Downloaded from Elgar Online at 09/26/2021 06:52:48AM Via Free Access 382 Elgar Companion to Hayekian Economics

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Downloaded from Elgar Online at 09/26/2021 06:52:48AM Via Free Access 382 Elgar Companion to Hayekian Economics Index 1980s Unemployment and the Unions Banking Policy and the Price Level (book) 314, 320, 321, 322 (book) 101 1984 (novel) 372 Barber, Benjamin 263 Bardhan, Pranab 289, 290 ‘acceleration of time’ 345, 346 Barry, Norman 7–9, 240 accounting prices 65, 248, 249 Bartley III, W.W. 116 A Century of Bank Rate (book) 30 Bellante, Don 23 ‘adverbial rules’ 210 Bentham, Jeremy 17–18 aggregate demand 13, 96–7, 98, 106, Berle, Adolf 281 326, 327–8 Beveridge, William 110 American Steel Foundries v. Tri-City Blaug, Mark 59–60, 62 Central Trades Council (1921) 337 ‘blind faith’ 365–6 ‘Anglo-American approach’ 72 Böhm-Bawark, Eugen von anti-rationalistic approachj 210–11 and Austrian school 141 Aréna, Richard 28, 31 and capital theory 23, 25, 166, 168, Armentano, Dominick 335–6 182–3 Arrow–Debreu model 249 influence on Hayek 12, 37, 58 Austrian Institute for Business Cycle as ‘master’ 147 Research 1, 47–8, 144–5 and Mises 140 Austrian school of economics Buchanan, James 255, 344, 350 and capital theory 25, 26, 47–9, Burke, Edmund 225 57–8, 67, 73–4, 91–2, 166–7, business (trade) cycles 173–4 and capital theory 25, 49, 71, 82–4, and competition policy 36–7 86 hostility towards 35 and central-bank policy 132–4 intellectual paths of 11 and change in Hayek’s economic and Lachmann 165–6 theory 110 and macroeconomics 13–14 and consumption goods 19–21, 23 and market processes 130–31 and credit expansion 133–4 and methodological individualism 1 and ‘cumulative process’ 19 and methodological subjectivism 154 empirical weakness of theory 30 and Mises 138–41 and enhanced factor incomes 19 and monetary policy 346, 357 and enterprise 21 and neoclassicism 197 and entrepreneurship 20 and price system 60 and equilibrium analysis 196–7 and socialist calculation debate and full employment 21 278–9, 281–2, 286, 288, 290 and general equilibrium theory 5 and spontaneous order 226, 231, and Hayek’s relationship with 240, 242 Lachmann 166 and subjectivism 1 and Hayek’s rivalry with Keynes 1 Backhouse, Roger 35, 36 and industrial fluctuations 51, 53, bank lending 19, 21, 26, 27–8 57–8 381 Roger W. Garrison and Norman Barry - 9780857931115 Downloaded from Elgar Online at 09/26/2021 06:52:48AM via free access 382 Elgar companion to Hayekian economics and inflation acceleration illustrative examples 72–3, 74, 75, mechanism 26–7 77, 84–6 and interest rates 20–21, 30, 82–3, and industrial fluctuations 50–51, 84, 87–8, 132–4 57–8 and intertemporal equilibrium 95–6 and institutions 185–7 and investment 21, 31, 82, 83–4 and interest rates 82–3, 84, 87–8 and macroeconomics 21 and investment 81–2, 83–4, 85–6, and Mises 140 88 and monetary disequilibrium 83–4 and Keynesian economics 71 and monetary expansion 19–20, and macroeconomics 23, 71, 92 82–4, 86–7 and microeconomics 71–2, 92 and monetary theory 51, 53 and monetary expansion 82–4, 85–6 and new classicism 30, 32 and monetary policy 67 and price levels 22–3 and neoclassicism 58, 72, 79–80, 92 and quantity theory 22–3 and ‘period of production’ 24–5, 48, and renewed interest in Hayek 19 49, 48, 76, 103–5, 182 and Ricardo Effect 20, 21–2, 30 and price expectations 86–8 and static equilibrium 