. For a similar p oint cf. Alesina and

Ro drik 1994.

4

In the mo del agents are endowed by some basic ability and receive basic education

which is pro duced and provided costlessly. In the pap er education is always meant

to be higher education. Ex ante everyb o dy is a candidate for receiving higher

education and once chosen to be in the education pro cess will complete the degree.

The education pro cess is taken to be suciently pro ductive in converting no skills

into high skills. Even if p eople have the same innate abilities and the same initial

endowments and although the capital market functions p erfectly, there is inequalityin

the presentvalue of lifetime earnings in the mo del. For a recent mo del that studies the

p ositive and causal link from income equality to human capital accumulation and

high growth, see Chiu 1998. His mo del attributes the source of inequality to innate

ability di erences and liquidity constraints. This pap er o ers a di erent, technology

based explanation with a p ositive causal link from human capital to income equality

and high growth for given p olicy.

5

I abstract from problems arising from the time sp ent receiving education. Of

course, students forgo wage earnings for some time with the exp ectation that they

are comp ensated by higher wages in the future. If one follows the human capital

literature e.g. Mincer 1958 and views education as an e ort demanding pro cess,

causing students to exp erience disutility while learning, the mo del may easily account

for that by endowing the low skilled by some xed p ositive and endowing the high

skilled by some xed negative amount of lifetime 'happiness', without altering the

qualitative results of the pap er. Along these lines I consider only adults who are at 3

In the market equilibrium growth is p ositively related to the p er-

centage of high skilled p eople in p opulation up to a certain p oint. That is

so b ecause the government takes resources away from the private sector

in order to nance education, which reduces growth. On the other hand

it generates more high skilled p eople which exert a p ositive e ect on pro-

duction, growth and wage equality. For maximum growth taxes and so

the number of high skilled p eople must not be to o high. Furthermore,

growth and wage equality dep end p ositively on the pro ductivity of the

education sector.

Next, a public p olicy analysis is conducted. If the government's

welfare function attaches xed weights to the representative high or low

skilled individual's utility, a p olicy that only represents the low skil led

worker is like a Raw lsian p olicy. Both cho ose the growth maximizing

number of high skilled p eople in the mo del. The intuition for this is that

the low skilled worker's wage do es not dep end on x, the p ercentage of high

skilled p eople in p opulation. But their capital income do es dep end on x,

which explains why the low skilled worker cho oses the growth maximizing

x and the highest after-tax return on capital. A striking implication of

the mo del is that growth maximization and Raw lsian preferences yield

identical p olicies.

The opp osite holds for a government that only represents the aver-

age high skil led worker. It acts like an Anti-Raw lsian government. Both

cho ose x lower than the growth maximizing one, b ecause the wage pre-

mium dep ends negatively on x. High skilled workers do not like to o many

of their own kind, since that reduces the wage premium but raises their

capital income. In the optimum they cho ose a x lower than the growth

maximizing one.

In the mo del a strictly utilitarian government faces the non-trivial

problem of maximizing individual utility levels and the weight, it attaches

to them. It optimally sets a x higher than the growth maximizing one,

least as old as the ones with a degree. Then the low skilled joining the lab our pool

as adults may be taken to have received utility by b eing idle during adolescence. In

contrast, the high skilled would have studied and su ered disutilityup to adultho o d.

Alternatively, one may simply assume that all p eople sp ent the same time in scho ol,

but attend di erent courses leading to di erent degrees. 4

which implies that it attaches more weight to having high skilled p eople

in the economy than making the average high or low skilled individual

'happy'.

A comparison of the di erent p olicies indicates that a government

serving the average low skilled worker cho oses a growth maximizing p ol-

icy. It is ambiguous whether in comparison to each other the utilitarian

or the average high skilled lab our serving government has higher growth,

but b oth cho ose less than maximal growth.

The optimal low skilled workers' p olicy implies a more equitable

wage distribution than a high skilled workers' one. In comparison, the

strictly utilitarian governmentcho oses a more equal wage ratio than the

low skilled workers' government. Interestingly,a strictly utilitarian p olicy

is more egalitarian in the mo del than a Raw lsian one.

High and low skilled lab our form the clientele of representative

governments. The public p olicy analysis suggests that the recent high

growth, relatively low income inequality exp erience of some countries may

be due to a combination of public education p olicies and improvements

in the pro ductivity of the education sector which is dicult to measure.

If the pro ductivity is equal across some countries, a p olicy favouring low

skilled lab our maximizes growth, attracts capital by granting high after-

tax returns and reduces inequality compared to the optimal p olicy of

high skilled lab our.

The pap er is organized as follows: Section 2 describ es the economy.

Section 2.1 derives the optimal b ehaviour of the private sector and the

market equilibrium. Section 2.4 investigates optimal p olicies for govern-

ments with di erent welfare functions. Section 2.5 compares the optimal

p olices and section 3 provides some concluding remarks.

2 The Mo del

Consider an economy that is p opulated by N large memb ers of two

representative dynasties of in nitely lived individuals. The two dynasties

are high skil led workers, L , and low skil led workers, L , where L ;L

1 0 1 0 5

denote the total numb ers of the resp ective agents in each dynasty. The

di erence between high and low skilled lab our is "lumpy", that is, either

an individual has received education in the form of a degree and is then

considered high skilled or it has no degree and remains in the low skilled

lab our p o ol. By assumption the p opulation is stationary so that L xN

1

and L 1 xN where x denotes the p ercentage of high skilled p eople

0

in p opulation. The memb ers of the dynasties supply one unit of either

high or low skilled lab our inelastically over time. Each worker initially

owns an equal share of the total capital sto ck, which is held in the form of

shares of many identical rms op erating in a world of p erfect comp etition.

Thus, all agents receive wage and capital income and make investment

6

decisions. I assume that aggregate pro duction is given by

1

] ; 0 < < 1; 1 H ; H = [L + L  + L Y = A K

1 0 t t

1 t

where K denotes the aggregate capital sto ck including disemb o died tech-

t

7

nological knowledge, H measures e ective lab our in pro duction, and A

t

is a pro ductivity index at time t. The pro duction function is a reduced

8

form of the following relationship between high and low skilled lab our:

By assumption e ective labour dep ends on basic skil ls and high skil ls and

that basic skil ls and high skil ls are imperfect substitutes in pro duction.

On the other hand it is assumed that low and high skil led people are

perfect substitutes in basic skil ls. Thus, high skilled p eople may always

p erform the tasks of low skilled p eople in the mo del, but low skilled p eo-

ple can never execute tasks that require a degree. Notice that each typ e

6

Postulating an equal initial wealth capital distribution is a simpli cation, which

serves to bring out clearly the e ects of di erent p olicies on the income distribution.

