The Effects of CAFTA on Democratic Institutions in Central America" (2010)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Effects of CAFTA on Democratic Institutions in Central America Claremont Colleges Scholarship @ Claremont CMC Senior Theses CMC Student Scholarship 2010 Free Trade and Free Societies: The ffecE ts of CAFTA on Democratic Institutions in Central America David Nahmias Claremont McKenna College Recommended Citation Nahmias, David, "Free Trade and Free Societies: The Effects of CAFTA on Democratic Institutions in Central America" (2010). CMC Senior Theses. Paper 229. http://scholarship.claremont.edu/cmc_theses/229 This Open Access Senior Thesis is brought to you by Scholarship@Claremont. It has been accepted for inclusion in this collection by an authorized administrator. For more information, please contact [email protected]. CLAREMONT McKENNA COLLEGE FREE TRADE AND FREE SOCIETIES: THE EFFECTS OF CAFTA ON DEMOCRATIC INSTITUTIONS IN CENTRAL AMERICA SUBMITTED TO PROFESSOR RODERIC AI CAMP AND DEAN GREGORY HESS BY DAVID SIDNEY SHAFFER NAHMIAS FOR SENIOR THESIS FALL 2009/SPRING 2010 APRIL 26, 2010 CONTENTS CHAPTER 1. Introduction 1 CHAPTER 2. Theory and Methodology 30 CHAPTER 3. Mexico and NAFTA: A Test of the Democratic Audit 59 CHAPTER 4. El Salvador 91 CHAPTER 5. Costa Rica 138 CHAPTER 6. Conclusions 184 BIBLIOGRAPHY. 191 ABSTRACT During the debate over the ratification of the United States-Central America-Dominican Republic Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA), the Bush Administration argued that implementation of a free trade agreement would help strengthen the nascent democracies in Central America. As a bilateral agreement, CAFTA would not only foment greater trade liberalization by expanding market access and eliminating trade barriers, but also help transform the entire commercial frameworks in Central America and promote economic development. These implications are not just economic – in particular, its provisions on intellectual property and investment rights, government procurement and labor standards affect the political institutions underpinning democracy and rule of law. This thesis assesses the role in which CAFTA has affected democratic institutions in Central America. It employs a methodology known as the Democratic Audit to evaluate consequences to four dimensions of democracy – the electoral processes, open and accountable institutions, civil and political liberties, and civil society. It demonstrates the value of using the Democratic Audit to assess a trade agreement’s political effects with an application to Mexico after NAFTA. Then this work considers the case studies of El Salvador and Costa Rica, the most salient examples of democratic institutional change after CAFTA, by drawing on original research especially into the electoral politics and civil society development in these countries. Ultimately, the thesis argues that the most significant institutional effects of CAFTA have been its role as a political issue, rather than its content, in galvanizing popular opinion and reinvigorating electoral politics and civil society – ironically, not the consequences that the Administration originally had in mind. The research demonstrates that, even if some conclusions cannot be drawn due to the recency of CAFTA, the framework it has employed will be an invaluable tool for assessing future trade agreements. CHAPTER 1 Introduction In a 2005 address at the Heritage Foundation, a prominent Washington think tank, former United States Trade Representative and Deputy Secretary of State Robert Zoellick alleged that the implementation of a trade agreement with Central America would help consolidate democracy in a region beleaguered by a history of political authoritarianism and violence. The United States-Central America-Dominican Republic Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA) offered more than just an arcane debate on tariff levels, rules of origin, and intellectual property rights, a chance to weigh the entire political implications of regional economic integration. Zoellick called the impending agreement “the logical culmination of twenty years of democratic and social progress in Central America, nurtured and encouraged by the United States.” 1 According to Zoellick, CAFTA was an instrument to reinforce the budding democratic institutions in Central America established less than two decades prior. He explained that, “[CAFTA] will strengthen the foundations of democracy by promoting growth and cutting poverty, creating equality of opportunity, and reducing corruption.” 