Zur Lage Der Soziologie

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Zur Lage Der Soziologie © F. Enke Verlag Stuttgart Zeitschrift für Soziologie, Jg. 6, Heft 1, Januar 1977, S. 91118 Zur Lage der Soziologie Max Weber: A Bibliographical Essay* GuentherlRoth DepartmenYof Sociology, University of Washington, Seattle Max Weber: ein bibliographischer Bericht Inhalt: Der Beitrag gibt einen Überblick über die Rezeption der Soziologie MAX WEBERS in der seit 1960 erschie­ nenen Literatur. Angesichts der Breite und Spezialisierung dieser Literatur werden sechs Bereiche der WEBER-Rezep- tion unterschieden und nacheinander behandelt: (1) WEBERS vergleichende Studien und historische Typologien, (2) seine methodologischen und erkenntnistheoretischen Beiträge, (3) seine Stellung als Theoretiker des „bürokrati­ schen Zeitalters“, (4) seine allgemeinpolitischen und hochschulpolitischen Auffassungen, (5) die marxistische Aus­ einandersetzung mit WEBER sowie Vergleiche zwischen dem Weberschen und dem Marxschen Ansatz und schließlich (6 ) die Biographie MAX WEBERS im Kontext der zeitgenössischen Geistesgeschichte. Abstract: The article attempts an overview of the reception of MAX WEBERS’s sociology in the literature published since 1960. Considering the wide scope and specialization of this literature, six dimensions in the WEBER-reception are dis­ tinguished and taken up in turn: ( 1) WEBER’s comparative studies and historical typologies; (2) his basic methodolo­ gical and epistemological contributions; (3) his place among theorists of “the bureaucratic age” ; (4) his general and his academic politics; (5) the Marxist struggle against WEBER, but also scholarly comparisons of WEBER and MARX; and finally (6 ) WEBER’s biography in the context of the intellectual history of his and our time. Much scholarship and partisanship continue to the relations between ideologies and social revolve around the works and impact of MAX structures, and as a methodologist concerned WEBER and KARL MARX. In recent years the with the relations of methods, values and facts, level of DÜRKHEIM scholarship has improved, WEBER must remain controversial in the battles, and there is a steady stream of studies on indivi­ inside and outside the academy, about the pur­ dual writers and various isms in the history of pose and consequences of social knowledge for modern social thought. However, nothing compa­ polity and society — empirical study is never an res to the sheer magnitude of the concern with innocent or neutral undertaking. MARX and WEBER. This is not at all surprising in MARX’s case, since political ideologies linked In would like to distinguish three stages or phases with his name legitimate the governments of a in the American and English WEBER reception. large part of the globe and since in many other During the first stage The Protestant Ethic and countries variants of Marxism are kept alive by the Spirit o f Capitalism (1904/5), in TALCOTT radicalism — by the ineradicable revolutionary PARSONS’ translation of 1930 (WEBER 1958), sentiments of alienated intellectuals - in the face became widely assigned reading on American of persistent inequalities and inequities. WEBER campuses, but without reference to WEBER’s however, never created an ism in politics or scho­ comparative studies of the world religions. With larship, not even the political decisionism or the the growing interest in large-scale organization methodological individualism that have sometimes and stratification in the wake of the Second been attributed to him. What, then, maintains so World War WEBER’s notions of bureaucracy and much interest in WEBER’s work? Primarily its of class and status were widely diffused, but intrinsic scholarly superiority, as a comparative without their systematic location in his typolo­ approach to macrosociological investigation, over gies. GERTH and MILLS’ 1946 selections from reductionist Marxism and ahistorical structural WEBER (WEBER 1946), contrasting bureaucra­ functionalism. However, there are also political cy and charisma, became very influential in shap­ and epistemological reasons for WEBER’s conti­ ing an image of WEBER’s work, and PARSONS’ nued importance: As a researcher probing into translation of the difficult-to-read categories of Part I of Economy and Society (published under the misleading title The Theory o f Social and * Revised version of an introduction to a re-issue of R. BENDIX, Max Weber. Berkeley: University of Economic Organization in 1947) made available California Press, 1977. By permission. that segment in splended isolation