Alternatively, supp ose a third typ e owns al l the initial capital sto ck. Then one may

verify that all the results for governments representing high or low skilled workers

hold. Also, as will be shown b elow, the workers' utility dep ends on the balanced

growth rate so that analyzing high and low skilled workers emb o dies the problem, a

capital owning class would have.

7

Thus, technological knowledge is taken to b e a sort of capital go o d which is used

to pro duce nal output in combination with other factors of pro duction. For an up-to-

date discussion of these kinds of endogenous growth mo dels see, for instance, Aghion

and Howitt 1998, chpt. 1.

8

For a more detailed explanation see App endix A. 6

of lab our alone is not an essential input in pro duction.

The government runs a balanced budget at each p ointin time, uses

its tax revenues to nance public education and maintains a constant

9

ratio of exp enditure G to its tax base. It taxes the agents' wealth

t

holdings at a constant rate  on the capital sto ck of the representative

G K

t t

. So G = k N = K and =  for all t. Thus, real agent k =

t t t t

N K

t

resources are taken from the private sector and used to nance public

education, which generates high skilled workers. In general, public edu-

cation is 'pro duced' using government resources and other factors such

as high skilled lab our itself. That is captured by the following reduced

form of the education technology



x =  where 0 <   1 ; 2

1 2

x =  > 0 and x =  1  0. Thus, if the government

 

channels more resources into the education pro cess, it will generate more

high skilled p eople, x > 0. However, doing this generally b ecomes more



dicult at the margin. This is supp osed to re ect that, if x < 0, more



public resources provided to the education sector lead to a decreasing

marginal pro duct of those resources due to congestion or other e ects.

10

The parameter  measures the pro ductivity of the education sector. If

 < 1, the education sector is pro ductive and a marginal increase in the

wealth tax rate increases education output substantially. Underlying that

is the description of an education sector with spillovers from, for instance,

9

Various tax bases would be p ossible to investigate in the mo del. Capital taxes

are considered to keep the analysis simple and are supp osed to capture a broad class

of tax arrangements. For a similar approach in a di erent context see Alesina and

Ro drik 1994.

10

The reduced form education technology directly relates the p ercentage of high

skilled p eople x to the p ercentage of resources wealth going into the education

sector  . Then  may be viewed as the elasticity of education output to edu-

cation nancing input and may be interpreted as a pro ductivity measure. As



x =  ln  < 0 b ecause  < 1, a higher  reduces output for given  . Thus,



for given p olicy a decrease in  re ects a more pro ductive education technology. Also

x

1

and more conventionally, let pr = denote pro ductivity. Then pr =  , which is



decreasing in  as well. Hence, for given p olicy pro ductivitywould b e decreasing in 

according to b oth pro ductivity concepts. 7

high skilled to new high skilled p eople or where the capital equipment

such as computers makes the education technology very pro ductive. The

case  = 1 lo oks as though the education technology were quite pro duc-

tive as well, since then the number of high skilled p eople rises one-to-one

with an increase in the tax rate. However, x < 0 for given p olicy so that



a higher  leads to less high skilled p eople education output. Combining

this with the assumption of a non-increasing marginal pro duct x  0



may justify calling  = 1 a relatively unpro ductive education technology.

Equation 2 is compatible with many mo dels that also use high

skilled lab our as an input generating education. For instance, let h

t

denote the total sto ck of human capital in the economy in a discrete

time mo del. Following Azariadis and Drazen 1990 assume that human

capital evolves according to

h = f G ;K ;h  h

t+1 t t t t

where new human capital h is pro duced by non-increasing returns.

t+1

Here human capital formation would dep end on the level of the sto ck of

knowledge h , government resources provided for education G and the

t t

tax base K . The function f  governs the evolution of human capital.

t

G

t

= Assume that it is separable in the form f g G ;K ;h . Let g = c

t t t

K

t

c  and for simplicity

0 00

; where c  0; c > 0; c  0; 0 < < 1: h = c  h

t+1

t

where measures the pro ductivity of the education sector and c  cap-

tures the eciency or quality of education, dep ending on the government

11

resources channeled into education. What distinguishes this mo del

from those contributions is that in this pap er human capital is carried

discretely by the agents and so h = x N . Normalize p opulation by set-

t t

ting N = 1. Then total human capital at date t is given by x . In a

t

11

For a similar expression in an optimizing agent framework, see Nerlove, Razin,

Sadka and von Weizsacker 1993 eqn. 7. That is a widely used sp eci cation. See,

for example, eqns. 1, 2 in Glomm and Ravikumar 1992, eqn. 1 in Eckstein and

Zilcha 1994, or eqn. 2 in Razin and Yuen 1996. 8

steady state x = x = x and so

t t+1

1

1

: x = c 

Next supp ose that the eciency of the education sector is describ ed by



c  =  where 0 <  < 0. For non-increasing returns to scale it is



necessary that  +  1. Let  then the more explicit set-up

1

would be equivalent to 2 in steady state. As x < 0, any increase 



would mean that less human capital is generated in steady state. From

the assumption of non-increasing returns to scale it follows that   1

so that   1. Hence,  = 1 would represent a relatively unpro ductive

human capital formation pro cess.

Finally, notice that from equation 2 cho osing  is equivalent to

cho osing x. For the rest of the chapter it is convenient to use the inverse

1



relationship  = x whenever the government cho oses taxes.

2.1 The Private Sector

There are as many identical rms as individuals and the rms face p erfect

comp etition. I assume that there is a capital spillover, which takes the

K

t

form A = , where  , so that the average capital sto ck = k

t

t

N

12

is the source of a p ositive externality. Then simplify by setting =

which allows one to concentrate on steady state b ehaviour. For a justi-

cation see Romer 1986. As the rms cannot in uence the externality,

it do es not enter their decision directly so that

r = 1 k K H ;

t

t

h i

1

1 1

L + L  + L ; 3 w = k K

1 0 1

t

1

t

1

1

w = k K L + L  :

0 1 0

t

t

The workers have logarithmic utility and own all the assets which are

collateralized one-to-one by capital. A representative worker takes the

12

The mo del also works if the externality dep ends on the entire capital sto ck instead. 9

paths of r;w ;w ; as given and solves the problem

1 0

Z

1

t

max ln c e dt 4

i

c

i

0

_

s:t: k = w +r  k c i = 0; 1 5

i i

k = constant; k = free:

0 1

Equation 5 is the worker's dynamic budget constraint. The worker's

problem is a standard one see e.g Chiang 1992, chpt. 9. and its

solution involves the following growth rate of the average high or low

skilled worker's consumption

= = = r   : 6

c c

0 1

So consumption of all workers grows at the same rate in the optimum

and dep ends on the after-tax return on capital. As the workers own

the initial capital sto ck equally and have identical utility functions, their

investment decisions are the same. Thus, the wealth distribution will

not change over time and all agents continue to own equal shares of the

total capital sto ck over time. The only di erence in utility stems from

di erent wage incomes which a ect the instantaneous levels of steady

state consumption.