2 As per his reasoning, trade-induced growth would grant citizens a greater economic stake in their society, encouraging them to participate in their democracy. This oft-asserted 1 Robert Zoellick, “From Crisis to Commonwealth: CAFTA and Democracy in Our Neighborhood” (lecture, the Heritage Foundation, Washington, D.C., May 16, 2005). Available at www.heritage.org/research/tradeandforeignaid/hl884.cfm : 3. 2 Ibid., 4. 1 2 theoretical association between market capitalism and liberal democracy supports many of the claims enunciated by free trade proponents, but determining the actual strength of this relationship is far more complicated than they presume. This central argument, posed by Zoellick in the run-up to the U.S. Congress’s approval of CAFTA, is the genesis for this thesis – to what extent has CAFTA strengthened democracy in Central America? The Bush Administration employed the rhetoric of “democracy promotion” throughout the negotiation process. In January 2002, President George Bush announced that he would undertake formal trade talks with Central America, starting a multiyear negotiation process that culminated with the trade ministers of each country signing an agreement in 2004. Pursuant to the 2002 Trade Act that granted the President “fast track authority,” President Bush notified Congress before signing the trade agreement. His letter of intent to formally enter into a free trade agreement with Central America expresses this association again between trade liberalization and democratization: Our Central American partners have made dramatic progress in transitioning from countries wracked by civil war to peaceful, democratic societies. This agreement will write a new page of our history with Central America – one that depicts sustained engagement in support of democracy, peaceful regional integration, economic opportunity, and hope. 3 In this thesis, I will explore the accuracy of this rhetoric by evaluating the results of the Central American Free Trade Agreement on democratic political institutions in Central America. I will construct a methodology through which the influence of an international free trade agreement on domestic politics can be gauged. By considering 3 George W. Bush, Notification of intention to enter into a free trade agreement (FTA) with the governments of Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras and Nicaragua . Message to the House Committee on Ways and Means, 108 th Cong., 2d sess., H. Doc. 108-159 (February 20, 2004). 3 different dimensions of democracy, this procedure will be able to isolate the factors and elements in CAFTA that have left the greatest impact on democratization in this region. In doing so, it will contribute original research and analysis to investigate a subject untouched by current scholarship. Most of the literature on trade agreements tends to focus on economic and socio-economic factors, and the recency of CAFTA even further reduces the amount of published work on the topic. Based on the theories that link economic growth with democratization and the actual copious language in CAFTA devoted to institutional capacity building, I will hypothesize that CAFTA has had a generally positive effect on democracy in Central America. The remainder of this chapter is devoted to providing context to CAFTA by tracing its roots in the market capitalist reforms of the previous decade and the justifications articulated on both sides to sign such a transformational agreement. A general explanation of the textual content of CAFTA and the negotiation process will follow. Ultimately, this chapter serves as an introduction from which to launch into deeper analysis of the agreement’s political results. Free Trade Agreements Bilateral free trade agreements proliferated after World War II. Despite a coordinated effort to establish multilateral or global agreements through the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and later the World Trade Organization, many states pursued agreements with specific countries for more than economic reasons. Bilateral free trade agreements create preferences and disparities in the international 4 system while trying to achieve certain foreign policy objectives. They can distort trade if they divert the flow of goods, services and capital to less efficient producers than other countries outside the bilateral relationship. 4 However, countries often employ bilateral trade agreements as diplomatic tools for foreign policy interests, as they can be negotiated to reward partners with economic privileges and to underscore a strategic alliance. Developing countries in particular pursue preferential trade agreements to improve their access to foreign, developed markets and to integrate themselves into the new system of global competition. These agreements also help contribute to domestic growth by promoting foreign investment and expanding the internal goods market. 5 While in some instances trade alone accounts for small changes in the economy, its impact can multiply the effects of domestic fiscal or monetary policy. The economic rationale for free trade is well founded; in fact, support for trade is nearly ubiquitous among economists, no matter their