106–7 and price system 118 and technological change 132, 133 and Prices and Production 5, 17, and unions 328 23–4, 48, 49 and productivity of capital 75–7 Cairnes, J.E. 29 and Ricardo Effect 52–3 Caldwell, Bruce 2, 28, 29, 173 and river analogy 80–81 Capital and Growth (book) 18 and ‘roundaboutness’ of production Capital and its Structure (book) 167 process 48, 49, 55, 58, 72, 73–4, capital heterogeneity 169–73, 179–82, 75–7, 82, 84, 182–3 183 and stock of capital 78–9, 168–9 capital theory and ‘structure of production’ 48–9, ‘Anglo-American approach’ 72–3 52–3, 54–5, 58, 67, 75, 78 and Austrian school 47–9, 57–8, 67, and technological change 183–4 73–4, 91–2, 166–7, 173–4 and ‘triangles’ 25–6, 48, 103–4, 118 and business cycles 25, 49, 71, 82–4, and unemployment 105 86 and University of Chicago 5, 17 and capital heterogeneity 169–73, capitalism 183 and capital theory 74–5, 78, 79–80, and capitalism 74–5, 78, 79–80, 81, 81, 83, 92 83, 92 and commodity production 296–7 and complexity 173, 175–9, 182–7 and Keynes 94, 96 and consumption goods 48–9, 72–3, and Marxian socialism 261–2 74–5, 77, 80–81, 83–4, 85–6, and Mises 149, 153 88–90 and price system 64–6 and credit extension 24 and socialist calculation debate critiques of 23–4, 26, 57–8 280–82, 283, 289–90, 291 and disequilibrium 174–6, 185–6 Capitalism and Freedom (book) 116 and division of labour 48, 76, 183 ‘catallaxy’ 66, 67, 211–12 and entrepreneurship 48, 74–5, 79, central planning 81, 92 and collapse of Soviet empire 367 and expectations 166, 167–9, 172 and commodity production 296–7 and Hayek’s influence on Lachmann and comparative institutional 166, 167–9, 174–6 analysis 215–16 Roger W. Garrison and Norman Barry - 9780857931115 Downloaded from Elgar Online at 09/26/2021 06:52:48AM via free access Index ­383 and economic calculation 59, 248, and business cycles 19–21, 23 252 and capital theory 48–9, 72–3, 74–5, and international trade 301–4 77, 80–81, 83–4, 85–6, 88–90 and Mises 4, 33 and productivity 183 and monetary policy 355 consumption spending 126–7 and price system 63–4, 65, 150–51 Cottrell, Allin 290 and socialism 142, 149–151 credit expansion 19, 24, 53, 133–4, 140, and socialist calculation debate 172, 328 282–3, 287, 291 Critical Essays in Monetary Theory and spontaneous order 231–2, 237 (book) 18 and unions 332 crystal formation 227–8, 236 central-bank policy 4, 132–4 cultural evolution 212–13, 233, 237–8, ceteris paribus assumption 3 239, 240–41, 257–8 Chamberlin, Edward 281 ‘Choice in currency’ (pamphlet) 111 Darwin, Charles 225 ‘circulating capital’ 49, 74 Darwinism 178, 225, 240, 257 Clayton Act (1914) 317 Davidson, David 27 Coase, Ronald 252 de Jasay, Anthony 345, 349, 350, 356, Cockett, Richard 37 365 Cockshot, W. Paul 290 ‘Denationalization of money’ codetermination 315, 339 (pamphlet) 111 ‘co-efficient of money transactions’ 55 Deutscher, Patrick 34 coercive unionism 314, 315–19, 322–31, Dicey, A.V. 317 337 Dickinson, H.D. 283 collective bargaining 314, 315, 318–19, Director, Aaron 17 331–2, 338 discoordination of markets 322–3 Collectivist Economic Planning (book) distributive principle 270–74 151, 247 division of labour 48, 54, 56, 76, Committee on Social Thought 2, 6, 17 149–50, 183, 198 communitarian socialism 262–5 Dostaler, Gilles 35 comparative institutional analysis Duplex Printing v. Deering (1921) 317 215–18 durable capital 72–3 competition policy 36–7 Durbin, Evan 17 