2.2 Market Equilibrium

For the rest of the pap er normalize by setting N = 1 so that the factor

rewards in 3 are given by

1

r = 1 1 + x  ; w = k 1 + x  and w = k : 7

1 t 0 t

The return on capital is constant over time and wages grow with capital.

1

As w = w 1 + x , high skilled lab our receives a premium over what

1 0

their low skilled counterpart gets. That re ects the fact that the high

skilled may always p erfectly substitute for low skilled lab our so that

b oth typ es of lab our receive the same wage w for routine tasks and that

0

p erforming high skilled tasks is remunerated by the additional amount 10

1

w x . The premium dep ends on the p ercentage of high skilled lab our

0

in the p opulation, grows over time at the rate and is decreasing in x

for a given capital sto ck.

From the pro duction function one immediately gets = so

y k

that per capita output and the capital-lab our ratio grow at the same

rate. With constant N total output also grows at the same rate as the

aggregate capital sto ck. From 6 the consumption of the representative

K

0

worker grows at . Each worker owns k = units of the initial capital

0

N

w c

i i

_

sto ck. Equation 5 implies k = w +r  k c so that = r

i i k

k

  for i = 0; 1 where r   is constant. In steady state, is constant

k

w

i

is constant as well, b ecause from 7 by de nition. But

k

1

w k 1 + x  w

1 t 0

1

= = 1 + x  and = ;

k k k

t t t

which implies = . Thus, the economy is characterized by balanced

k

growth in steady state with = = = = = .

Y K y k c c

1 0

_

Furthermore, from equation 5 and using k = k and = =

k k c

1

in steady state one obtains r  k = w +r  k c . Thus,

c t i t i

0

c = w + k and c = w + k 8

1 1 t 0 0 t

are the instantaneous consumption levels of a representative high or low

skilled worker in steady state.

1 1

 

one obtains = 1 1+ x  x  From 6, 7 and  = x

so that for given  an increase in x raises growth. The necessary rst

1

1



x

1

order condition for growth maximization involves 1 x =



which up on solving for x establishes that



1

x^ = [ 1 ] 9

is the growth maximizing p ercentage of high skilled workers in the p op-

1

1

is the growth maximizing tax rate. ulation and ^ = [ 1 ]



1

Lemma 1 Agrowth maximizing government chooses x^ = [ 1 ] 11

1

1

. and ^ = [ 1 ]

Growth is a concave function of x since for   1 and any x

2

12

d 1 1

2 2



= 1  x 1 x < 0

2

dx  

and the marginal growth rate for x ! 0 is in nity,

3 2

1



d x

1

5 4

lim = +1 = x 1 

x!0

dx 

1

since  1 by assumption. By the concavity of and given the ab ove



prop erties there is a x, generating the same growth as 0. In that

case the government cho oses a rather high tax rate, implying a high x.

So in the mo del it is p ossible that an economy has high skilled workers,

but do es not do b etter than another economy with no high skilled p eople.

That x is given by

1



+  = 0 0 x = 1   1 [1+x ]+ x



1

10 x~ = 1 

and clearly x~ > x^. The e ect of a change in the pro ductivity of the

education sector for a given x 2 0; 1 is given by

1



d lnx x

< 0: =

2

d 

An increase in  makes the pro duction of education more dicult. So a

reduction in , that is, making the education technology more pro ductive,

raises the growth rate. Hence, the growth maximizing x must also be

higher.

Lemma 2 The growth rate has the fol lowing properties:

d

1. is concave in x. 2. lim = +1.

dx

x!0



d

1

3. < 0 for x 2 0; 1. 4. If x~ = 1  , then 0 = x.

d 12

The prop erties can be read o from Figure 1. It can be seen that the

Figure 1: as a function of x for di erent 

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. . .

. . .

. . .

. . .

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

......

......

......

.. ...

.. ..

. ..

.. ..

.. ..

. ..

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. ..

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. . ^

. .

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

. . 2

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

. . .

. .

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

. . .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. . .

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

......

. .. ..

.. ..

......

. .

. . ..

. . .

. . . . .

. . .

. .

. . . .

. . .

. . .

. . ..

. .

. . . . .

.

. . . .

. ^

. . . . .

. .

. . .

.

. . . .

. . . .

.

. . .

. . .

. . .

. 1

. . .

. . . .

. .

. . .

.

. . . .

. .

. . .

.

. . . .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

.

.

. . .

. .

.

. .

. . . .

.

. .

.

. . .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

. . . .

. .

.

. . .

. .

.

.

. . .

.

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

. . .

. . .

.

.

. .

. . .

. . .

. . .

. .

. . . .

. .

. . .

. . . .

. .

......

. . . .

.

. .

. . . . .

.

. .

. . . .

. .

. . 0

. . . .

.

.

. .

. . .

. .

.

.

. . . .

. .

. .

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

. .

. .

. . .

.

. .

. .

. . .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

. . . .

. .

.

. . . . .

. .

. . . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . . . .

. .

.

. . .

. .

. .

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

. .

. . . .

. .

. . . . .

. .

.

. . .

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

. .

.

. . .

. .

. . .

. .

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

. .

. . . .

. .

. . . . .

.

.

. . . .

. .

.

. . . .

.

. .

. . .

. .

.

. . . . .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

.  

. .

. .

.

. .

.

.

. 2

.

.

. .

.

. .

. .

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

. .

. . . .

. .

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

. .

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

. .

.

. . .

. .

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . . . .

.

.

. . . .

. .

. . . . .

.

.

. . . .

. .

. . . . .

.

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

.

. . . .

.

. .

. . . .

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. . . . .

.

.

. . . .

. .

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

. .

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

.

.

. . . .

. .

. . . . .

.

. .

. . .

.

.  

.

. . .

. .

.

. . . .

.

. .

. . .

. . 1

.

. . . .

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. . . .

.

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

.

.

. . . .

. .

. . . .

.

.

.

. . . .

. .

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

.

.

. . . .

.

.

. . . . .

.

. .

. . .

.

.