Recommended publications
  • Appendix to “Social Inequalities, Identity
    World Inequality Lab – Working Paper N° 2021/11 Social Inequalities, Identity, and the Structure of Political Cleavages in Argentina, Chile, Costa Rica, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru, 1952-2019 Appendix Oscar Barrera Ana Leiva Clara Martínez-Toledano Álvaro Zúñiga-Cordero March 2021 Social Inequalities, Identity, and the Structure of Political Cleavages in Argentina, Chile, Costa Rica, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru, 1952-2019 Oscar Barrera Ana Leiva Clara Martínez-Toledano Álvaro Zúñiga-Cordero† Appendix This document supplements our working paper “Social Inequalities, Identity, and the Structure of Political Cleavages in Argentina, Chile, Costa Rica, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru, 1952-2019”. It contains all appendix tables and figures. † Oscar Barrera (World Inequality Lab): [email protected]; Ana Leiva (University of Oslo, UiO): [email protected]; Clara Martínez-Toledano (Imperial College London, World Inequality Lab): [email protected]; Álvaro Zúñiga-Cordero (Paris School of Economics, World Inequality Lab): [email protected]. We are grateful to Lavih Abraham, Ronald Alfaro- Redondo, María Julia Blanco, Francesco Bogliacino, Nicolás DvosKin, Ignacio Flores, Gustavo García, Amory Gethin, Kyong Mazaro and Thomas PiKetty for their useful advice. Figure AA1 - Vote for Peronists by income decile in Argentina 100% 90% D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1995-99 2007-11 2015-19 Source: authors' computations using Argentinian post-electoral and political attitudes surveys. Note: the figure shows the share of votes received by the Peronist party by income decile. Figure AA2 - Vote for Peronists by income group in Argentina 90% 80% Bottom 50% Middle 40% Top 10% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1995-99 2007-11 2015-19 Source: authors' computations using Argentinian post-electoral and political attitudes surveys.
    [Show full text]
  • Types of Semi-Presidentialism and Party Competition Structures in Democracies: the Cases of Portugal and Peru Gerson Francisco J
    TYPES OF SEMI-PRESIDENTIALISM AND PARTY COMPETITION STRUCTURES IN DEMOCRACIES: THE CASES OF PORTUGAL AND PERU GERSON FRANCISCO JULCARIMA ALVAREZ Licentiate in Sociology, Universidad Nacional Mayor de San Marcos (Peru), 2005. A thesis submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF ARTS in POLITICAL SCIENCE Department of Political Science University of Lethbridge LETHBRIDGE, ALBERTA, CANADA © Gerson F. Julcarima Alvarez, 2020 TYPES OF SEMI-PRESIDENTIALISM AND PARTY COMPETITION STRUCTURES IN DEMOCRACIES: THE CASES OF PORTUGAL AND PERU GERSON FRANCISCO JULCARIMA ALVAREZ Date of Defence: November 16, 2020 Dr. A. Siaroff Professor Ph.D. Thesis Supervisor Dr. H. Jansen Professor Ph.D. Thesis Examination Committee Member Dr. J. von Heyking Professor Ph.D. Thesis Examination Committee Member Dr. Y. Belanger Professor Ph.D. Chair, Thesis Examination Committee ABSTRACT This thesis analyzes the influence that the semi-presidential form of government has on the degree of closure of party competition structures. Thus, using part of the axioms of the so-called Neo-Madisonian theory of party behavior and Mair's theoretical approach to party systems, the behavior of parties in government in Portugal (1976-2019) and Peru (1980-1991 and 2001-2019) is analyzed. The working hypotheses propose that the president-parliamentary form of government promotes a decrease in the degree of closure of party competition structures, whereas the premier- presidential form of government promotes either an increase or a decrease in the closure levels of said structures. The investigation results corroborate that apart from the system of government, the degree of closure depends on the combined effect of the following factors: whether the president's party controls Parliament, the concurrence or not of presidential and legislative elections, and whether the party competition is bipolar or multipolar.
