Speaking Biology

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Speaking Biology 1 Speaking Biology. From Kant to Parsons…. And beyond? Script for Lecture May 19th 2008 FAU Erlangen Sociology Colloquium The audience of this event was comprised of MA and PhD graduate students and members of the faculty on the occasion of a summary lecture of the results of my work as a PhD candidate of the department, a relation to my current projects and their relation to my conception of the future of social science in general. Alexander Stingl Galvanistrasse 17 90459 Nuremburg Gemany +491607863333 [email protected] 2 1.Introduction to Speech First of all thank you for having me today, and thank you very much for agreeing to let me speak in English. I am obliged by protocol to mention the DAAD, because they made possible a trip to the Parsons archives at Harvard in Summer 2007. I most certainly would have to mention a great many names of people who have aided my research, but we probably would be running out of time. So I refer to the publication of the thesis, which will occur within a year’s time, with Edward Mellen Press it seems. The title of this presentation is “Speaking biology. From Kant to Parsons”. Since the general assumption is that I have, been doing my PhD work on Talcott Parsons, I must first make a very important confession: I have not. My interest was in the sources and the genealogy of his theoretical language in the history of science. I have found that the language that Parsons applied was the language of biology. Aside from that, allow me a provocation: I have also found out that Parsons seems inevitably quite and utterly boring. Now, before I elaborate – on both, the biology and the boredom – let me please explain in short why and how I became interested in Talcott Parsons and why and how he became actually the least of my worries. 2. Communication as Problem The problem I was thus toying with some five years ago when I was still pondering what I wanted to do not for my PhD, but my MA thesis – which took a very different turn in topic, but delivered the first inkling of my methodological approach; now this problem was the question or questions: 3 How, when and why did we begin to address the problem or the question of Communication and Mediality or Communicabilty in science and philosophy? While it certainly is always a nice sentiment to say with Alfred North Whitehead that all our pondering is but a footnote to Plato, I think it is equally clear that the way in which we today in the social sciences, in humanities and in the natural sciences and even in popular and public discourse speak about communication, information and media has a distinct “quality” to it. A quality not found in Plato, or Aquinas or Descartes. This “quality” has emerged at a certain place in time, under certain circumstances and with certain consequences. My research was and will continue to be guided by this question, because I remain convinced that this “quality” is the guiding thread, the thin red line that connects all of modern science. In the end, all those “turns” we have witnessed – the linguistic turn, the cultural turn, the iconic turn – they can all be reduced to the problem of communication, communicability and media. Naturally, I sought to begin my research, or let us say my adventure of communication with an archeology. And coming from the background of sociology I started at the uppermost layer of social theories. 4 3. Parsons/Habermas/Luhmann It is certainly no surprise then that I began with Niklas Luhmann’s media theory on the one hand and was looking at the aspect of the differences that his theory has with his opponent Jürgen Habermas in regard to communication and media. We can look at both men in a way that suggests that they are both different sides of the very same coin. But like two sides of a coin, they will forever face in exactly opposite directions and never one another. And they both share a blind spot, namely the body of the coin itself. In other words, from a less dogmatic point of view that allows for some contextualism Luhmann and Habermas offer two complementary accounts of social reality with the exception of their analogous blind spot. That blind spot is filled by a theory that accounts for a bridge between individual actors and collectivities as systems. A theory that accounts for the intermediary. That theory is the theory of Talcott Parsons, whose scholarship served both Luhmann and Habermas as an intellectual basis. At the same time, Parsons had enunciated the very first explicit sociological media and communication theory. In my archeology, Parsons became the natural next step downwards to finding a source of the problem of communication in science. A brief word on Habermas’ sources, which will receive a specific twist further down. There are many works and theories that Habermas draws from. But aside from Parsons, there is certainly one other that has received comparatively little attention by his interpreters. That is Hannah Arendt. I must thank Mark Gould for pointing this out to me and thereby confirming my suspicion on that. And please forgive me for leaving you in the dark for but a moment, why Hannah Arendt has a role to play in my reconstruction of Parsons’ language. 