.

. . .

. .

.

. . . .

.

. .

. . .

. .

. . . . .

. .

. .

.

......

.

. .

. .

. . . . .

.

. . ..

. .

. . . ..

. . .

..

. .

......

. .

..

. . .

..

. . .

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. . .

.

.

. .

. .

.

. . .

x

x^ x^ x~

1 2 2 1

1

Parameter values: = ,  =0:01,  =1,  =0:6.

1 2

2

growth maximizing x increases with an increase in the pro ductivity lower

 of the education technology and that there exists a x~ where 0 =

x.

2.3 Income Inequality

In the mo del all income di erences between individuals are due to di er-

ences in wage income. If one wants to relate growth to income inequality

it makes sense to lo ok at an average of p ersonal wage incomes over time.

If the agents can sell their income stream in a p erfect capital market,

they will discount their stream of wages by the market rate of return on

assets, r  . Consequently, the present value of their lifetime wages is

Z Z

1 1

w

i0

r  t t r  t d

w e dt = w e e = where i = 0; 1: w

it i0

i



0 0

d

Thus, w denotes the sum of an individual's wage income discounted by

i

the market rate of return on assets. That is the income concept used 13

13

when analyzing the wage income distribution in this pap er. Notice

1

k w k 1 + x  w

0 1 0 0

d d

= and w = = 11 w =

1 0

   

and that the mean of the discounted sum of wage incomes is

1 + x  k

0

d d d

= + xw  = 1 xw : 12

1 0



d d

d

dw dw

d

1 0

= 0, < 0 and > 0, that is, the mean of the PV implying

dx dx dx

of lifetime wage income is increasing in x. In order to compare any

two cumulative distribution functions of discounted lifetime wage income

assume x > x. Then the di erent values of x will give rise to two

1

d d

x, which have x  and Gw cumulative distribution functions, F w

1

i i

unequal means.

If F dominates G in the sense of Second Order Stochastic Domi-

nance SOSD, then F will be preferred to G by any increasing, concave

so cial welfare function according to Atkinson 1970. Geometrically, a

distribution F w  dominates another distribution Gw  in the sense of

SOSD if over every interval [0;c], the area under F w  is never greater

14

and sometimes smaller than the corresp onding area under Gw .

Second Order Sto chastic Dominance is equivalent to Generalized

Lorenz Curve GLC dominance. For a pro of see, for example, Lamb ert

1993, pp. 62-66. A GLC is obtained by multiplying the values of the

y-axis of an ordinary Lorenz Curve, which relates the share of the p opu-

lation x-axis to the share in total income y-axis that that p opulation

share receives, by mean income, i.e. share of total income  mean

income. The GLC for the distribution of the PV of lifetime wages is

13

Other income variables one may want to use are current wage income w , de-

it

w

it

. All of these concepts su er trended initial wages w , or capital adjusted wages

i0

k

t

from the problem that do not fully re ect the path the wages follow.

14

The concept derives from evaluating risky returns under conditions of uncertainty.

See e.g. Hirshleifer and Riley 1992, chpt. 3.4. Formally and for non-negative incomes,

Z Z

c c

Gw dw . F w dw  Second Order Stochastic Dominance requires

0 0 14

presented b elow.

Figure 2: Generalized Lorenz Curve

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

1 mean income x 

.

.

.

.

1

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

1 mean income x

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

share in total income 

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

mean income

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . d

. .

. .

. .

.

.

. .

. .

. .

.

.

. 1 x w

.

.

.

.

.

.

. B

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

0

. d d .

. .

......

.

.

. .

.

.

. .

.

.

. . .

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

.

. .

. 0

. .

. .

.

.  1 + x  w =1 xw

. . .

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

. . .

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

. 0 0 .

. .

.

. B

. . .

.

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

.

. .

.

. d

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. 1 + x  w . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. 0 . .

. .

. .

. . .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. . .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. . 0

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

0 1

1 x

1 x

1

share in p opulation

A GLC dominates another one if the two curves do not cross and one

is completely ab ove the other one. In the gure the income distribution

asso ciated with x > x GLC-dominates the income distribution for x.

1

d

The reason is that an increase in x raises  and shifts the kink at B to

0

a p oint B which is to the left and on the old GLCx.

According to a theorem by Shorro cks 1983 GLC dominance car-

ries with it welfare approval according to every increasing, strictly con-

cave utility-of-income function. Put another way: Every individualistic

additively separable symmetric and inequality-averse so cial welfare func-

tion would prefer the GLC dominating income distribution. That means

that according to the GLC dominance criterion there exists a unanimous

preference for the PV of lifetime wage income distribution with the

higher GLC. Even the high skilled would prefer the distribution with a

higher x under e.g. a veil of ignorance. In that sense the mo del's so ci-

ety as a whole would prefer the distribution of the PV of lifetime wage

15

income generated by the higher p ercentage of high skilled p eople.

15

It is straightforward to see that exactly the same holds for the distribution of

w

it

. It also holds if detrended initial wage incomes w and capital adjusted wages

i0

k

t

one works with currentwage rates w and x  x^ . In that case an increase in x causes

it

the new GLC to be everywhere ab ove the old GLC for t > 0, b ecause the capital

sto ck would be higher at each date and mean income would rise. However, if x>x^

it do es not necessarily hold. 15

Let I x be any inequality measure re ecting that a higher x leads

16

to a GLC dominating distribution. Then I 0 = I 1 = 0 < I x and

dI

< 0 for x 2 0; 1. Thus, according to I x and for the PV of lifetime

dx

wage incomes there is no measured inequality if all agents get the same

wage and they are all either equally high or low skilled. If there is any

skill heterogeneity, pro ducing more skills reduces inequalityin the PV of



lifetime wage incomes if measured by I x. Furthermore, as x =  and

so I  , a decrease in  for a given p olicy  , would lower I x.

Prop osition 1 If there is heterogeneity in skil ls, x 2 0; 1, an increase

in the percentage of high skil led people or an increase in the productivity

of the education technology lower  for given policy reduce inequality in

the present value of lifetime wage incomes in the sense of Generalized

Lorenz Curve Dominance.

Thus, according to the prop osition and in terms of the PV of life-

time wage income an increase in the number of high skilled p eople repre-

sents an equalizing income transfer from a rich, high skilled to a relatively

p o or, low skilled p erson.

2.4 The Government

The government takes the optimal decision of the workers as given and

cho oses taxes to generate education output. This is equivalent to cho os-

ing x in the mo del. I assume that the government has di erent ob jectives.