    [Show full text]
  • Election Results in Argentina, 1995-2019 100
    Figure 15.1 - Election results in Argentina, 1995-2019 100 90 Peronists Non-Peronists 80 70 60 50 40 Share of votes (%) votes of Share 30 20 10 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Source: authors' computations using official election results (see wpid.world). Note: the figure shows the share of votes received by selected groups of Argentinian political parties in general elections between 1995 and 2019. Peronist parties received 48% of votes in the 2019 election. Anti-peronist parties are the Radical Civic Union (UCR), the Front for a Country in Solidarity (FREPASO), Acción por la Republica, Coalición Cívica ARI, Cambiemos, Frente de Izquierda, and Recrear. Figure 15.2 - The Peronist vote by income and education in Argentina, 1995-2019 20 Difference between (% of top 10% educated) and (% of bottom 90% educated) voting Peronist 15 10 Difference between (% of top 10% earners) and (% of bottom 90% earners) voting Peronist 5 0 -5 -10 -15 -20 -25 1995-99 2007-11 2015-19 Source: authors' computations using Argentinian post-electoral and political attitudes surveys (see wpid.world). Note: the figure shows the relative support of highest-educated and top-income voters for Peronists, after controlling for age, gender, religious affiliation, religiosity, employment status, marital status, occupation, rural-urban location, region, ethnicity, and perceived social class. In 2015-2019, top 10% income earners were 8 percentage points less likely to vote for Peronists. Table 15.1 - The structure of political cleavages in Argentina, 2015-2019 Share of votes received (%) Peronists Non-Peronists Education Primary 55% 45% Secondary 51% 49% Tertiary 38% 62% Income Bottom 50% 55% 45% Middle 40% 44% 56% Top 10% 34% 66% Occupation Public worker 39% 61% Private worker 34% 66% Entrepreneur 27% 73% Self-employed 38% 62% Subjective social class Working class 57% 43% Upper/Middle class 32% 68% Location Urban area 47% 53% Rural area 40% 60% Source: authors' computations using Argentinian political attitudes surveys (see wpid.world).
    [Show full text]
  • How Could the Covid-19 Crisis Impact the Future of Natural Resource Development in Latin America? – Strictly Confidential | 2
    How could the Covid- 19 crisis impact the future of natural resource development in Latin America? NEW RISKS AND OPPORTUNITIES IN AN EVOLVING POLITICAL, ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL LANDSCAPE MAY 2020 How could political, economic and social fallout from the Covid-19 crisis impact natural resource development in Latin America? This is one of a series of Critical Resource thought pieces exploring the impacts of the Covid-19 pandemic on the natural resource sector. This piece was informed by conversations with Critical Resource’s senior advisory network, which includes the foremost regional experts. Please get in touch if you would like to discuss how these issues affect your business. Summary of key findings Latin America is expected to be among the hardest hit of emerging markets and developing economies by the macroeconomic impact of the Covid-19 crisis. An April 2020 report published by the UN Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC) estimated that regional GDP will contract by over 5% in 2020. By comparison, GDP in sub-Saharan Africa and the Middle East and Central Asia region is forecast to contract by 1.6% and 2.8% respectively, while emerging and developing Asia will see 1% growth according to International Monetary Fund (IMF) projections. This will push an additional 30 million people across the ECLAC region into poverty and another 16 million into extreme poverty. The regional unemployment rate will likely hit 12%. The responses of governments to the socio-economic ramifications of the pandemic have been varied. Mexico’s President Andrés Manuel López Obrador (AMLO), an ostensible leftist, has embraced Thatcher- style austerity, eschewing new debt and stimulus spending.