from the main 92 Zeitschrift für Soziologie, Jg. 6, Heft 1, Januar 1977, S. 91 -1 1 8 body (WEBER 1947). Moreover, PARSONS’ distinction from WEBER’s acute sense for the “creative misinterpretation” of WEBER in The ambiguities and paradoxes of western rationa­ Structure o f Social Action (PARSONS 1937) and lism. subsequent writings as one of his forerunners and a systems theorist manque received much atten­ Both BENDIX and PARSONS shared prominent­ tion after 1950 with the ascendancy of his struc­ ly in the second stage of the WEBER reception, tural functionalism1. which was reached reciprocally with the revival of comparative studies in the fifties. Whereas In 1960 REINHARD BENDIX countered this many development studies followed a “Weberian- Parsonian interpretation by putting before the Parsonian” approach emphasizing the predomi­ reader the historical substance of WEBER’s com­ nance of values in social systems old and new, parative sociology of politics, law and religion BENDIX’s intellectual portrait showed the reader on the level of its own intentions (BENDIX the intricate ways in which WEBER related ideas I960)2. PARSONS had at first treated WEBER and material and ideal interests. Moreover, BEN­ as one predecessor among others of his own DIX facilitated the study of development issues theory of voluntarist social action and later by clearly relating The Protestant Ethic to WE­ juxtaposed to him his own social systems analy­ BER’s studies on the world religions, and by em­ sis, which provided a framework for studying the bedding bureaucracy and charisma in their pro­ relations of social actors irrespective of time and per typological matrix within the Sociology of place. From his systems perspective WEBER’s de­ Domination in Economy and Society. He also finitions of various kinds of social action and his edited, with a group of students, the first reader historical typologies appeared atomistic. Yet WE­ in comparative political sociology, State and So­ BER too presented, in the first chapter of Econo­ ciety (BENDIX et al. 1968), which was based on my and Society, a general, “ahistorical” sociolo­ a Weberian conception of historical sociology in gy of the social group, which moved logically contrast to the functionalist approach with its from individual social action through various evolutionary overtones3. forms of social relationships to the concerted actions in the organization ( Verband) with its le­ The third stage of dealing with WEBER began gitimate domination. For WEBER these definitions with the centenary commemoration of his birth provided the basis for an historical typology at the Heidelberg meetings of the German Socio­ within which the distinctive and historically uni­ logical Association in 19644. The event turned que course of western rationalism could be stu­ out to be the beginning of the great onslaught on died. By contrast, PARSONS came to relate his WEBER as arch representative of liberal or bour­ systems approach to a neo-evolutionism that per­ geois social science, an onslaught carried forth ceived the “progress” from tradition to moderni­ by a new political generation without any memo­ ty as a process of almost unilinear structural dif­ ries of the Second World War and hence without ferentiation and value transformation - in sharp any personal yardsticks for comparing the pre­ sent with the past. 1 On PARSONS’ WEBER interpretation, see also J. It is important to understand that the three COHEN, L. HAZELRIGG, W. POPE (1975a) , and stages are not exclusive sequences: The Prote­ the subsequent exchange: PARSONS (1975) and COHEN, HAZELRIGG, POPE (1975b). On the stant Ethic is still frequently interpreted in isola­ first stage of the WEBER reception, see ROTH and tion; the selections from the very popular GERTH BENDIX (1959). On the notion of “creative misin­ and MILLS edition are still widely used as the terpretation”, see my essay on “Value-Neutrality major reading assignment on WEBER; the defini­ in Germany and the United States”, in BENDIX and ROTH, 1971: 35, and on its effects in the con­ text of the gradual WEBER reception, see also H. STUART HUGHES, 1975: 31ff. 3 For the contrast between Weberian historical socio­ logy and structural functionalism in State and Society 2 For overviews and expositions of WEBER’s work see RANDALL COLLINS (1968). as a whole since 1960, see RAYMOND ARON (1967); LEWIS A. COSER (1971); JULIAN FREUND 4 See OTTO STAMMER (1971), especially HERBERT (1969) . There are two readers: DENNIS WRONG MARCUSE, “Industrialization and Capitalism”, pp. (1970) ; DIRK KÄSLER (1972). 133-151 in this volume. Zur Lage der Soziologie 93 tions from Part I of Economy and Society are scholarly citations still refer to the various frag­ still ritually quoted out of theoretical and histo­ mentary selections rather than to the complete rical context. However, the comparative approach edition.) My introduction to Economy and So­ is now well-established, although funding for for­ ciety (see WEBER 1968: xvii-civ) was written eign area studies has declined severely. Finally,