For instance, it may represent only high skilled workers, only low skilled

workers or a mixture of the two. Integrating the utility of the repre-

sentative low and high skilled worker as given by 4 one obtains See

d

w

16

1

1 which Fields A simple measure satisfying the prop erties of I x is I =

d

w

0

1987, axiom A5, calls relative gap inequality, de ned in terms of mean wage incomes

of the two groups. Notice that the measure as such do es not take explicit account

of the p opulation comp osition. However, in the mo del it implicitly do es, b ecause the

wage rates dep end on the relative number of high skilled p eople. In app endix B I

check the prop erties of I x against those of some other commonly used inequality

measures. It is shown that, for instance, the variance and the co ecient of variation

1

have the prop erties of I xif  .

2 16

App endix C.

1

ln  1 + x + k  ln c

0 1

h

+ = + and 13 V =

2 2

   

ln c ln  + k 

0 0

l

V = = : 14 + +

2 2

   

h l

Sup erscript h l  stands for high low skilled. Notice that V > V for

x 2 0; 1.

A Class of Governments. Consider a government's so cial welfare

b h l h l

function W V ;V  = V +1  V with 2 [0; 1] which attaches

xed weights on the individual high and low skilled agent's utility. If

= 1 the government is only concerned ab out the welfare of the repre-

sentative high skilled worker and if = 0 it cares ab out the average low

skilled worker only. For all other values of it represents a mixture of

b

the representative agents' utility. The FOC for the maximization of W

is given by

 !  !

l h

1 @ 1 @ @V 1 1 @c 1  @c @V

1 0

+1  = + + + = 0:

@x @x  @x c  @x  @x c  @x

1 0

@c

0

= 0 b ecause low skilled lab our's wages and consumption Notice that

@x

do not dep end on x. Simpli cation yields

 ! !

2

1 k x

0 x

= 0 15 +

1 2

 k 1 + x +k 

0 0

@

where = . From this one immediately obtains an imp ortant result.

x

@x

As the rst expression on the LHS is negative for > 0, must be

x

p ositive. Given the concavity of the government would cho ose x < x^.

Thus, a government attaching p ositive weight to a representative high

skilled worker cho oses a smaller than the the growth maximizing x.

The case = 0 is of sp ecial interest b ecause it is equivalent to

the choice of a Raw lsian government. A Rawlsian government has a

h l

welfare function W = minV ;V . As the wages of the high skilled are 17

h l

always greater than those of the low skilled, c > c and so V > V

1 0

for all x 2 0; 1. But then = 0 captures the preferences of a Rawlsian

government with leximin preferences over the individuals' utilities. Thus,

a Rawlsian government, which maximizes the utilityof the least wel l-o ,

and a government representing the average low skilled worker, set the

growth maximizing tax rate, x = x^.

l

If = 1 the government acts in the interest of the average high

skilled worker. That government's choice is equivalenttoan Anti-Raw lsian

h l

government with leximax preferences such that W = maxV ;V . Re-

1

1



x

1

call = 1 x and use 15 to get the FOC for = 1

x



2

1

 1 k x

0

1 1



=  1 x x

1

k 1 + x + k

0 0

1

 1 

1+2



=  1 x x

1

1 + x + 

1



 x + x + x =  1 :  1  x

1



Notice x^ =  1  so that

1 1 1

  

x  x + x + x = x^ : 16 x^

Hence, an increase in makes a governmentcho ose a x lower than x^. The

lowest x will be chosen by a government representing the representative

high skilled worker. Call the x chosen by a = 1 government x . Then

h

x^ > x > x for 2 0; 1.

h

Prop osition 2 If = 0, the government represents the average low

skil led worker only and acts like a Raw lsian government. Both choose

x^ and maximize the after-tax return on capital and growth.

If = 1, the government represents the average high skil led worker

only and acts like an Anti-Raw lsian government. Both wil l set x < x^

h

and have lower growth than the Raw lsian government.

b

and > 0 wil l Any other government with a welfare function W

set x < x^ . The optimal choices imply ^ if = 0 and x  if = 1

h 18

where ^ > x . Also for 2 0; 1, x ; 1 < x;  < ^x; 0 and

h h

I 1 > I   > I 0.

Thus, wage inequalityis lower and growth higher under a Rawlsian than

b

under any other government with a welfare function W . Notice that

the prop osition do es not claim that the Rawlsian governmentcho oses to

17

eliminate all inequality.

A Strictly Utilitarian Government The strictly utilitarian govern-

u h l h l

ment maximizes W V ;V  = x V + 1 x V , and its problem is

u

non-trivial in the mo del, b ecause maximization of W do es not only in-

volve maximizing the individual utility indices, but also cho osing the

u

 weights x; 1 x attached to them. Using 14 one may express W

as

x ln c x 1 x ln c 1 x

1 0

u

W x = + + +

2 2

   

x ln c 1 x ln c

1 0

= + + :

2

  

u

The derivative of W with resp ect to x is given by

! 

u

@W 1 x 1 x @c @c

0 x 1

 x= ln c + + ln c +

0 1

2

@x  @x c @x c 

1 0

where  x denotes marginal welfare. As the initial consumption of the

@c

0

low skilled do es not dep end on x in steady state  = 0 simplify to

@x

obtain

 !

@c x 1 c

1 x 1

ln + + : 17  x=

2

 c @x c 

0 1

17

Minimal inequality is not p ossible in the mo del unless x = 0 or x = 1 which is

what a strictly utility or income egalitarian governmentcho oses. These choices would

also be Rawlsian. In Rehme 1998 it is shown that such an indeterminate p olicy

is generally bad for growth. Interestingly, if the agents are very patient, they prefer

x = 0. For the sake of realism this pap er assumes from now on that there is always

some heterogeneity in skills, x 2 0; 1. 19

1

For an optimum  x = 0 is required. Recall c = k 1 + x + k

1 0 0

so that

1

@c 1 x x

1

 x = < 0:

1

1

@x c 1 + x +

1

c

1

one veri es that Also for ln

c

0

! 

1

c 1 + x + 

1

 x ln > 0 = ln

2

c + 

0

1

1+x +

> 1. Thus, unless S x  x+  x = 0 one b ecause

2 1

+

gets x 6= x^ in 17. This follows from the concavity of . In app endix D

I show that S x > 0 and strictly decreasing for all x 2 [0; 1]. But then

 x > 0 at x = x^ and so by the concavity of one must have < 0 in

x

an optimum and x > x^ where subscript u denotes the optimal choice of

u

the utilitarian government.