4. Archeology of Parsons: Back to Kant via Jaspers/Weber and Meiklejohn/Early Pragmatism (Emerson/James/Cooley) My archeology leads me through Parsons down a very interesting road. Parsons combines in a sense the best of both worlds: the Anglo-American and the Continental-European context. Very specifically, these worlds circumscribe the 5 interdisciplinary and international discourse of philosophy and physiology in the dialogue between Northeast Coast American and German scholarship in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century. In the United States, Parsons was immersed in a tradition that ran from Alexander Meiklejohn’s Kantianism back to the first generation of Pragmatism with Ralph Waldo Emerson and William James. In Germany, Parsons found a similar intellectual climate in Karl Jaspers’ class-room in Heidelberg, where he encountered the spirit of Max Weber and Emile Durkheim. There were a number of candidates, for who was the common source for these different strands of the intellectual discourse. Upon careful reconstruction this source was revealed to be Rudolf Hermann Lotze (1817 – 1881). Lotze was both a philosopher and a physiologist. My task was therefore set: If I wanted to find out, how the theoretical language of Talcott Parsons was made possible, then I had to investigate the discourse of philosophy and physiology. Going further back from Lotze it became clear to me that indeed the source for the conceptual frame of reference for this dialogue was Kantian philosophy. Turning from archeology to genealogical reconstruction, I would have to begin with Kant and Kantianism and via Lotze investigate the German and American branches of the discourse that became re-united in Parsons’ theoretical language. 5. Biology versus Logic My idea is thus the following: Talcott Parsons spoke a theoretical language that has become rare in the social sciences. He was one of the last scholars to be socialized, educated and immersed in an intellectual climate permeated by Kantianism and Lotzeanism “in spirit”, if you like. This way of talking, thinking and theorizing, this mode of thought, or as we can call it dialect of science, this epistemological vernacular of biology has been replaced by another language. A dialect of science, a vernacular that owes its conceptions to physicalist reductionism, naturalism, mathematics, logics and the idea of quantification. 6 The emergence of this dialect occurred towards the end of the nineteenth century with John Dewey, Bertrand Russell and G.E. Moore. It gained strength and with Quine and others became the dominant tongue of science, including social science. 6. Genius Accounts versus discursive accounts I am speaking of languages more than of people. And in this regard, let me briefly say something about previous interpretations of the work and biography of Talcott Parsons. Whenever I mention that I am generally interested in the work of Parsons the reaction is two-fold. One half of people simply roll their eyes thinking I am seeking to “re-introduce grand theory”, a type of theory that seeks to have an “abstract explanation for everything”. Well, I do not, nor does that interpretation do justice to what Parsons did. Plus, I am not interested in Parsons’ work and biography for the sake of Parsons but because he is an excellent example for a development in the history of science – the genealogy of the biological vernacular. The other half of the people, making usually the same mistake, give me the advise that Harald Wenzel has written the final word on Parsons, or that I can at best offer a footnote correction and that any attempt to link Parsons to Neo-Kantianism or whatever else must fail, because Harald Wenzel has shown that the sole interpretation left is to link Parsons to Alfred North Whitehead. Or so I been told by Wolfgang Schluchter and Hans Joas. Well, since I did not want to write a biography of Parsons or simply offer another reconstruction of his theoretical development, I do not feel obliged to accept that. But most interestingly, my work reveals that there would be another account of Parsons possible. The problem is the following: Nearly all previous attempts follow what we can call a “genius-account”. Parsons life and work is reconstructed in the course of the life of Talcott Parsons the genius, the man, the individual.
Recommended publications
  • Marx and Mendacity: Can There Be a Politics Without Hypocrisy?