competitive markets dynamic equilibrium 5, 54 and entrepreneurship 66, 257 and price system 63, 66 Ebenstein, Alan 5, 6, 246 and socialism 62, 63, 66, 252, 257–8 Econometrica (journal) 15 and socialist calculation debate 280, economic calculation 285–6, 289 and general equilibrium theory 67 and spontaneous order 66–7, 257–8 and market processes 60–62 competitive order 66–7 and price system 60–61, 64–5 complementarity 169–71, 173 and socialism 1, 4, 59, 60–62, 64–5, complexity 173, 175–87 149, 246, 247–9, 281–3, 284, ‘compositive social theory’ 235–6, 239 287–8 Comte, Auguste 258–9 ‘Economic calculation in the socialist constitutional economics 344, 345, 348, commonwealth’ (article) 281, 356–7 282 constructivist rationalism 67, 229–30, Economic Journal 14–15, 109 231, 232, 234, 235–7, 259 Economica (journal) 108 consumption goods ‘Economics and knowledge’ (article) Roger W. Garrison and Norman Barry - 9780857931115 Downloaded from Elgar Online at 09/26/2021 06:52:48AM via free access 384 Elgar companion to Hayekian economics and change in Hayek’s economic and Keynesian economics 166–7 theory 94 and market processes 188–9 and economic calculation 247 experimental economics 36 and expectations 167 and ‘human action’ 152, 155 falsificationism 2 importance of 1, 2 fascism 108 and socialism 4 Federal Reserve (US) 133–4 and socialist calculation debate 286 Ferguson, Adam 225, 296 and static equilibrium 106–7 ‘firm heterogeneity’ 179–80 and ‘transformation’ of Hayek 195, Fisher, Stanley 22 197–8, 203 fixed capital 26 Economics as a Coordination Problem: Fleetwood, Steve 211–12 The Contribution of Friedrich A. ‘forced saving’ 19, 20, 21, 25, 52, 84, 87, Hayek (book) 6 88, 89, 90, 101, 103, 106 Economy and Society (book) 154 ‘formal-similarity’ argument 283 egalitarianism 267–9, 270, 271, 273, Foundation of Economic Education 377–8 35 ‘elastic’ currency 54 free trade 294–5, 303, 304–6, 309, 311 Ellis, Howard 15, 26 freedom of association 314–15, ‘emergence’ 179 332–3 Employment Acts (1980, 1982) 340 freedom of contract 315, 321, 333–6 Engels, Friedrich 261 Friedman, Milton enterprise/enterprises 21, 82, 95–6, 262, commonality with Hayek 113, 116, 320, 329–30, 335, 337–9 117–18, 130, 135 entrepreneurship and Keynesianism 120, 121–2 and business cycles 20 and ‘long-run/short-run’ and capital theory 48, 74–5, 79, 81, relationships 128–9, 135 92 and macroeconomics 113, 119–23, and competitive markets 66, 257 125, 130, 132 and expectations 187–8 methodology of 117, 121, 122, 132 and interest rates 51 opposing views to Hayek 116–17, and knowledge 204, 254 118–23, 124 and market processes 287 and quantity theory 22, 23, 120–21, and monetary policy 54, 56, 353 122–3, 125 and price expectations 56 response to Prices and Production and price system 64–6 135 and production process 50, 52–3 and ‘simple common model’ 120, and socialist calculation debate 287 129 and stationary states 59 and ‘transmission mechanisms’ ‘envy’ 377–8 129–30 Essays in Positive Economics (book) and unions 335 117 and University of Chicago evolution 177–8, 225, 240–41 economics department 5, 17 ‘evolutionary natural law’ 373–4 Friedrich Hayek: A Biography (book) exclusive representation 318–19, 331–2, 246 334, 340 full employment expectations and business cycles 21 and capital theory 166, 167–9, 172 and consumption goods 89 and entrepreneurs 187–8 goal of 81, 87 and institutions 187–8 and inflation 26–7, 87 Roger W.