Furthermore, it is shown in app endix E that the level of welfare

u u

W x is lower at x = 1 than at x^ . But W ^x > W 1 implies  x =

1 < 0 so that the optimal solution must satisfy x^ < x < 1, b ecause S x

u

u

is strictly decreasing for any x > x^ and is concave in x. As W ^x >

u

W 1 and all the derivatives exist, there must be one x 2 ^x; 1 where

 x = 0. Then, the choice x^ < x < 1 implies I 1 = 0 < I < I ^x and

u u

1 < < ^ .

u

Prop osition 3 A strictly utilitarian government chooses x such that

u

x 2 ^x; 1 implying 0 < I < I ^x and 1 < < ^ .

u u u

This is an interesting result and the intuition for it is not as straight-

forward as it seems. The strictly utilitarian government maximizes the

individual utility indices and the weights the groups contribute to over-

all welfare. More precisely, it trades o a higher individual high skilled

worker's utility requiring a low x with its desire to maximize the number

of high skilled p eople. On the other hand, it trades o higher welfare of

each low skilled p erson which would imply cho osing x^ with its desire to

minimize the number of low skilled p eople. In the optimum, it attaches 20

more welfare weight on having high skilled p eople in the economy than

cho osing the growth maximizing number of high skilled p ersons. Thus,

it cho oses lower than maximum growth, but by this it pushes down wage

inequality compared to a growth maximizing government.

2.5 Comparison of the Di erent Policies

The prop ositions imply 0 < x ;x ;x < 1 where x denotes the strictly

u h l u

utilitarian, x the high skilled lab our and x the low skilled lab our gov-

h l

ernment's optimal choice. Thus,

Prop osition 4 The optimal policies of the governments are such that

1. ; ; > 1. 2. = ^ > ; . 3. R . 4. I > I > I .

u h l l u h u h h l u

Figure 3: The governments' optimal p olicies

. .

. . .

. . .

. . .

. . .

. . .

. . .

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

......

.. ...

. ..

.. ..

.. ..

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

. . .

. .

. ..

. .

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

. .

..

. .

. .

.

^ . .

. .

.

. .

.

.

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

. . .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

. . .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

......

. . . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. . .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

. .

.

.

. .

.

.

. .

..

. .

..

.

. ..

..

......

. ..

..

.

. ..

.

.

. .

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

x

x x

 x !

h l 1

u

Agovernment representing the average low skilled worker acts growth

maximizing and generates less wage inequality than a government rep-

resenting the average high skilled worker. Due to the externality, high

skilled p eople exert on pro duction, the low skilled workers' wages do not

dep end on x in equilibrium. Thus, they cho ose maximum growth and

the highest after-tax return on capital.

For the average high skilled lab our representing government things

are quite di erent. The p ositive externalityin pro duction has a negative

impact on their wages and that makes them cho ose a low x. On the 21

other hand, a high x increases their capital income. The trade-o is

solved so that the wage income comp onent of their utility dominates and

they do not cho ose the growth maximizing x. So it is so cially desirable to

have sucient high skilled lab our, but for the representative high skilled

p erson it is privately bad, if to o many of its kind are present.

The strictly utilitarian government maximizes the sum of the in-

dividual utility indices. It cho oses more than the growth maximizing

number of high skilled workers b ecause it weighs the number of individ-

uals more than the average utility of each typ e. That leads to a p olicy

inducing a more equal wage income distribution. From the analysis it is

not clear whether a utilitarian government has higher or lower growth

than a government representing high skilled lab our, but it will de nitely

18

have less income inequality.

Interestingly, the strictly utilitarian government cho oses a p olicy

that is moreegalitarian in terms of wages than a government representing

low skilled lab our and so more egalitarian than a Raw lsian p olicy. That

provides an example that a Rawlsian ob jective do es not always imply

19

more egalitarianism than a utilitarian ob jective.

3 Conclusion

The exp erience of high growth economies suggests that there is a p ositive

link from providing education to income equality and growth. The pap er

o ers a theoretical explanation of this stylized fact. Assuming that only

p eople with a degree can take high skilled jobs, I show that the public

choice of human capital directly a ects income inequality and economic

growth.

18

This follows since the implicit solutions for the Anti-Rawlsian and the utilitarian

governments in 16, resp.  x = 0 in 17 are not easily solved and dep end in a

non-linear way on the parameters of the mo del. As an exact solution do es not add

signi cantly to the qualitative results, I leave it an op en question.

19

The textb o ok comparison of utilitarian and leximin welfare functions usually

argues that the choice of a utilitarian leads to more and not less inequality. See, for

instance, Mas-Colell, Whinston and Green 1995, p. 828. 22

Due to market imp erfections or institutional restrictions, the high

skilled contribute more to e ective lab our in pro duction than their un-

skilled counterpart. Hence, the number of p eople carrying high skills

plays a crucial role in the mo del. The government raises taxes on all

individuals and provides public education which pro duces human capi-

tal in the form of high skilled p eople. It is shown that the pro ductivity

of the education sector has a p ositive in uence on growth and income

equality. A Rawlsian government representing the average unskil led

worker cho oses the growth maximizing number of high skilled p eople.

The average high skil led worker's government cho oses less skilled p eople

and makes the wages more unequal and growth lower than the Rawlsian

p olicy. A strictly utilitarian government is shown to cho ose more high

skilled p eople than the low skilled lab our's government.

The pap er's main insight lies in the result that a government rep-

resenting the average low skil led worker cho oses maximum growth, the

highest after-tax return on capital and a wage distribution that is more

equitable than the one chosen by a government representing the average

high skil led worker. That stresses the imp ortance of education p olicies

in the growth pro cess and their distributional consequences. It also pro-

vides a theoretical explanation why some highly comp etitive East Asian

countries have relatively low income inequality and high growth.

Of course, it would be desirable to know more ab out the exact link

between government revenues channelled into education and the educa-

tion output. The level of human capital that individuals carry is clearly

imp ortant. Human capital acquisition may entail more than one degree

for di erent levels of human capital. These and other questions are left

for further research. 23

App endix

A Technology

1

By assumption Y = A H K , where the index of e ective lab our H

t t

t

t

dep ends on lab our requiring basic skil ls B  and lab our requiring high

skil ls S . Labour requiring basic skills is p erformed by high and low

skilled persons, B = B L ;L , whereas high skilled lab our is only p er-

0 1

formed by high skilled p ersons, S = S L . High and low skilled p eople

1

are p erfect substitutes to each other when p erforming basic skill routine

tasks, i.e. B L ;L  = L + L . Thus, high skilled p eople also p erform

0 1 0 1

those routine tasks a low skilled p erson may do. On the other hand,

only high skilled p eople can p erform high skilled tasks lab our and for

simplicity let S L  = L . To capture the relationship between lab our

1 1

1

1





 





inputs assume H = [B + S ] . For  < 1 lab our = [L + L  + L ]

1 0

1

requiring basic skills B  and lab our requiring high skills S  are imp er-

fect less than p erfect substitutes. For ease of calculations let  = < 1

which yields equation 1. For a similar set-up in a di erent context see

Garcia-Pe~nalosa 1995a.