    Analyse & Kritik 01+02/2015 (© Lucius & Lucius, Stuttgart) S. 521 Martin Jay Marx and Mendacity: Can There Be a Politics without Hypocrisy? Abstract: As demonstrated by Marx's erce defence of his integrity when anonymously accused of lying in l872, he was a principled believer in both personal honesty and the value of truth in politics. Whether understood as enabling an accurate, `scientic' depiction of the contradictions of the present society or a normative image of a truly just society to come, truth-telling was privileged by Marx over hypocrisy as a political virtue. Contemporary Marxists like Alain Badiou continue this tradition, arguing that revolutionary politics should be understood as a `truth procedure'. Drawing on the alternative position of political theorists such as Hannah Arendt, who distrusted the monologic and absolutist implications of a strong notion of truth in politics, this paper defends the role that hypocrisy and mendacity, understood in terms of lots of little lies rather than one big one, can play in a pluralist politics, in which, pace Marx, rhetoric, opinion and the clash of values resist being subsumed under a singular notion of the truth. 1. Introduction In l872, an anonymous attack was launched in the Berlin Concordia: Zeitschrift für die Arbeiterfrage against Karl Marx for having allegedly falsied a quotation from an 1863 parliamentary speech by the British Liberal politician, and future Prime Minister, William Gladstone in his own Inaugural Address to the First International in l864. The polemic was written, so it was later disclosed, by the eminent liberal political economist Lujo Brentano.1 Marx vigorously defended himself in a response published later that year in Der Volksstaat, launching a bitter debate that would drag on for two decades, involving Marx's daughter Eleanor, an obscure Cambridge don named Sedly Taylor, and even Gladstone himself, who backed Brentano's version.
    [Show full text]
  • September 2020
    Econ Journal Watch Scholarly Comments on Academic Economics Volume 17, Issue 2, September 2020 COMMENTS Comment on Sen, Karaca-Mandic, and Georgiou on Stay-at-Home Orders and COVID-19 Hospitalizations in Four States John A. Spry 270–278 Reply to John Spry on Stay-at-Home Orders and COVID-19 Hospitalizations Soumya Sen, Pinar Karaca-Mandic, and Archelle Georgiou 279–281 The Moving to Opportunity Experiment: What Do Heterogeneous Estimates of the Effect of Moving Imply About Causes? Robert Kaestner 282–298 Response to “The Moving to Opportunity Experiment: What Do Heterogeneous Estimates of the Effect of Moving Imply About Causes?” Raj Chetty, Nathaniel Hendren, and Lawrence F. Katz 299–304 Re-examination of the Theoretical and Historical Evidence Concerning Colonial New Jersey’s Paper Money, 1709–1775: A Further Comment on Grubb Ronald W. Michener 305–332 Recalculating Gravity: A Correction of Bergstrand’s 1985 Frictionless Case Nico Stoeckmann 333–337 ECONOMICS IN PRACTICE Gender, Race and Ethnicity, and Inequality Research in the American Economic Review and the American Economic Association’s Conference Papers Jeremy Horpedahl and Arnold Kling 338–349 INTELLECTUAL TYRANNY OF THE STATUS QUO Professional Scholarship from 1893 to 2020 on Adam Smith’s Views on School Funding: A Heterodox Examination Scott Drylie 350–391 CHARACTER ISSUES Republicans Need Not Apply: An Investigation of the American Economic Association Using Voter Registration and Political Contributions Mitchell Langbert 392–404 Liberalism in Brazil Lucas Berlanza 405–441 WATCHPAD Dispute on Method or Dispute on Institutional Context? Foreword to the Translation of Carl Menger’s “Errors of Historicism” Karen Horn and Stefan Kolev 442–459 The Errors of Historicism in German Economics Carl Menger 460–507 What 21st-Century Works Will Merit a Close Reading in 2050?: First Tranche of Responses Niclas Berggren, Arthur M.