    [Show full text]
  • Party Organizational Strength in New and Old Democracies
    Revista do CESOP http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1807-01912019251199 e-ISSN 1807-0191 Time after time: party organizational strength in new and old democracies Pedro Floriano Ribeiro1 Luis Locatelli2 The ‘time factor’ has not been systematically considered in cross-national studies on party organizations. Relying on the largest dataset to date on party organizations, namely the Political Party Database Project (PPDB), the article tests the impact of time as a two-level variable (duration of democracy and age of parties) on parties’ organizational strength in new and established democracies. We add original data from three Latin American countries to the nineteen countries covered by the first PPDB database (132 parties overall). The results suggest that parties in established democracies have less members and more money than those of newer democracies. Among the latter, the greater capacity for mass mobilization produces stronger parties—as in Latin America—compared to the Eastern European countries. The findings challenge the traditional view of the exceptional weakness of Latin American parties and point to the importance of time as a multilevel variable: besides the national context, the “ancestral” party origin in previous regimes have a large impact on organizational strength. Keywords: party organizations; political parties; party membership; party finance; Latin America Introduction3 Many studies in political science consider time as a relevant factor in the explanation of political processes, implicitly or explicitly, when adopting historical approaches. However, a few authors have systematically placed “politics in time” (Pierson, 2004). In this sense, the influence of time as a multilevel variable—duration of democracy and age of parties—on party membership, party funding, and organizational strength has not been systematically tested until today in cross-national comparative studies.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction Challenges of Party- Building in Latin America
    Cambridge University Press 978-1-107-14594-8 — Challenges of Party-Building in Latin America Edited by Steven Levitsky , James Loxton , Brandon Van Dyck , Jorge I. Domínguez Excerpt More Information 1 1 Introduction Challenges of Party- Building in Latin America Steven Levitsky, James Loxton, and Brandon Van Dyck Political parties are the basic building blocks of representative democracy. Political scientists have long argued that democracy is “unworkable” (Aldrich 1995: 3) or even “unthinkable” (Schattschneider 1942: 1) with- out them. Yet four decades into the third wave of democratization, parties remain weak in much of Latin America. Since 1990, major parties have weakened dramatically or collapsed altogether in Argentina, Bolivia, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Guatemala, Peru, and Venezuela.1 At the same time, most efforts to build new parties have failed. The regional landscape is littered with the corpses of new parties that either failed to take off or experienced brief electoral success but then izzled out or col- lapsed.2 Consequently, most Latin American party systems are more luid today than they were two decades ago. Of the six party systems scored as “institutionalized” in Mainwaring and Scully’s (1995) seminal work, one (Venezuela) has collapsed fully, three (Argentina, Colombia, Costa Rica) have collapsed partially, and a ifth (Chile) has arguably been “uprooted” (Luna and Altman 2011).3 Of the four party systems that Mainwaring and Scully (1995) classiied as “inchoate,” only Brazil’s has strengthened 1 On party weakness and party system collapse in Latin America, see Roberts and Wibbels (1999), Sánchez (2009), Morgan (2011), Seawright (2012), and Lupu (2014, 2016).
    [Show full text]
  • Country Briefing 2011
    DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR EXTERNAL POLICIES OF THE UNION POLICY DEPARTMENT Chile COUNTRY BRIEFING 2011 Abstract Sebastián Piñera took office on 11 March 2010 as the first President from the centre-right Coalition for Change (Coalición por el Cambio), ending 20 of years of government by the centre-left Concertación. His government enjoyed considerable popularity during its first months in office, but has since been met by large scale protests, particularly against its education policies, and approval ratings for the President have declined significantly. The protests point to an underlying frustration with fundamental aspects of the political system and the model of society which has characterised Chile since the transition to democracy. The coming months are likely to be decisive for the Government's chances of overcoming the current challenges and re-gain the political initiative. The economy has registered more than 25 years of almost uninterrupted, high growth rates and is expected to grow above the regional average also in 2011. While Chile has become a model for economic and social development, the country still faces challenges in reaching developed country status. Following a strategy of "open regionalism", Chile has developed an extensive network of free trade and other economic agreements with partners in Latin America, North America, Asia and Europe. Under the Association Agreement signed in 2002, Chile's relations with the EU have strengthened on many fronts in recent years. Chile will host next year's EU-Latin America and the Caribbean Summit. FOR EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT INTERNAL USE ONLY! DG EXPO/B/PolDep/Note/2011_241 October/2011 EN Policy Department DG External Policies This Country Briefing was requested by the European Parliament's Delegation to the Euro-Latin American Parliamentary Assembly.