Recommended publications
  • Economics for Real People
    Economics for Real People An Introduction to the Austrian School 2nd Edition Economics for Real People An Introduction to the Austrian School 2nd Edition Gene Callahan Copyright 2002, 2004 by Gene Callahan All rights reserved. Written permission must be secured from the publisher to use or reproduce any part of this book, except for brief quotations in critical reviews or articles. Published by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 518 West Magnolia Avenue, Auburn, Alabama 36832-4528. ISBN: 0-945466-41-2 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Dedicated to Professor Israel Kirzner, on the occasion of his retirement from economics. My deepest gratitude to my wife, Elen, for her support and forbearance during the many hours it took to complete this book. Special thanks to Lew Rockwell, president of the Ludwig von Mises Institute, for conceiving of this project, and having enough faith in me to put it in my hands. Thanks to Jonathan Erickson of Dr. Dobb’s Journal for per- mission to use my Dr. Dobb’s online op-eds, “Just What Is Superior Technology?” as the basis for Chapter 16, and “Those Damned Bugs!” as the basis for part of Chapter 14. Thanks to Michael Novak of the American Enterprise Insti- tute for permission to use his phrase, “social justice, rightly understood,” as the title for Part 4 of the book. Thanks to Professor Mario Rizzo for kindly inviting me to attend the NYU Colloquium on Market Institutions and Eco- nomic Processes. Thanks to Robert Murphy of Hillsdale College for his fre- quent collaboration, including on two parts of this book, and for many fruitful discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • Lucas on the Relationship Between Theory and Ideology
    Discussion Paper No. 2010-28 | November 17, 2010 | http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2010-28 Lucas on the Relationship between Theory and Ideology Michel De Vroey IRES, University of Louvain Please cite the corresponding journal article: http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2011-4 Abstract This paper concerns a neglected aspect of Lucas’s work: his methodological writings, published and unpublished. Particular attention is paid to his views on the relationship between theory and ideology. I start by setting out Lucas’s non-standard conception of theory: to him, a theory and a model are the same thing. I also explore the different facets and implications of this conception. In the next two sections, I debate whether Lucas adheres to two methodological principles that I dub the ‘non-interference’ precept (the proposition that ideological viewpoints should not influence theory), and the ‘non-exploitation’ precept (that the models’ conclusions should not be transposed into policy recommendations, in so far as these conclusions are built into the models’ premises). The last part of the paper contains my assessment of Lucas’s ideas. First, I bring out the extent to which Lucas departs from the view held by most specialized methodologists. Second, I wonder whether the new classical revolution resulted from a political agenda. Third and finally, I claim that the tensions characterizing Lucas’s conception of theory follow from his having one foot in the neo- Walrasian and the other in the Marshallian–Friedmanian universe. JEL B22, B31, B41, E30 Keywords Lucas; new classical macroeconomics; methodology Correspondence Michel De Vroey, IRES, University of Louvain, Place Montesquieu 3, B- 3458 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium: e-mail: [email protected] A first version of this paper was presented at seminars given at the University of Toronto and the University of British Columbia.
    [Show full text]
  • A Hayekian Theory of Social Justice
    A HAYEKIAN THEORY OF SOCIAL JUSTICE Samuel Taylor Morison* As Justice gives every Man a Title to the product of his honest Industry, and the fair Acquisitions of his Ancestors descended to him; so Charity gives every Man a Title to so much of another’s Plenty, as will keep him from ex- tream want, where he has no means to subsist otherwise. – John Locke1 I. Introduction The purpose of this essay is to critically examine Friedrich Hayek’s broadside against the conceptual intelligibility of the theory of social or distributive justice. This theme first appears in Hayek’s work in his famous political tract, The Road to Serfdom (1944), and later in The Constitution of Liberty (1960), but he developed the argument at greatest length in his major work in political philosophy, the trilogy entitled Law, Legis- lation, and Liberty (1973-79). Given that Hayek subtitled the second volume of this work The Mirage of Social Justice,2 it might seem counterintuitive or perhaps even ab- surd to suggest the existence of a genuinely Hayekian theory of social justice. Not- withstanding the rhetorical tenor of some of his remarks, however, Hayek’s actual con- clusions are characteristically even-tempered, which, I shall argue, leaves open the possibility of a revisionist account of the matter. As Hayek understands the term, “social justice” usually refers to the inten- tional doling out of economic rewards by the government, “some pattern of remunera- tion based on the assessment of the performance or the needs of different individuals * Attorney-Advisor, Office of the Pardon Attorney, United States Department of Justice, Washington, D.C.; e- mail: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Is the Family a Spontaneous Order?