    [Show full text]
  • The Interjurisdictional Migration of European Authors of Liberty, 1660 – 1961: a Quantitative Analysis1
    1 January 12, 2016 THE INTERJURISDICTIONAL MIGRATION OF EUROPEAN AUTHORS OF LIBERTY, 1660 – 1961: A QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS1 Niklas Potrafke2 Roland Vaubel3 Abstract Hume, Montesquieu and Kant were the first to suggest that the rise of liberty in Europe and the West has been due to political fragmentation and competition among rulers because the creative elites had the option of leaving the country in response to political repression. In this paper we estimate the extent to which emigrating authors of liberty actually reacted to such political and economic factors. We distinguish four types of repressive political events: restoration of an authoritarian monarchy, suppression of liberal protests, takeover by a totalitarian regime and occupation by a foreign repressive power. We test for additional explanations of emigration. Our sample of well-known authors of liberty includes 401 persons from twenty European countries in 1660 to 1961. Our logistic regressions yield the following main results. The repressive events did have significant and large effects on emigration with lags of up to five years. Emigration was also influenced by the author’s occupation and interjurisdictional income differentials. The probability of emigration was larger if the author was of middle age and lived in a small country but these effects were numerically small. The decision to emigrate was not affected by the author’s education. JEL classifications: F22, N33, Z18 _______________ 1 Acknowledgements: The authors thank Daniel Mannfeld, Felix Weber, Georg Arndt and Justina Fischer for tabulating the data and Justina Fischer and Jonathan Seiler for retrieving some of the data. We received helpful comments from Dennis Snower, David Stadelmann, Bengt-Arne Wickström and the participants of the World Public Choice Society Meetings 2012, the Silvaplana Workshop on Political Economy 2013, the CESifo Political Economy Workshop 2013 and two anonymous referees.
    [Show full text]
  • Prices and Production and Other Works: F.A
    PRICES AND PRODUCTION AND OTHER WORKS: F.A. HAYEK ON MONEY, THE BUSINESS CYCLE, AND THE GOLD STANDARD The Ludwig von Mises Institute thanks Mr. Toby Baxendale for his magnificent sponsorship of the publication of this book. Prices and Production and Other Works: F.A. Hayek on Money, the Business Cycle, and the Gold Standard Preface by Danny Quah Foreword by Toby Baxendale Edited with an Introduction by Joseph T. Salerno Ludwig von Mises Institute Auburn, Alabama Copyright 2008 Ludwig von Mises Institute Hayek photograph on back cover courtesy of The Cambridgeshire Collection, Cambridge Central Library. For information, write the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 518 West Magnolia Avenue, Auburn, Alabama 36832, U.S.A. mises.org. ISBN: 978-1-933550-22-0 Contents Preface by Danny Quah . vii Foreword by Toby Baxendale . .xi Introduction by Joseph T.Salerno . .xv Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle (1933) . 1 Preface by F.A. Hayek . 3 1. The Problem of the Trade Cycle . 9 2. Non-Monetary Theories of the Trade Cycle . 23 3. Monetary Theories of the Trade Cycle . 51 4. The Fundamental Cause of Cyclical Fluctuations . 73 5. Unsettled Problems of Trade Cycle Theory . 105 The “Paradox” of Saving (1929, 1931) . 131 Prices and Production (1931, 1935) . 189 Preface to the Second Edition . 191 Lecture 1: Theories of the Influence of Money on Prices . 197 Lecture 2: The Conditions of Equilibrium between the Production of Consumers’ Goods and the Production of Producers’ Goods . 223 Lecture 3: The Working of the Price Mechanism in the Course of the Credit Cycle . 253 Appendix to Lecture 3: A Note on the History of the Doctrines Developed in the Preceding Lecture .
    [Show full text]
  • ACTA UNIVERSITATIS UPSALIENSIS Skrifter Utgivna Av Statsvetenskapliga Föreningen I Uppsala 196
    ACTA UNIVERSITATIS UPSALIENSIS Skrifter utgivna av Statsvetenskapliga föreningen i Uppsala 196 Svante Nycander The History of Western Liberalism Front cover portraits: Thomas Jefferson, Baruch de Spinoza, Adam Smith, Alexis de Tocqueville, Oliver Wendell Holmes, Joseph Schumpeter, Woodrow Wilson, Niccoló Machiavelli, Karl Staaff, John Stuart Mill, François-Marie Arouet dit Voltaire, Mary Wollstonecraft, John Locke, Jean-Jacques Rousseau, Immanuel Kant, Ludwig Joseph Brentano, John Dewey, Wilhelm von Humboldt, Charles-Louis de Secondat Montesquieu, Ayn Rand © Svante Nycander 2016 English translation: Peter Mayers Published in Swedish as Liberalismens idéhistoria. Frihet och modernitet © Svante Nycander and SNS Förlag 2009 Second edition 2013 © Svante Nycander and Studentlitteratur ISSN 0346-7538 ISBN 978-91-554-9569-5 Printed in Sweden by TMG Tabergs AB, 2016 Contents Preface ....................................................................................................... 11 1. Concepts of Freedom before the French Revolution .............. 13 Rights and Liberties under Feudalism and Absolutism ......................... 14 New Ways of Thinking in the Renaissance ........................................... 16 Calvinism and Civil Society .................................................................. 18 Reason as a Gift from God .................................................................... 21 The First Philosopher to Be Both Liberal and Democratic ................... 23 Political Models during the Enlightenment ..........................................