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral System Design: the New International IDEA Handbook
    Electoral System Design: The New International IDEA Handbook Electoral System Design: The New International IDEA Handbook Andrew Reynolds Ben Reilly and Andrew Ellis With José Antonio Cheibub Karen Cox Dong Lisheng Jørgen Elklit Michael Gallagher Allen Hicken Carlos Huneeus Eugene Huskey Stina Larserud Vijay Patidar Nigel S. Roberts Richard Vengroff Jeffrey A. Weldon Handbook Series The International IDEA Handbook Series seeks to present comparative analysis, information and insights on a range of democratic institutions and processes. Handbooks are aimed primarily at policy makers, politicians, civil society actors and practitioners in the field. They are also of interest to academia, the democracy assistance community and other bodies. International IDEA publications are independent of specific national or political interests. Views expressed in this publication do not necessarily represent the views of International IDEA, its Board or its Council members. The map presented in this publication does not imply on the part of the Institute any judgement on the legal status of any territory or the endorsement of such boundaries, nor does the placement or size of any country or territory reflect the political view of the Institute. The map is created for this publication in order to add clarity to the text. © International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance 2005 Reprinted 2008 Applications for permission to reproduce or translate all or any part of this publication should be made to: Information Unit International IDEA SE -103 34 Stockholm Sweden International IDEA encourages dissemination of its work and will promptly respond to requests for permission to reproduce or translate its publications. Graphic design by: Magnus Alkmar Cover photos: © Pressens Bild Printed by: Trydells Tryckeri AB, Sweden ISBN: 91-85391-18-2 Foreword The Universal Declaration of Human Rights states that ‘everyone has the right to take part in the government of his country, directly or through freely chosen representatives’.
    [Show full text]
  • Social Inequalities, Identity, and the Structure of Political Cleavages in Argentina, Chile, Costa Rica, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru, 1952-2019
    World Inequality Lab – Working Paper N° 2021/11 Social Inequalities, Identity, and the Structure of Political Cleavages in Argentina, Chile, Costa Rica, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru, 1952-2019 Oscar Barrera Ana Leiva Clara Martínez-Toledano Álvaro Zúñiga-Cordero March 2021 Social Inequalities, Identity, and the Structure of Political Cleavages in Argentina, Chile, Costa Rica, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru, 1952-2019 Oscar Barrera, Ana Leiva, Clara Martínez-Toledano, Álvaro Zúñiga-Cordero * March 21, 2021 Abstract This paper combines electoral surveys to analyze the transformation of the struc- ture of political cleavages in Argentina, Chile, Costa Rica, Colombia, Mexico and Peru over the last decades. We document that Latin American countries are characterized by personalist leaderships (e.g., Fujimori in Peru, Uribe in Colombia) and important historical cleavages (e.g., anti vs. pro-PLN in Costa Rica) that blur class-based vot- ing patterns and have led in some cases to the emergence of competing pro-poor and ethnic-based competing coalitions (e.g., PRN-PLN in Costa Rica, Fujimori-Humala in Peru) over the last decades. The party systems of Costa Rica, Colombia and Peru have thus generated volatile political socio-economic cleavages, while in the more institu- tionalized party systems of Argentina, Brazil, Chile and Mexico they have been less volatile. *Oscar Barrera (World Inequality Lab): [email protected]; Ana Leiva (University of Oslo, UiO): [email protected]; Clara Martínez-Toledano (Imperial College London, World Inequality Lab): [email protected]; Álvaro Zúñiga-Cordero (Paris School of Economics, World Inequality Lab): [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Challenges of Party-Building in Latin America Steven Levitsky James
    CHAPTER 1 Introduction: Challenges of Party-Building in Latin America Steven Levitsky James Loxton Brandon Van Dyck Political parties are the pillars of representative democracy. Political scientists have long argued that democracy is “unworkable” (Aldrich 1995: 3) or even “unthinkable” (Schattschneider 1942: 1) without them. Yet four decades into the third wave of democratization, parties remain weak in much of Latin America. Since 1990, major parties have weakened dramatically or collapsed altogether in Argentina, Bolivia, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Guatemala, Peru, and Venezuela.1 At the same time, most efforts to build new parties have failed. The regional landscape is littered with the corpses of new parties that either failed to take off or experienced brief electoral success but then fizzled out or collapsed.2 Consequently, most Latin American party systems are more fluid today than they were two decades ago. Of the six party systems scored as “institutionalized” in Mainwaring and Scully’s (1995) seminal work, one (Venezuela) has collapsed fully, three (Argentina, Colombia, Costa Rica) have collapsed partially, and a fifth (Chile) has arguably been “uprooted” (Luna and Altman 2011).3 Of the four party systems that Mainwaring and Scully (1995) classified as “inchoate,” only Brazil’s has 1 On party weakness and party system collapse in Latin America, see Roberts and Wibbels (1999); Sánchez (2009); Morgan (2011); Seawright (2012); and Lupu (2014, 2016). 2 Examples include the United Left (IU), Liberty Movement, Independent Moralizing Front (FIM), and Union for Peru (UPP) in Peru; the Front for a Country in Solidarity (FREPASO), the Union of the Democratic Center (UCEDE), the Movement for Dignity and Independence (MODIN), and Action for the Republic in Argentina; the National Encounter Party (PEN) in Paraguay; the Guatemalan Republican Front (FRG), National Advancement Party (PAN), and Guatemalan National Revolutionary Unity (URNG) in Guatemala; and the M-19 Democratic Alliance (AD M-19) in Colombia.