B The relationship between I x and some

measures of income inequality

In this app endix and for convenience, the PV of lifetime wage income

will simply be called wage income.

Lorenz Curve. A Lorenz Curves LC relates the p opulation to the

d

income shares. Total wage income is  N . Furthermore, L = xN ,

0

d

L = xN and mean income  is increasing in x. The share of total

1 24

d d

1xw w L

0

0 0

= so that the Lorenz income going to the low skilled is

d d

 N 

curve lo oks like Figure 4 b elow.

Figure 4: Ordinary Lorenz Curve

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

1

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

share in total income .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

d

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

1 x w . .

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

A .

.

.

. .

.

.

0

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

......

. . .

.

. .

.

.

. .

. . .

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

. . .

.

.

. .

. .

.

. . .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

. .

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

d .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

1 + x  w . .

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

. .

.

.

. .

.

. . .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. . .

0 .

. .

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. . .

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. . .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

. .

.

. . .

. .

.

.

. .

.

. . .

.

. .

.

.

. .

. .

. .

. .

.

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

. .

.

. . .

.

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

.

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. .

.

. . .

. .

.

.

. .

.

. . .

.

. .

.

.

. .

. . .

.

. .

.

.

. .

. .

. .

.

. .

.

. .

. .

..

0 .

.

..

.

.. .

..

.

.

..

.

. .

0 1

1 x

share in p opulation

The Lorenz Curve LC has a kink at the p oint A at which 1 x

1x

p ercent of total wage income. On p ercent of the p opulation receive

1+x

the margin an increase in x shifts A to the left by 1 unit for a given

income share. On the other hand, a marginal increase in x reduces the

income share by

1

1 + x + x 1 x

2

1 + x 

for a given population share. If such a change would move A up to

any new p osition ab ove the old Lorenz Curve LC dominance, then

inequality would unambiguously have b een reduced. Thus, one must

analyze whether the movementof A to the left is greater or less than the

movementupordown. In the mo del A moves down. Thus, the condition

amounts to

1

1 + x + x 1 x

LH S  : < 1 : RH S 

2

1 + x  25

If x is rather lowx ! 0, the inequality do es not hold. Hence, in general

the LCs cross no unambiguous ranking of the wage income distributions

is p ossible according to the LC dominance criterion.

Gini Co ecient. From the LC one may calculate the Gini co ecient

as

" 

2 2 1

x1 x 1 x x 1 + x  x 1 x

+ G = 1 2 + =

21 + x  1+ x 21 + x  1+x

where the expression in square brackets represents the area under the

LC. Then

i h

1 1

1 + x  x x 1 x sg nG  = x 1 x x

x

1

= x [ 1 x x]1+ x  x 1 x

For low x, x ! 0, an increase in x raises the Gini index, whereas for

higher values of x a higher x reduces it. Hence, the Gini co ecient do es

not pro duce unambiguous rankings of the wage income distribution.

The Variance and the Co ecient of Variation. The variance of

d

p ersonal wage income V x is

d d d 2 d d 2

V = w   x +w   1 x

1 0

h i h i

2 2

d 1 d d d

= w 1 + x  w 1 + x  x + w w 1 + x  1 x

0 0 0 0

" 

2

1 x

2

2

d 2

= w x x +x  1 x

0

x

2

2 1 d

x 1 x = w

0 26

1

which is decreasing in x if < . The co ecient of variation is de ned

2

p

d

V

d

by C and amounts to

d



1

2

1

d

1 w x

0

x

d

: C x=

d

w 1 + x 

0

dC

The sign of dep ends on

dx

2 3

1 1 1

2 2 2

1 x 1 x x 1 x

1 2 1

4 5

x x 1 + x  x x

x 2 x x

!  "

1

1

2

1 x 1 x 1

1

= x 1 + x  x 1

x x 2 x

1

. which is de nitely negative for all x 2 [0; 1] if 

2

C Welfare Measures

R

j

t

t

The workers' welfare integral is given by U = ln c e dt where

j;t

t

0

j = 0; 1. Let t ! 1 and use integration by parts. De ne v = ln c ,

2 j;t

t

dv = e . Then dv = c_ =c = = constant, in steady state, and

1 2 j j

1

t

v = e . That implies

1



Z Z

h i

1 1

1

1 1

t t t

ln c e ln c e dt = + e dt

j;t j;t

0

 

0 0

1

1 ln c 0

j

t

e ; C1  =

2

 

0

where j = 0; 1. Evaluation of the expression at the particular limits

h l

establishes V in 13 and V in 14. 27

D Pro of that S x > 0 for all x 2 [0; 1]

I want to show S x  x+  x > 0 for all x 2 [0; 1]. To this end

2 1

1

let  x 1 + x + and notice that S is the sum of two functions.

3

I will show that S x is strictly decreasing in x for any x 2 [0; 1]. So I

need to know the derivative of S x with resp ect to x which is given by

@  @  @S

2 1

= +

@x @x @x

2 2 2 2 2 2 3

1 x 1  x 1  x

= +

2

  

3 3

3

2 2 2 3 2 2 2

1  x 1  x

=

2

 

3

3

and is clearly negative for any non-negative x. Thus, S x is strictly

decreasing in x. Next, I show that lim S x = 0 implying inf S x =

x!1

0; 8x 2 0; 1. So I need to show that lim  + lim  = 0. Notice

2 1

x!1 x!1

that

1 1

1 x 1  1 x

 = = : =

1

 

1 1 1

+1 1 + x +  1+ x + x 1 +

Then the claim is clearly true since

 !

1 

lim  = lim = 0 and

1



1

x!1 x!1

+1 x 1 +

! 