    [Show full text]
  • Franz Brentano Und Carl Menger
    Die philosophisch-psychologischen Grundlagen der Österreichischen Wertlehre: Franz Brentano und Carl Menger Inaugural-Dissertation zur Erlangung der Doktorwürde der Philosophischen Fakultät III der Julius-Maximilians-Universität Würzburg vorgelegt von Andrea Reimherr aus Veitshöchheim Würzburg 2005 1 Erstgutachter: Prof. Dr. W. Baumgartner Zweitgutachter: Prof. Dr. H.-G. Monissen Tag des Kolloquiums:17.2.2006 2 Inhaltsverzeichnis Einleitung 6 1. Methode und Wissenschaftstheorie 9 1.1. Brentanos Methode und Wissenschaftstheorie 10 1.1.1. Zeitgeschichtlicher Hintergrund und Quellen 11 1.1.1.1. Die Philosophie im 19. Jahrhundert 11 1.1.1.2. Gibt es eine „Österreichische Philosophie“? 13 1.1.1.3. Die Geschichte der Philosophie 18 1.1.2. Wissenschaftsauffassung 28 1.1.2.1. Die Habilitationsthesen 28 1.1.2.2. Die Psychologie als Wissenschaft 32 1.1.2.3. Psychologie als Basis der Geisteswissenschaften 38 1.1.3. Methode und Theorie 47 1.1.3.1. Induktion 48 1.1.3.2. Gesetze a priori 58 1.1.3.3. Teil-Ganzes-Lehre 59 1.2. Mengers Methode und Wissenschaftstheorie 62 1.2.1.Einflüsse 63 1.2.1.1. Menger und Aristoteles 63 1.2.1.2. Vorläufer der subjektiven Theorie 72 1.2.1.3. Die Historische Schule und der Methodenstreit 78 1.2.2. Wissenschaftstheorie 81 1.2.2.1. Aufgabe und Einteilung der Politischen Ökonomie 81 1.2.2.2. Die theoretischen Wissenschaften 87 1.2.2.3. Das Verhältnis der politischen Ökonomie zu den anderen Wissenschaften 97 1.2.3. Methodische Aspekte und Besonderheiten 107 1.2.3.1. Die Werturteilsfreiheit der Wissenschaften 108 1.2.3.2.
    [Show full text]
  • Early Notes in Folders
    Marshall Library of Economics Marshall Papers Section 4 Early notes in folders Identity code Marshall 4 Description level 3 Content Notes in hard covers Summary This section comprises Marshall's early notes. Although largely undated, most can be attributed to before 1890. With the exception of the earliest general notebook and a section of notes on [Johann Heinrich] Von Thunen all are enclosed within hard cover folders. There is no evidence of how Marshall originally ordered these, but he clearly re-used them and there is evidence that some of the original series is missing. The old Marshall Library box numbers showed no logical ordering, thus as no date order can be established they have been rearranged in alphabetical order using Marshall's titles. The untitled general notebook and loose notes on Von Thunen are placed at the beginning of the series. One untitled folder has been put under Economic History. Identity code Marshall 4/1 Previous number Marshall LBB 5 Description level 4 Record creation Person Role Writer Name Marshall, Alfred Date c1867-1869 Document form Record type Notes Specific type Academic notes Acquisition Summary Loose note dated 24.5.1938 with this item states Mary Marshall lent it to Mr [Claude] Guillebaud. He was to give it to the Marshall Library when he had finished with it. Content Summary An early note or commonplace book consisting of eleven sections of folded paper, including some embossed with arms of Cambridge Union Society, apparently hand stitched at later date into hard cover. Those sections with headings are meditanda, T.W., memoranda for Fleming, poetry, terse sayings, mathematical, similes metaphors etc.