Recommended publications
  • Introduction to the Thematic Dossier | Economy and Society: Politics, Practices, Agents, and Institutions
    Configurações Revista Ciências Sociais 26 | 2020 Economy and Society: politics, practices, agents, and institutions Introduction to the Thematic Dossier | Economy and Society: politics, practices, agents, and institutions Rodrigo da Costa Dominguez, Lisbeth Rodrigues, Jeremy Land e Jari Eloranta Edição electrónica URL: http://journals.openedition.org/configuracoes/10367 DOI: 10.4000/configuracoes.10367 ISSN: 2182-7419 Editora Centro de Investigação em Ciências Sociais Edição impressa Paginação: 7-17 ISSN: 1646-5075 Refêrencia eletrónica Rodrigo da Costa Dominguez, Lisbeth Rodrigues, Jeremy Land e Jari Eloranta, « Introduction to the Thematic Dossier | Economy and Society: politics, practices, agents, and institutions », Configurações [Online], 26 | 2020, posto online no dia 16 dezembro 2020, consultado o 18 dezembro 2020. URL : http://journals.openedition.org/configuracoes/10367 ; DOI : https://doi.org/10.4000/configuracoes. 10367 © CICS Dominguez, Rodrigo da Costa; Rodrigues, Lisbeth; Land, Jeremy; Eloranta, Jari - Introduction to the Thematic Dossier: Economy and Society: politics, practices, agents, and institutions. Configurações, vol. 26, 2020, pp. 7-17. Introduction to the Thematic Dossier | Economy and Society: politics, practices, agents, and institutions RODRIGO DA COSTA DOMINGUEZ* CICS – University of Minho LISBETH RODRIGUES** CSG-ISEG – University of Lisbon JEREMY LAND*** University of Jyväskylä and University of Helsinki JARI ELORANTA**** University of Helsínki Interplay of the Economy and Society The economic orientation or the concept of “economic action” (Wirtschaften) intro- duced by Max Weber in his essays on the sociology of economics addresses the issue of satisfying desires for “utilities” (Nutzleistungen) as an exercise of an actor’s control over a certain resource. This resource is, originally, driven and directed towards eco- nomic ends.
    [Show full text]
  • Max Weber's Disciples
    STXXXX10.1177/0735275117740402Sociological TheoryJoosse 740402research-article2017 Original Article Sociological Theory 2017, Vol. 35(4) 334 –358 Max Weber’s Disciples: © American Sociological Association 2017 https://doi.org/10.1177/0735275117740402DOI: 10.1177/0735275117740402 Theorizing the Charismatic st.sagepub.com Aristocracy Paul Joosse1 Abstract While several studies have explored the interactional dynamics of charismatic power, most have neglected the role of what Weber termed the charismatic aristocracy. This article revives the classical concept to respond to contemporary calls for performative, follower- centric approaches to charisma. Specifically, the charismatic aristocracy is placed at the center of an analysis of a reiterative moment in charismatization: when influential followers generate content for the emerging charismatic persona. In these germinal moments, the dialogical nature of charisma is most clear, precisely because it is then that charismatic leaders often are not themselves confident in their status and can be found responding to instructional cues—indeed following the lead—of those positioning themselves as obsequious followers. Drawing on 10 years of observations, multistage interviews, and media collections, I provide an interactionist account of the charismatic emergence of John de Ruiter, leader of a successful new religious movement. I conclude by tabling a model that conceives of the charismatic aristocracy as an important fulcrum for expectation, affectation, and recognition in charismatic interactions. Keywords charisma, Max Weber, symbolic interactionism, cultural sociology, relational sociology, power When Hans Gerth and C. Wright Mills introduced Weber’s concept of charisma to English readers in 1946, they did so with some major reservations. Weber’s emphasis on the charis- matic leader, we were warned, is a continuation of a “philosophy of history” which, after Carlyle’s Heroes and Hero Worship [1841], influenced a great deal of nineteenth-century history writing.