    Is the Family a Spontaneous Order? Steven Horwitz Department of Economics St. Lawrence University Canton, NY 13617 TEL (315) 229 5731 FAX (315) 229 5819 Email [email protected] Version 1.0 September 2007 Prepared for the Atlas Foundation “Emergent Orders” conference in Portsmouth, NH, October 27-30, 2007 This paper is part of a larger book project tentatively titled Two Worlds at Once: A Classical Liberal Approach to the Evolution of the Modern Family. I thank Jan Narveson for an email exchange that prompted my thinking about many of the ideas herein. Work on this paper was done while a visiting scholar at the Social Philosophy and Policy Center at Bowling Green State University and I thank the Center for its support. 1 The thirty or so years since F. A. Hayek was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economic Science has seen a steady growth in what might best be termed “Hayek Studies.” His ideas have been critically assessed and our understanding of them has been deepened and extended in numerous ways. At the center of Hayek’s work, especially since the 1950s, was the concept of “spontaneous order.” Spontaneous order (which would be more accurately rendered as “unplanned” or “undesigned” or “emergent” order) refers, at least in the social world, to those human practices, norms, and institutions that are, in the words of Adam Ferguson, “products of human action, but not human design.” For Hayek, this concept was central to his critique of “scientism,” or the belief that human beings could control and manipulate the social world with the (supposed) methods of the natural sciences.
    [Show full text]
  • FALL 2015 Journal of Austrian Economics
    The VOL. 18 | NO. 3 | 294–310 QUArtERLY FALL 2015 JOURNAL of AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS PRAXEOLOGY OF COERCION: CATALLACTICS VS. CRATICS RAHIM TAGHIZADEGAN AND MARC-FELIX Otto ABSTRACT: Ludwig von Mises’s most important legacy is the foundation and analysis of catallactics, i.e. the economics of interpersonal exchange, as a sub-discipline of praxeology, the science of human action. In this paper, based both on Mises’s methodical framework and on insights by Tadeusz Kotarbinski and Max Weber, a “praxeology of coercion,” or, more precisely, an analysis of interpersonal actions involving threats, is developed. Our investigation yields both a reviewed taxonomy of human action and a first analysis of the elements of this theory, which we term cratics. This shall establish the basis for adjacent studies, furthering Mises’s project regarding the science of human action. KEYWORDS: Austrian school, praxeology, catallactics, coercion JEL CLASSIFICATION: B53 Rahim Taghizadegan ([email protected]) is director of the academic research institute Scholarium (scholarium.at) in Vienna, Austria, lecturer at several univer- sities and faculty member at the International Academy of Philosophy in Liech- tenstein. Marc-Felix Otto ([email protected]) is equity partner at the consulting firm The Advisory House in Zurich, Switzerland. Both authors would like to thank the research staff at the Scholarium for their help and input, in particular Johannes Leitner and Andreas M. Kramer. 294 Rahim Taghizadegan and Marc-Felix Otto: Praxeology Of Coercion… 295 INTRODUCTION he Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises intended to re-establish economics on a deductive basis, with the subjective Tvaluations, expectations, and goals of acting humans at the center, following the tradition of the “Austrian School” (see Mises, 1940 and 1962).
    [Show full text]
  • The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: a Critique of Received Explanations
    The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: A Critique of Received Explanations Joseph T. Salerno or roughly the first three quarters of the nineteenth century, the "liberal school" thoroughly dominated economic thinking and teaching in F France.1 Adherents of the school were also to be found in the United States and Italy, and liberal doctrines exercised a profound influence on prominent German and British economists. Although its numbers and au- thority began to dwindle after the 1870s, the school remained active and influential in France well into the 1920s. Even after World War II, there were a few noteworthy French economists who could be considered intellectual descendants of the liberal tradition. Despite its great longevity and wide-ranging influence, the scientific con- tributions of the liberal school and their impact on the development of Eu- ropean and U.S. economic thought—particularly on those economists who are today recognized as the forerunners, founders, and early exponents of marginalist economics—have been belittled or simply ignored by most twen- tieth-century Anglo-American economists and historians of thought. A number of doctrinal scholars, including Joseph Schumpeter, have noted and attempted to explain the curious neglect of the school in the En- glish-language literature. In citing the school's "analytical sterility" or "indif- ference to pure theory" as a main cause of its neglect, however, their expla- nations have overlooked a salient fact: that many prominent contributors to economic analysis throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries expressed strong appreciation of or weighty intellectual debts to the purely theoretical contributions of the liberal school.
