Prices and Production and Other Works: F.A
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
PRICES AND PRODUCTION AND OTHER WORKS: F.A. HAYEK ON MONEY, THE BUSINESS CYCLE, AND THE GOLD STANDARD The Ludwig von Mises Institute thanks Mr. Toby Baxendale for his magnificent sponsorship of the publication of this book. Prices and Production and Other Works: F.A. Hayek on Money, the Business Cycle, and the Gold Standard Preface by Danny Quah Foreword by Toby Baxendale Edited with an Introduction by Joseph T. Salerno Ludwig von Mises Institute Auburn, Alabama Copyright 2008 Ludwig von Mises Institute Hayek photograph on back cover courtesy of The Cambridgeshire Collection, Cambridge Central Library. For information, write the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 518 West Magnolia Avenue, Auburn, Alabama 36832, U.S.A. mises.org. ISBN: 978-1-933550-22-0 Contents Preface by Danny Quah . vii Foreword by Toby Baxendale . .xi Introduction by Joseph T.Salerno . .xv Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle (1933) . 1 Preface by F.A. Hayek . 3 1. The Problem of the Trade Cycle . 9 2. Non-Monetary Theories of the Trade Cycle . 23 3. Monetary Theories of the Trade Cycle . 51 4. The Fundamental Cause of Cyclical Fluctuations . 73 5. Unsettled Problems of Trade Cycle Theory . 105 The “Paradox” of Saving (1929, 1931) . 131 Prices and Production (1931, 1935) . 189 Preface to the Second Edition . 191 Lecture 1: Theories of the Influence of Money on Prices . 197 Lecture 2: The Conditions of Equilibrium between the Production of Consumers’ Goods and the Production of Producers’ Goods . 223 Lecture 3: The Working of the Price Mechanism in the Course of the Credit Cycle . 253 Appendix to Lecture 3: A Note on the History of the Doctrines Developed in the Preceding Lecture . 277 Lecture 4: The Case For and Against an “Elastic” Currency . 283 Appendix to Lecture 4: Some Supplementary Remarks on “Neutral Money” . 301 Capital and Industrial Fluctuations: A Reply to a Criticism . 305 v vi Prices and Production and Other Works Monetary Nationalism and International Stability (1937) . 331 Preface . 333 Lecture 1: National Monetary Systems . 337 Lecture 2: The Function and Mechanism of International Flows of Money . 351 Lecture 3: Independent Currencies . 367 Lecture 4: International Capital Movements . 385 Lecture 5: The Problems of a Really International Standard . 403 Reflections on the Pure Theory of Money of Mr. J.M. Keynes (1931, 1932) . 423 The Mythology of Capital (1936) . 487 I. Professor Knight’s Argument . 489 II. On Some Current Misconceptions . 495 III. Professor Knight’s Criticism Based on a Misunderstanding . 501 IV. His Own Position Prevents Him from Giving Any Explanation of How the Limitation of Capital Restricts the Increase of Output . 505 V. An Erroneous Assertion Following from His Fundamental Position: The Value of Capital Goods When Interest Disappears . 514 VI. Problems of Capital and “Perfect Foresight” . 517 Investment That Raises the Demand for Capital (1937) . 521 The Relative Significance of the Amount of Investment and of the Form That It Takes . 524 “Completing Investments” and the Rate of Interest . 526 Causes of an Urgent Demand for Funds for Completing Investments . 528 Bibliography . 531 Index . 547 Preface conomics never labels anything any more. Well, more accu- Erately, it does; only now it hardly ever uses labels formed from people’s names. In part, this is due to the smorgasbord approach to ideas taken by economics. Like many other academic disciplines, economics ruthlessly mixes and matches, customizes and adapts, rips and mashes the most penetrating insights, the most appropriate mod- els from all different sources, applying them to whichever eco- nomic problem is currently being addressed. In those circum- stances the message gets through to the practitioner economist that it is more useful to know an idea itself, and how to apply and modify it, than to peer into its provenance or to understand how the originator of that idea thought about three or five other sub- stantively different problems. In mathematics, this idea is taken even further. The most powerful and insightful practitioners are those whose names become so merged with a discovery that their surnames get low- ercased whenever mentioned with the matching idea.The proper name disappears as anything distinctive, and instead becomes just vocabulary. In economics, perhaps partly at fault as well, those intellec- tual leaders in the profession now, whose names are most likely to deserve such adjectivization, themselves eschew debates that vii viii Prices and Production and Other Works might lead to such identification. Thus, for instance, the same economists who argued that the money supply is the fundamen- tal cause of inflation also argued for the importance of fiscal bal- ance and discipline in determining, again, inflation. The same economists whose work set the agenda for decades of business cycles research were also the ones who provided calculations showing that such economic fluctuations are fundamentally insignificant for society’s well-being overall. Mainstream