    [Show full text]
  • A New Look at Max Weber and His Anglo-German Family Connections1
    P1: JLS International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society [ijps] PH231-474840-07 October 28, 2003 17:46 Style file version Nov. 19th, 1999 International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society, Vol. 17, No. 2, Winter 2003 (C 2003) II. Review Essay How Well Do We Know Max Weber After All? A New Look at Max Weber and His Anglo-German Family Connections1 Lutz Kaelber2 Guenther Roth’s study places Max Weber in an intricate network of ties among members of his lineage. This paper presents core findings of Roth’s analysis of Weber’s family relations, discusses the validity of Roth’s core theses and some of the implications of his analysis for Weber as a person and scholar, and addresses how Roth’s book may influence future approaches to Weber’s sociology. KEY WORDS: Max Weber; history of sociology; classical sociology; German history; Guenther Roth. “How well do we know Max Weber?”—When the late Friedrich H. Tenbruck (1975) raised this question almost thirty years ago, he had Weber’s scholarship in mind. The analysis of Weber’s oeuvre and the debate over it, fueled by a steady trickle of contributions of the Max Weber Gesamtaus- gabe, has not abated since. Thanks to the Gesamtausgabe’s superbly edited volumes, we now know more about Weber the scholar than ever before, even though the edition’s combination of exorbitant pricing and limitation to German-language editions has slowed its international reception. Tenbruck’s question might be applied to Weber’s biography as well. Here, too, the Gesamtausgabe, particularly with the edition of his personal letters, has been a valuable tool for research.1 Yet the fact remains that what we know about Weber the person derives to a significant extent from 1Review essay of Guenther Roth, Max Webers deutsch-englische Familiengeschichte, 1800–1950.
    [Show full text]
  • Marx and Mendacity: Can There Be a Politics Without Hypocrisy?
    Analyse & Kritik 01+02/2015 (© Lucius & Lucius, Stuttgart) S. 521 Martin Jay Marx and Mendacity: Can There Be a Politics without Hypocrisy? Abstract: As demonstrated by Marx's erce defence of his integrity when anonymously accused of lying in l872, he was a principled believer in both personal honesty and the value of truth in politics. Whether understood as enabling an accurate, `scientic' depiction of the contradictions of the present society or a normative image of a truly just society to come, truth-telling was privileged by Marx over hypocrisy as a political virtue. Contemporary Marxists like Alain Badiou continue this tradition, arguing that revolutionary politics should be understood as a `truth procedure'. Drawing on the alternative position of political theorists such as Hannah Arendt, who distrusted the monologic and absolutist implications of a strong notion of truth in politics, this paper defends the role that hypocrisy and mendacity, understood in terms of lots of little lies rather than one big one, can play in a pluralist politics, in which, pace Marx, rhetoric, opinion and the clash of values resist being subsumed under a singular notion of the truth. 1. Introduction In l872, an anonymous attack was launched in the Berlin Concordia: Zeitschrift für die Arbeiterfrage against Karl Marx for having allegedly falsied a quotation from an 1863 parliamentary speech by the British Liberal politician, and future Prime Minister, William Gladstone in his own Inaugural Address to the First International in l864. The polemic was written, so it was later disclosed, by the eminent liberal political economist Lujo Brentano.1 Marx vigorously defended himself in a response published later that year in Der Volksstaat, launching a bitter debate that would drag on for two decades, involving Marx's daughter Eleanor, an obscure Cambridge don named Sedly Taylor, and even Gladstone himself, who backed Brentano's version.
    [Show full text]
  • UNIVERSITY of CALIFORNIA Santa Barbara the Disenchantment of The
    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Santa Barbara The Disenchantment of the World and Ontological Wonder A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree Doctor of Philosophy in Religious Studies by Martin Becker Lorca Committee in charge: Professor Thomas A. Carlson, Chair Professor Elliot R. Wolfson Professor Andrew Norris June 2019 The dissertation of Martin Becker Lorca is approved. ____________________________________________ Elliot R. Wolfson ____________________________________________ Andrew Norris ____________________________________________ Thomas A. Carlson, Committee Chair March 2019 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS This dissertation could not have been finished without the help of family and friends, I would like them thank here: In thank my classmates at UCSB, Dusty Hoesly, Michael Kinsella, Matt Robertson and Sohaira Siddiqui, for their intellectual companionship and friendship. For making possible the practice of reflection as a communal enterprise, I thank my friends: Eva Braunstein, Chris Morales, Samantha Kang, Lucas Wright, and Tim Snediker, who gave life to the philosophical group at Santa Barbara. With deep gratitude, for his precious help in editing and in giving essential feedback, I thank my friend Garrett Baer, with whom, in our philosophical walks at Lake Los Carneros (Goleta)—embodying the old peripatetic tradition—let ourselves to philosophize freely and sincerely. For crucial help editing this work, I thank Garrett Baer, Ryan Kelley, Allice Haynes, Kali Handelman, Kevin Johnston, Alexander Cohen, and Arnulf Becker Lorca. Much of the interpretation of “the nothing” comes from long and deep conversations with Franco Bertossa and Ricardo Pulido. I thank them for raising the question of Being, the one that touches “to the point where our entire nature is so shaken that is will never again be the same” (Heidegger, What is Called Thinking?, 179).