    [Show full text]
  • Socialism, Economic Calculation And
    SOCIALISM, ECONOMIC CALCULATION AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP BY Jesús Huerta de Soto TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER I: INTRODUCTION ............................................................................. 1 1. SOCIALISM AND ECONOMIC ANALYSIS .................................................... 1 The Historic Failure of Socialism ........................................................................ 1 The Subjective Perspective in the Economic Analysis of Socialism ................... 3 Our Definition of Socialism ................................................................................. 4 Entrepreneurship and Socialism ........................................................................... 5 Socialism as an Intellectual Error ......................................................................... 6 2. THE DEBATE ON THE IMPOSSIBILITY OF SOCIALIST ECONOMIC 7 CALCULATION .................................................................................................. Ludwig von Mises and the Start of the Socialism Debate .................................... 7 The Unjustified Shift in the Debate toward Statics .............................................. 8 Oskar Lange and the “Competitive Solution” ...................................................... 9 “Market Socialism” as the Impossible Squaring of the Circle ............................. 9 3. OTHER POSSIBLE LINES OF RESEARCH ..................................................... 10 1. The Analysis of So-called “Self-Management Socialism” ............................. 10 2. “Indicative
    [Show full text]
  • Firmin Oulès and the “New Lausanne School”
    Firmin Oulès and the "New Lausanne School" David Sarech (University of Lausanne, Ph.D. Student) In this paper I will present Firmin Oulès’ “harmonized economics” and interrogate the relationship between state and market in his thought. “Harmonized economics” were conceived as the continuation of Léon Walras’ theory. The key concept of the first Lausanne school is the notion of equilibrium. Indeed, Walras forged it in order to “scientifically” demonstrate the superiority of a competition-based economy. However, the mathematical approach he chose, as well as his disdain for the orthodox economy of his time, led him to be misunderstood and he did not receive the recognition he was expecting. Thus the concept of general equilibrium would be forgotten until the mid 1950’s when it would become the core of microeconomics. However, as recent studies in history of economic thought have shown, the concept of equilibrium in Walras’ thought has to be understood in a broader context than a purely economical one. Indeed, the main goal of Walras was to bring an answer to “the social question”. Contrary to Marx, he did not think of it as being a problem of profit distribution between labor and capital. Instead he thought the goal of the economist was to create an economic system were everyone would be able to exert its inner abilities and in which inequalities would be based solely on merit. The incentive created by private property and profit-seeking being the groundwork of a flourishing economy, the equilibrium had to be understood as a tool to establish this idealistic society.
    [Show full text]
  • Peter J. Boettke
    PETER J. BOETTKE BB&T Professor for the Study of Capitalism, Mercatus Center at George Mason University, & University Professor of Economics and Philosophy Department of Economics, MSN 3G4 George Mason University Fairfax, VA 22030 Tel: 703-993-1149 Fax: 703-993-1133 Web: http://www.peter-boettke.com http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=182652 http://www.coordinationproblem.org PERSONAL Date of birth: January 3, 1960 Nationality: United States EDUCATION Ph.D. in Economics, George Mason University, January, 1989 M.A. in Economics, George Mason University, January, 1987 B.A. in Economics, Grove City College, May, 1983 TITLE OF DOCTORAL THESIS: The Political Economy of Soviet Socialism, 1918-1928 PROFESSIONAL EXPERIENCE Academic Positions 1987 –88 Visiting Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, George Mason University 1988 –90 Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, School of Business Administration, Oakland University, Rochester, MI 48309 1990 –97 Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, New York University, New York, NY 10003 1997 –98 Associate Professor, Department of Economics and Finance, School of Business, Manhattan College, Riverdale, NY 10471 1998 – 2003 Associate Professor, Department of Economics, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA 22030 (tenured Fall 2000) 2003 –07 Professor, Department of Economics, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA 22030 2007 – University Professor, George Mason University 2011 – Affiliate Faculty, Department of Philosophy, George Mason University FIELDS OF INTEREST
    [Show full text]
  • Adam Smith and the Austrian School of Economics: the Problem of Diamonds and Water
    Stefan Poier 1st year Part-time Doctoral Studies Adam Smith and the Austrian School of Economics: The Problem of Diamonds and Water Keywords: Adam Smith, Austrian School of Economics, Value Paradox, Marginal Utility, Decision Making Introduction When end of 2017 Leonardo da Vinci's painting "Salvator Mundi" was auctioned off for over $450 million, it was nearly three times as expensive as the second most expensive painting, a Picasso, and it could have compensated for the state deficit of Lithuania. An absurdly high sum for a piece of wood and oil paint. How do you explain such a price? Neither the amount of time spent working on it, nor the benefits from this work alone could justify it. Why do we often pay high prices for goods with little use, but low prices for things that are sometimes partially vital? Generations of economists and philosophers have tried to resolve this apparent paradox. An explanation for this price is - quite simply - an individual’s willingness to pay this price. The prestige gain of owning one of only fifteen paintings of the probably most important artist and universal scholar of all time can already provide an enormous increase in status. It is the scarcity, the uniqueness of the artwork, which justified the high increase in utility or satisfaction. If there were any number of similar works, no one would pay more than the utility value for it. This – today rational – economic inference was not always granted. It is based on the recognition that the benefits of consumption of a good decreases with the amount consumed (and thus with the saturation of the consumer).