eco- nomics pragmatically emphasizes debate about results, not about methodologies. So, certainly, individuals’ names can be bolted onto specific curves, econometric estimators, statistical tests, probability inequalities, interest-rate rules, and mathematical equations and models—but not onto entire systems or ways of thinking. The case of Friedrich Hayek, however, provides a rare exam- ple of a consistent body of work in the profession where such identification might be justified. Living the frenetic cultured existence of the mid-1900s—as political events forever changed the global geography of intellec- tual endeavor—Hayek became one of the twentieth century’s most influential economists and political philosophers. In eco- nomics he made profound and enduring contributions in areas as diverse as monetary and business cycle theory, the social organi- zation of dispersed knowledge, and the spontaneous emergence of order. But while seemingly varied, all these research questions were attacked by Hayek from a consistent, unified perspective. It is this single perspective then that potentially can be most iden- tified with Hayek. However, matters are complex from the opposite direction as well. Hayek viewed business cycles as having their initiating impulse of central bank credit overexpansion and their propagation mecha- nism of misallocation of capital across short- and long-term invest- ments.This is echoed in many modern technical treatments—both empirical and theoretical—of economic fluctuations. Preface ix Hayek saw the price system as the single leading mechanism by which limited local knowledge and actions can be efficiently aggregated into optimal social outcomes—through human action, not human design. This is, in one guise, simply the fun- damental theorem of welfare economics. But combining these two Hayek propositions—that on business cycles and that on local knowledge—also recovers critical ingredients of Robert Lucas’s rational expectations reconciliation of the short-run Phillips curve with monetary neutrality. Being clear about the distinction between monetary and credit overexpansion brings to the fore modern econometric investigations of the different roles of money and credit over business cycles. Exploring the full implications of whether markets perfectly aggregate imperfect information is precisely the idea underlying a rich seam of tech- nical research in microeconomics. Hayek’s description of order emerging spontaneously, in a self-organized way, from out of seeming chaos—the application of which to economics he coined the term catallaxy—turns out to be the defining characteristic of the science of complex adap- tive systems. It is an idea that sees profound application not only, again, in the fundamental theorems of welfare economics, but in areas as varied as Alan Turing’s explanation for the black and white speckled patterns on cattle, hypotheses on the emergence of peaks and troughs in economic activity across not just time but geographical space, and indeed is embedded deeply in specula- tions on the origins of life itself, in research on computational and mathematical biology. While pre-Thatcher, pre-Reagan mainstream politics and social policy worldwide might have grown interventionist with fine-tuning and demand management, and thus distant from Hayek’s intellectual position, by contrast, many mainstream economists and social scientists never really left Hayek. Instead, the great majority have absorbed his ideas so implicitly that the name has been not just lowercased but left unmentioned alto- gether. Hayek’s ideas are seamlessly intertwined with so much of x Prices and Production and Other Works modern academic economics that, indeed, practically everyone in the profession has come into contact with or uses Hayekian insights. What this does for intellectual history is likely unfortu- nate. But, on the other hand, it might be the ultimate accolade for Friedrich Hayek, an intellectual concerned with ideas and knowledge, and their use for good in society. I congratulate the Ludwig von Mises Institute for bringing back into print Hayek’s writings on business cycles. This collec- tion will be a critical touchstone for future thinking in the area. Danny Quah London School of Economics March 2007 Foreword t is with great pleasure that I fully support the reproduction of Ithese works. I congratulate Lew Rockwell and his team for having the foresight to do this in honor of Hayek, one of the most important economists of the last century. An old Polish soldier who had settled in London after World War II exposed me to the teachings of Hayek when I was sixteen years old. He had fought the Nazi machine as a member of the Royal Air Force. An equally nasty totalitarian force subsequently occupied his country: the Stalinist Communists. After the war, he settled in my neighborhood, and I got talking to him. He was adamant that I read Hayek as Hayek could show me all that was wrong with totalitarianism. The book offered was The Road to Serfdom. I did. I dedicate this reproduction to all those people who have suffered untold hardship under various totalitarian regimes.