    [Show full text]
  • The Classics in Economic Sociology
    I The Classics in Economic Sociology There exists a rich and colorful tradition of economic sociology, which roughly began around the turn of the twentieth century and continues till today. This tradition has generated a number of helpful concepts and ideas as well as interesting research results, which this and the following chapter seek to briefly present and set in perspective. Economic soci- ology has peaked twice since its birth: in 1890–1920, with the founders of sociology (who were all interested in and wrote on the economy), and today, from the early 1980s and onward. (For the history of economic sociology, see Swedberg 1987, 1997; Gislain and Steiner 1995). A small number of important works in economic sociology—by economists as well as sociologists—was produced during the time between these two periods, from 1920 to the mid-1980s. The main thesis of this chapter, and of this book as a whole, is as follows: in order to produce a powerful economic sociology we have to combine the analysis of economic interests with an analysis of social relations. From this perspective, institutions can be understood as dis- tinct configurations of interests and social relations, which are typically of such importance that they are enforced by law. Many of the classic works in economic sociology, as I shall also try to show, hold a similar view of the need to use the concept of interest in analyzing the economy. Since my suggestion about the need to combine interests and social relations deviates from the existing paradigm in economic sociology, a few words will be said in the next section about the concept of interest as it has been used in social theory.
    [Show full text]
  • September 2020
    Econ Journal Watch Scholarly Comments on Academic Economics Volume 17, Issue 2, September 2020 COMMENTS Comment on Sen, Karaca-Mandic, and Georgiou on Stay-at-Home Orders and COVID-19 Hospitalizations in Four States John A. Spry 270–278 Reply to John Spry on Stay-at-Home Orders and COVID-19 Hospitalizations Soumya Sen, Pinar Karaca-Mandic, and Archelle Georgiou 279–281 The Moving to Opportunity Experiment: What Do Heterogeneous Estimates of the Effect of Moving Imply About Causes? Robert Kaestner 282–298 Response to “The Moving to Opportunity Experiment: What Do Heterogeneous Estimates of the Effect of Moving Imply About Causes?” Raj Chetty, Nathaniel Hendren, and Lawrence F. Katz 299–304 Re-examination of the Theoretical and Historical Evidence Concerning Colonial New Jersey’s Paper Money, 1709–1775: A Further Comment on Grubb Ronald W. Michener 305–332 Recalculating Gravity: A Correction of Bergstrand’s 1985 Frictionless Case Nico Stoeckmann 333–337 ECONOMICS IN PRACTICE Gender, Race and Ethnicity, and Inequality Research in the American Economic Review and the American Economic Association’s Conference Papers Jeremy Horpedahl and Arnold Kling 338–349 INTELLECTUAL TYRANNY OF THE STATUS QUO Professional Scholarship from 1893 to 2020 on Adam Smith’s Views on School Funding: A Heterodox Examination Scott Drylie 350–391 CHARACTER ISSUES Republicans Need Not Apply: An Investigation of the American Economic Association Using Voter Registration and Political Contributions Mitchell Langbert 392–404 Liberalism in Brazil Lucas Berlanza 405–441 WATCHPAD Dispute on Method or Dispute on Institutional Context? Foreword to the Translation of Carl Menger’s “Errors of Historicism” Karen Horn and Stefan Kolev 442–459 The Errors of Historicism in German Economics Carl Menger 460–507 What 21st-Century Works Will Merit a Close Reading in 2050?: First Tranche of Responses Niclas Berggren, Arthur M.