    [Show full text]
  • Schools of Economic Thought (Pdf)
    SCHOOLS OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT A BRIEF HISTORY OF ECONOMICS This isn't really essential to know, but may satisfy the curiosity of many. Mercantilism Economics is said to begin with Adam Smith in 1776. Prior to that, nobody thought of economics, or markets, as an object of study. It is not that they didn't pay attention to economic matters, it is simply that they didn't think of it in any systematic or coherent manner. It was all just off-the-cuff intuition and policy proposals by a myriad of merchants, government officials & journalists, principally in Britain. It is common to denote the period before 1776 as "Mercantilism". It wasn't a coherent school of thought, but a hodge-podge of varying ideas about improving tax revenues, the value & movements of gold and how nations competed for international commerce & colonies. Mostly protectionist, 'war-minded', and all haphazardly argued. (the principal features of the Mercantilist school are discussed in our "Gains from Trade" handout). There was some opposition to Mercantilist doctrines, notably among French and Scottish thinkers (e.g. Pierre de Boisguilbert, Francois Quesnay, Jacques Turgot and David Hume) Classical School The Enlightenment era (mid-1700s) in Europe brought a new spirit of scientific inquiry. Thinkers began looking to apply scientific principles not only to the physical world, but also to human society. In the same spirit that Sir Isaac Newton 'discovered' the "law of gravity" to explain the interaction of natural forces and decipher how the physical world operates, Enlightenment thinkers began trying to discover the "laws" of human interaction, to explain how human society operates.
    [Show full text]
  • Austrian Economic Thought: Its Evolution and Its Contribution to Consumer Behavior
    A Great Revolution in Economics –Vienna 1871 and after Austrian economic thought: its evolution and its contribution to consumer behavior Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen A great REVOLUTION In economics —VIENNA 1871 and after AUSTRIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT: ITS EVOLUTION AND ITS CONTRIBUTION TO CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen The letter type on the cover is of Arnold Böcklin (Basel 1827-1901 Fiesole). It is a typical example of the Art Nouveau (Jugendstil) style—the fashionable style of art in Vienna at the end of the 19th century (the time older Austrianism came in full swing). In a sense, Böcklin’s work represents the essence of Austrianism: “Never was he interested in the accidental; he wanted the everlasting”. Cereales Foundation, publisher Wageningen University P.O. Box 357, 6700 AJ Wageningen, The Netherlands E [email protected] Printed by Grafisch Service Centrum Van Gils B.V. Cover design by Hans Weggen (Art Director Cereales) © 2001 Lazaros Th. Houmanidis and Auke R. Leen ISBN 90-805724-3-8 In the memory of our beloved colleague JACOB JAN KRABBE PREFACE A Great Revolution in Economics—Vienna 1871 and after is about the revolution in economic thought that started in Vienna in the last quarter of the nineteenth century. After a time of trying to save the objective value theory the time was there for a new awakening of economic thought. In Vienna, for the first time by the 1871 publication of Menger’s Grundsätze, value become subjective, and the market a process with a sovereign consumer. This book is about this awakening that proved to be more than a plaisanterie viennoise.
    [Show full text]