    [Show full text]
  • JÖRN LEONHARD Progressive Politics and the Dilemma of Reform
    Sonderdrucke aus der Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg JÖRN LEONHARD Progressive Politics and the Dilemma of Reform German and American Liberalism in Comparison, 1880-1920 Originalbeitrag erschienen in: Maurizio Vaudagna (Hrsg.):The place of Europe in American history : twentieth-century perspectives. Torino: OTTO Ed., 2007, S. 115-132 7 nova americana in english edited by Maurizio Vaudagna ce of Europe in American History: Twentieth-Century Perspectives Tiziano Bonazzi, Darla Frezza, Claudio Zambianchi, Giuliana Muscio, Giuliana Gemelli, Antonella Cardellicchio, Jam Leonhard, Raffaella Baritono, Marco Mariano, Mario Del Pero, Jennifer Klein, Elisabetta Vezzosi, Maurizio Vaudagna, Manuel Plana, Alessandra Lorini, Simone Cinotto OTTBEDITORE THE PLACE OF EUROPE IN AMERICAN HISTORY: TWENTIETH- CENTURY PERSPECTIVES edited by M. Vaudagna OTTBEDITORE The Place of Europe in American History: Twentieth-Century Perspectives Edited by M. Vaudagna Collana Nova Americana in English Comitato scientifico: Marco Bellingeri, Marcell° Carmagnani, Maurizio Vaudagna Prima edizione gennaio 2007 ©2007, OTTO editore – Torino [email protected] http://wvvw.otto.to.it ISBN 88-95285-02-6 ISBN 978-88-95285-02-3 E vietata la riproduzione, anche parziale, con qualsiasi mezzo effettuato, compresa la fotocopia, anche ad use interno o didattico, non autorizzato. PROGRESSIVE POLITICS AND THE DILEMMA OF REFORM: GERMAN AND AMERICAN LIBERALISM IN COMPARISON, 1880-1920 JORN LEONHARD I. INTRODUCTION: LIBERALISM AS AN EXHAUSTED POLITICAL CONCEPT AFTER 1945 Speaking at a conference of German liberals in December 1948, which led to the foundation of the Free Democratic Party (FDP) in West Germany, Theodor Heuss, later the president of the Federal Republic, asked his audience whether the label "liberal" could still be used to identify a political party that regarded itself as part of the tradi- tion of political liberalism.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimizing the German Workforce: Labor Administration from Bismarck to the Economic Miracle
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Meskill, David Book — Published Version Optimizing the German workforce: Labor administration from Bismarck to the economic miracle Monographs in German History, No. 31 Provided in Cooperation with: Berghahn Books Suggested Citation: Meskill, David (2018) : Optimizing the German workforce: Labor administration from Bismarck to the economic miracle, Monographs in German History, No. 31, ISBN 978-1-78533-664-5, Berghahn Books, New York, NY, http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/j.ctt9qdd9p This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/182434 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ www.econstor.eu This open access library edition is supported by Knowledge Unlatched.
    [Show full text]
  • German Social Science, Meiji Conservatism, and the Peculiarities of Japanese History*
    German Social Science, Meiji Conservatism, and the Peculiarities of Japanese History* erik grimmer-solem Wesleyan University The German Origins of Japanese Exceptionalism Sir Rutherford Alcock, the first British minister in Tokyo, remarked in 1863 that Japan was a land of paradoxes impelled “by some occult law . in a perfectly opposite direction and reversed order.” 1 This view of Japan, borrowed directly from Herodotus’s description of the ancient Egyptians, has had a long career among foreign observers of Japan and drives the notion of Japanese exceptionalism to this day. Yet as histori- ans of Japan know, the Western notion of Japanese peculiarity is newer than is often realized. Engelbert Kaempfer (1651–1716), a German doctor in Dutch service in Japan and author of the celebrated History and Description of Japan (1777–1779), admired Japan as familiar, simi- lar to Europe, and, in some respects, a civilization ahead of the West.2 * An early version of this article was presented at the University of Chicago workshop “Japan in the World, the World in Japan” in May 2001, and I gratefully acknowledge the helpful suggestions of Tetsuo Najita. A revised draft was then presented at the German Studies Association conference in Washington, DC, in October 2001. I thank Dieter Buse and Nancy Wingfield for their useful comments. Bill Johnston, Donald Levine, Bruce Mas- ters, Devin Pendas, and David Titus gave valuable feedback on later drafts, and Michael Eastwood and Miwa Katsumata provided assistance translating Japanese sources. 1 Quoted in Endymion Wilkinson, Japan versus the West: Image and Reality (London: Penguin, 1991), p.