    [Show full text]
  • The Interjurisdictional Migration of European Authors of Liberty, 1660 – 1961: a Quantitative Analysis1
    1 January 12, 2016 THE INTERJURISDICTIONAL MIGRATION OF EUROPEAN AUTHORS OF LIBERTY, 1660 – 1961: A QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS1 Niklas Potrafke2 Roland Vaubel3 Abstract Hume, Montesquieu and Kant were the first to suggest that the rise of liberty in Europe and the West has been due to political fragmentation and competition among rulers because the creative elites had the option of leaving the country in response to political repression. In this paper we estimate the extent to which emigrating authors of liberty actually reacted to such political and economic factors. We distinguish four types of repressive political events: restoration of an authoritarian monarchy, suppression of liberal protests, takeover by a totalitarian regime and occupation by a foreign repressive power. We test for additional explanations of emigration. Our sample of well-known authors of liberty includes 401 persons from twenty European countries in 1660 to 1961. Our logistic regressions yield the following main results. The repressive events did have significant and large effects on emigration with lags of up to five years. Emigration was also influenced by the author’s occupation and interjurisdictional income differentials. The probability of emigration was larger if the author was of middle age and lived in a small country but these effects were numerically small. The decision to emigrate was not affected by the author’s education. JEL classifications: F22, N33, Z18 _______________ 1 Acknowledgements: The authors thank Daniel Mannfeld, Felix Weber, Georg Arndt and Justina Fischer for tabulating the data and Justina Fischer and Jonathan Seiler for retrieving some of the data. We received helpful comments from Dennis Snower, David Stadelmann, Bengt-Arne Wickström and the participants of the World Public Choice Society Meetings 2012, the Silvaplana Workshop on Political Economy 2013, the CESifo Political Economy Workshop 2013 and two anonymous referees.
    [Show full text]
  • The Disenchantment of Logically Formal Legal Rationality, Or Max Weber’S Sociology in the Genealogy of the Contemporary Mode of Western Legal Thought
    The Disenchantment of Logically Formal Legal Rationality, or Max Weber’s Sociology in the Genealogy of the Contemporary Mode of Western Legal Thought Duncan Kennedy* Introduction Max Weber began his sociology of law with a description of the then present of Western legal thought, along with a brief summary of its pre- vious stages. This appreciation begins with a summary description of the Western legal thought of Weber’s time, as it looks from our present one hundred years later, emphasizing the contrast between the mainstream of his time, now called Classical Legal Thought, and its critics in the “social current.” Part II presents Weber’s sociology of law, comparing and con- trasting his approach with that of the social current. The most striking thing about Weber’s sociology of law, from the perspective of legal the- ory a century after he wrote, is his ambivalent endorsement of legal for- malism. This entailed rejection of the social current’s critique, a critique that is close to universally accepted today. In Part III, I explain Weber’s attitude toward legal formalism as motivated by the internal require- ments of his theory of domination, in which, after the demise of all ear- lier modes of legitimation, the Iron Cage of modernity is held together by bureaucrats defined by their adherence to that mode of legal reasoning. Part IV argues that Weber’s approach was inconsistent with the irration- alist and decisionist strands in his own theory of modernity, a theory that helps in understanding the current situation of legal thought, if we take the un-Weberian step of applying it to legal formalism.
    [Show full text]
  • Prices and Production and Other Works: F.A
    PRICES AND PRODUCTION AND OTHER WORKS: F.A. HAYEK ON MONEY, THE BUSINESS CYCLE, AND THE GOLD STANDARD The Ludwig von Mises Institute thanks Mr. Toby Baxendale for his magnificent sponsorship of the publication of this book. Prices and Production and Other Works: F.A. Hayek on Money, the Business Cycle, and the Gold Standard Preface by Danny Quah Foreword by Toby Baxendale Edited with an Introduction by Joseph T. Salerno Ludwig von Mises Institute Auburn, Alabama Copyright 2008 Ludwig von Mises Institute Hayek photograph on back cover courtesy of The Cambridgeshire Collection, Cambridge Central Library. For information, write the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 518 West Magnolia Avenue, Auburn, Alabama 36832, U.S.A. mises.org. ISBN: 978-1-933550-22-0 Contents Preface by Danny Quah . vii Foreword by Toby Baxendale . .xi Introduction by Joseph T.Salerno . .xv Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle (1933) . 1 Preface by F.A. Hayek . 3 1. The Problem of the Trade Cycle . 9 2. Non-Monetary Theories of the Trade Cycle . 23 3. Monetary Theories of the Trade Cycle . 51 4. The Fundamental Cause of Cyclical Fluctuations . 73 5. Unsettled Problems of Trade Cycle Theory . 105 The “Paradox” of Saving (1929, 1931) . 131 Prices and Production (1931, 1935) . 189 Preface to the Second Edition . 191 Lecture 1: Theories of the Influence of Money on Prices . 197 Lecture 2: The Conditions of Equilibrium between the Production of Consumers’ Goods and the Production of Producers’ Goods . 223 Lecture 3: The Working of the Price Mechanism in the Course of the Credit Cycle . 253 Appendix to Lecture 3: A Note on the History of the Doctrines Developed in the Preceding Lecture .