    [Show full text]
  • The Poverty of the Progressivism and the Tragedy of Civil Society
    Hoover Press : Berkowitz/Progressive hberkp ch6 Mp_145 rev1 page 145 chapter six The Poverty of Progressivism and the Tragedy of Civil Society Jeffrey C. Isaac the uncertain fate of progressivism in America has been a recur- rent theme of public intellectual contention for well over a century. In that time, American politics has experienced recurrent waves of discontent, reform, and stasis. The reforms of the progressive era, the New Deal, and the Great Society can be thought of in terms of such cycles. That the United States has recently been experiencing a pro- longed stasis is a diagnosis shared by many commentators and artic- ulated cogently in E. J. Dionne Jr.’s acclaimed book on the subject— Why Americans Hate Politics—a book that, though over a decade old, is still frequently cited as having captured an enduring truth about our contemporary political life. Stasis, impasse, interregnum—for a variety of reasons, we are deeply disposed to believe that such con- ditions ought not to persist and cannot persist, that difficulties should and will be resolved in the course of time. Thus, Dionne’s diagnosis has given rise among many liberals to the notion that a progressive revival is in the cards. Following Walter Lippmann’s influential pro- This chapter draws on Isaac, The Poverty of Progressivism: The Future of American Democracy in a Time of Liberal Decline (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield, 2003). Hoover Press : Berkowitz/Progressive hberkp ch6 Mp_146 rev1 page 146 146 jeffrey c. isaac gressive era essay “Drift and Mastery,” these progressive liberals dis- cern drift, and they seek, and anticipate, a new form of mastery.
    [Show full text]
  • Online Appendix for “Don't Call It a Comeback
    Online Appendix for “Don’t Call It a Comeback: Autocratic Ruling Parties after Democratization” British Journal of Political Science Michael K. Miller The following pages display additional information and robustness checks referenced in the text. For convenience, I list a summary of these checks: • Table A1 lists all of the autocratic ruling parties in the sample, including the year of democratization, whether there was a violent break before transition, and the party’s out- comes within democracy. • Figure A1 displays the shift in the fraction of regimes with compulsory voting and inde- pendent judiciaries from before to after democratization, dividing by whether the parties acceded to democratization. As seen, parties that held power up to democratization were less likely to adopt both institutions, as they tended to make their continued dominance less likely. • Table A2 shows the main models, additionally controlling for modal regime types from the autocratic period (coded by Geddes et al. 2014). As shown in the paper, pure party regimes are strongly positive for success in democracy. More surprisingly, military parties (all regimes coded as military or military hybrids) are also positive, whereas personalist regimes (hybrids or pure) are negative for success. This captures the fact that personalist regimes tend to create relatively powerless, dependent parties that struggle to persist past the founding leader (Geddes 1999; Svolik 2012). • Table A3 shows the ordered logit models predicting Party Success (Table 2, Model 3), strat- ifying by modal regime type within autocracy. The four models in succession are limited to pure party regimes, not pure party regimes, military hybrids, and personalist hybrids.
    [Show full text]