    [Show full text]
  • Max Weber's Vision of Economics by Rkbard Swedberg Department of Sociology, Stockholm University S-10691 Stockholm, Sweden [email protected]
    Program for the Sflldy of Germany and Europe Working Paper Series *7.1 Max Weber's Vision of Economics by Rkbard Swedberg Department of Sociology, Stockholm University S-10691 Stockholm, Sweden [email protected] Abstract This paper argues that Max Weber's work in economics is very interesting but has been unduly neglected. More precisely, Weber had a vision of economics as a very broad topic, to which not only economic theory but also eco­ nomic history and economic sociology could contribute. Weber's term for this type of economics was Sozial­ oekonomik or social economics. Weber himself made contributions to all three parts of social economics-espe­ clally to economic sociology (he was one of the founders of Wirtscha{tssoziologie) but also to economic history and Oess so) to economic theory. August 6, 1996 MAX WEBER'S VISION OF ECONOMICS Weber deserves to be seen as one of this century's great economists, if we mean by economics a social science that attempts to explain economic behavior. For a variety of reasons, however, little attention has been paid to Weber's work in economics. The major reason for this is probably that neoclassical economics has gained monopoly on what is seen as "economics," and this does not include the broad and historically inspired approach that Weber advocated. Another reason is the somewhat paradoxical fact that while Weber himself-as well as his contemporaries-viewed him as an economist, posterity insists that he is basically a sociologist.1 Talcott Parsons, for example, early cast Weber for an Ameri, can audience as a sociologist, and according to the current Who's Who in Economics, We, ber was not an economist but "one of the major figures in sociology.
    [Show full text]
  • Zur Lage Der Soziologie
    © F. Enke Verlag Stuttgart Zeitschrift für Soziologie, Jg. 6, Heft 1, Januar 1977, S. 91118 Zur Lage der Soziologie Max Weber: A Bibliographical Essay* GuentherlRoth DepartmenYof Sociology, University of Washington, Seattle Max Weber: ein bibliographischer Bericht Inhalt: Der Beitrag gibt einen Überblick über die Rezeption der Soziologie MAX WEBERS in der seit 1960 erschie­ nenen Literatur. Angesichts der Breite und Spezialisierung dieser Literatur werden sechs Bereiche der WEBER-Rezep- tion unterschieden und nacheinander behandelt: (1) WEBERS vergleichende Studien und historische Typologien, (2) seine methodologischen und erkenntnistheoretischen Beiträge, (3) seine Stellung als Theoretiker des „bürokrati­ schen Zeitalters“, (4) seine allgemeinpolitischen und hochschulpolitischen Auffassungen, (5) die marxistische Aus­ einandersetzung mit WEBER sowie Vergleiche zwischen dem Weberschen und dem Marxschen Ansatz und schließlich (6 ) die Biographie MAX WEBERS im Kontext der zeitgenössischen Geistesgeschichte. Abstract: The article attempts an overview of the reception of MAX WEBERS’s sociology in the literature published since 1960. Considering the wide scope and specialization of this literature, six dimensions in the WEBER-reception are dis­ tinguished and taken up in turn: ( 1) WEBER’s comparative studies and historical typologies; (2) his basic methodolo­ gical and epistemological contributions; (3) his place among theorists of “the bureaucratic age” ; (4) his general and his academic politics; (5) the Marxist struggle against WEBER, but also scholarly comparisons of WEBER and MARX; and finally (6 ) WEBER’s biography in the context of the intellectual history of his and our time. Much scholarship and partisanship continue to the relations between ideologies and social revolve around the works and impact of MAX structures, and as a methodologist concerned WEBER and KARL MARX.
    [Show full text]