    [Show full text]
  • ACTA UNIVERSITATIS UPSALIENSIS Skrifter Utgivna Av Statsvetenskapliga Föreningen I Uppsala 196
    ACTA UNIVERSITATIS UPSALIENSIS Skrifter utgivna av Statsvetenskapliga föreningen i Uppsala 196 Svante Nycander The History of Western Liberalism Front cover portraits: Thomas Jefferson, Baruch de Spinoza, Adam Smith, Alexis de Tocqueville, Oliver Wendell Holmes, Joseph Schumpeter, Woodrow Wilson, Niccoló Machiavelli, Karl Staaff, John Stuart Mill, François-Marie Arouet dit Voltaire, Mary Wollstonecraft, John Locke, Jean-Jacques Rousseau, Immanuel Kant, Ludwig Joseph Brentano, John Dewey, Wilhelm von Humboldt, Charles-Louis de Secondat Montesquieu, Ayn Rand © Svante Nycander 2016 English translation: Peter Mayers Published in Swedish as Liberalismens idéhistoria. Frihet och modernitet © Svante Nycander and SNS Förlag 2009 Second edition 2013 © Svante Nycander and Studentlitteratur ISSN 0346-7538 ISBN 978-91-554-9569-5 Printed in Sweden by TMG Tabergs AB, 2016 Contents Preface ....................................................................................................... 11 1. Concepts of Freedom before the French Revolution .............. 13 Rights and Liberties under Feudalism and Absolutism ......................... 14 New Ways of Thinking in the Renaissance ........................................... 16 Calvinism and Civil Society .................................................................. 18 Reason as a Gift from God .................................................................... 21 The First Philosopher to Be Both Liberal and Democratic ................... 23 Political Models during the Enlightenment ..........................................
    [Show full text]
  • Franz Brentano Und Carl Menger
    Die philosophisch-psychologischen Grundlagen der Österreichischen Wertlehre: Franz Brentano und Carl Menger Inaugural-Dissertation zur Erlangung der Doktorwürde der Philosophischen Fakultät III der Julius-Maximilians-Universität Würzburg vorgelegt von Andrea Reimherr aus Veitshöchheim Würzburg 2005 1 Erstgutachter: Prof. Dr. W. Baumgartner Zweitgutachter: Prof. Dr. H.-G. Monissen Tag des Kolloquiums:17.2.2006 2 Inhaltsverzeichnis Einleitung 6 1. Methode und Wissenschaftstheorie 9 1.1. Brentanos Methode und Wissenschaftstheorie 10 1.1.1. Zeitgeschichtlicher Hintergrund und Quellen 11 1.1.1.1. Die Philosophie im 19. Jahrhundert 11 1.1.1.2. Gibt es eine „Österreichische Philosophie“? 13 1.1.1.3. Die Geschichte der Philosophie 18 1.1.2. Wissenschaftsauffassung 28 1.1.2.1. Die Habilitationsthesen 28 1.1.2.2. Die Psychologie als Wissenschaft 32 1.1.2.3. Psychologie als Basis der Geisteswissenschaften 38 1.1.3. Methode und Theorie 47 1.1.3.1. Induktion 48 1.1.3.2. Gesetze a priori 58 1.1.3.3. Teil-Ganzes-Lehre 59 1.2. Mengers Methode und Wissenschaftstheorie 62 1.2.1.Einflüsse 63 1.2.1.1. Menger und Aristoteles 63 1.2.1.2. Vorläufer der subjektiven Theorie 72 1.2.1.3. Die Historische Schule und der Methodenstreit 78 1.2.2. Wissenschaftstheorie 81 1.2.2.1. Aufgabe und Einteilung der Politischen Ökonomie 81 1.2.2.2. Die theoretischen Wissenschaften 87 1.2.2.3. Das Verhältnis der politischen Ökonomie zu den anderen Wissenschaften 97 1.2.3. Methodische Aspekte und Besonderheiten 107 1.2.3.1. Die Werturteilsfreiheit der Wissenschaften 108 1.2.3.2.
    [Show full text]