1

1 + x + 

= 0: lim  = lim ln

2

x!1 x!1

+ 

Since x 2 [0; 1] one clearly has x < 1 and so inf S x > 0 for all x 2 [0; 1]

and so S x > 0. 28

u u

E Pro of that W ^x  > W 1

I want to show that the level of welfare W x is lower at x = 1 than at

x^. Let x = 1. Then the di erence in welfare levels is given by

x^ ln c^ ln c 1 x^lnc 1 x lnc ^ 

1 1 0 0

u u

W ^x W 1 = : + +

2

  

where c is indep endent of x. Furthermore, using 9,

0

1 1

 

 [1 a2 1 ] = +1 ^x x^ ^  = 1 [1+ x^ ] x^

= + x^ [1 1  ] B > 0:

Then the condition for the di erence in welfare levels to be p ositive is

 !

d

B

x^ ln c^ x ln c c x x^lnc B c^

1 1 1 0 1

x

> + + > 0 , e

2

   c c

0 0

d

2 3

y y y

x^ c^

y

1

where d = and x = 1. Note that + + + ::: . > 1 and e = 1+

x c 1! 2! 3!

0

Then a sucient condition for the inequality with x = 1 to hold is

 !

1

B x

1+ + ::: > 1+

x + 



C + B >

+ 



E1 C + x^ [1 1  ] >

+ 

where C is a p ositive constant. Thus, the inequality holds b ecause the

u u

RHS is negative. Hence, W ^x > W 1 implying that  1 < 0, that

20

is, marginal welfare is negative if x is close to one.

20

It is not dicult to verify that a similar result may be obtained for x~ > x^. If

u u

~ > then W ^x >W ~x and  ~x < 0 by reasoning as ab ove. 29

References

Aghion, P. and P. Howitt, Endogenous Growth Theory, Cambridge,

Mass.: MIT Press, 1998.

Alesina, A. and D. Ro drik, \Distributive Politics and Economic

Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1994, 109, 465{490.

Atkinson, A. B., \On the Measurement of Inequality," Journal of Eco-

nomic Theory, 1970, 2, 244{263.

Azariadis, C. and A. Drazen, \Threshold Externalities in Economic

Development," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1990, 105, 501{526.

Becker, G. S, K. M. Murphy, and R. Tamura, \Human Capi-

tal, Fertility, and Economic Growth," Journal of Political Economy,

1990, 98, S12{S37.

B enab ou, R., \Inequality and Growth," in B. S. Bernanke and J. J.

Rotemb erg, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1996, Cambridge

and London: MIT Press, 1996, pp. 11{73.

Bertola, G., \Factor Shares and Savings in Endogenous Growth,"

American Economic Review, 1993, 83, 1184{1198.

, \Macro economics of Distribution and Growth," Working Pap er

98/39, Europ ean University Institute 1998.

Bound, J. and G. Johnson, \Changes in the Structure of Wages Dur-

ing the 1980's: An Evaluation of Alternative Explanations," Work-

ing Pap er 2983, NBER 1989.

Caball e, J. and M. S. Santos, \On Endogenous Growth with Physi-

cal and Human Capital," Journal of Political Economy, 1993, 101,

1042{1067. 30

Chiang, A. C., Elements of Dynamic Optimization, New York:

McGraw-Hill, 1992.

Chiu, W. H., \Income Inequality, Human Capital Accumulation and

Economic Performance," Economic Journal, 1998, 108, 44{59.

Deardor , A. V., \Growth and International Investment with Diverg-

ing Populations," Oxford Economic Papers, 1994, 46, 477{491.

Deininger, K. and L. Squire, \A New Data Set Measuring Income

Inequality," World Bank Economic Review, 1996, 10, 565{591.

Eckstein, Z. and I. Zilcha, \The e ects of compulsory scho oling on

growth, income distribution and welfare," Journal of Public Eco-

nomics, 1994, 54, 339{359.

Fields, G. S., \Measuring inequalitychange in an economy with income

growth," Journal of , 1987, 91, 611{625.

Findlay, R. and H. Kierzkowski, \International Trade and Human

Capital: A Simple General Equilibrium Mo del," Journal of Political

Economy, 1983, 91, 957{978.

Freeman, R., \The Decline in the Economic Rewards to College," Re-

view of Economics and Statistics, 1977, 59, 18{29.

Garcia-Pe~nalosa, C., \Absolute and Relative Inequality: A

Theory of Growth and Wage Di erentials," Discussion Pap er 97,

Nueld College, Oxford, UK 1995.

, \The Paradox of Education or the Go o d Side of Inequality," Oxford

Economic Papers, 1995, 47, 265{285.

Glomm, G. and B. Ravikumar, \Public versus Private Investment

in Human Capital: Endogenous Growth and Income Inequality,"

Journal of Political Economy, 1992, 100, 818{834. 31

Hirshleifer, J. and J. G. Riley, The Analytics of Uncertainty and

Information, Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992.

Katz, L. F. and A. Revenga, \Changes in the Structure of Wages:

The US versus Japan," Working Pap er 3021, NBER 1989.

Kremer, M., \Population Growth and Technological Change: One Mil-

lion B.C. to 1990," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1993, 108, 681{

716.

Lamb ert, P. J., The Distribution and Redistribution of Income: A

Mathematical Analysis, 2nd ed., Manchester, UK: Manchester Uni-

versity Press, 1993.

Londono, ~ J. L., \Human Capital and Long Run Swings of Income

Distribution," mimeo, Harvard University 1990.

Lucas, R. E., \On the Mechanics of Economic Development," Journal

of Monetary Economics, 1988, 22, 3{42.

Mas-Colell, A., M. D. Whinston, and J. R. Green, Microeconomic

Theory, Oxford University Press, 1995.

Mincer, J., \Investment in human capital and p ersonal income distri-

bution," Journal of Political Economy, 1958, 66, 281{302.

Nerlove, M., A. Razin, E. Sadka, and R. K. von Weizsacker,

\Comprehensive income taxation, investments in human and physi-

cal capital, and pro ductivity," Journal of Public Finance, 1993, 50,

397{406.

Razin, A. and C.-W. Yuen, \Capital income taxation and long-run

growth: New p ersp ectives," Journal of , 1996, 59,

239{263. 32

Rehme, G., \Essays on Distributive Policies and Economic Growth,"

Unpublished PhD Thesis, Europ ean University Institute 1998.

Romer, D., Advanced Macroeconomics, New York: McGraw Hill, 1996.

Romer, P. M., \Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth," Journal

of Political Economy, 1986, 94, 1002{1037.

Rosenzweig, M. R., \Population Growth and Human Capital Invest-

ments: Theory and Evidence," Journal of Political Economy, 1990,

98, S38{S70.

Shorro cks, A. F., \Ranking Income Distributions," Economica, 1983,

50, 1{17.

Tamura, R., \Income Convergence in an Endogenous Growth Mo del,"

Journal of Political Economy, 1991, 99, 522{540.

Tilak, J., \Rates of Return to Education and Income Distribution," De

Economist, 1989, 137, 454{465. 33