Austrian Economic Thought: Its Evolution and Its Contribution to Consumer Behavior

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Austrian Economic Thought: Its Evolution and Its Contribution to Consumer Behavior A Great Revolution in Economics –Vienna 1871 and after Austrian economic thought: its evolution and its contribution to consumer behavior Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen A great REVOLUTION In economics —VIENNA 1871 and after AUSTRIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT: ITS EVOLUTION AND ITS CONTRIBUTION TO CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen The letter type on the cover is of Arnold Böcklin (Basel 1827-1901 Fiesole). It is a typical example of the Art Nouveau (Jugendstil) style—the fashionable style of art in Vienna at the end of the 19th century (the time older Austrianism came in full swing). In a sense, Böcklin’s work represents the essence of Austrianism: “Never was he interested in the accidental; he wanted the everlasting”. Cereales Foundation, publisher Wageningen University P.O. Box 357, 6700 AJ Wageningen, The Netherlands E [email protected] Printed by Grafisch Service Centrum Van Gils B.V. Cover design by Hans Weggen (Art Director Cereales) © 2001 Lazaros Th. Houmanidis and Auke R. Leen ISBN 90-805724-3-8 In the memory of our beloved colleague JACOB JAN KRABBE PREFACE A Great Revolution in Economics—Vienna 1871 and after is about the revolution in economic thought that started in Vienna in the last quarter of the nineteenth century. After a time of trying to save the objective value theory the time was there for a new awakening of economic thought. In Vienna, for the first time by the 1871 publication of Menger’s Grundsätze, value become subjective, and the market a process with a sovereign consumer. This book is about this awakening that proved to be more than a plaisanterie viennoise. The book is the result of the collaboration of professor emeritus Lazaros Houmanidis of Greece and Auke Leen of the Netherlands. During his life long academic career Houmanidis has written numerous articles and books, mainly in Greek, about the Austrian School of Economics. These include The Subjective Theory of Value, from the Physiocrates until today (1954) and, more recently, History of Economic Theories (1999). Leen has written a book The Consumer in Austrian Economics and the Austrian Perspective on Consumer Policy (1999) and several articles and articles in books about the role of the consumer in modern Austrian economics. The first part, written by Houmanidis, mainly describes the older Austrian School of economics whose ideas were developed largely in Austria during the 1870s and 1880s. Similar views had been developed earlier, however, and other economists were also accepting a subjective theory of value at the same time. The main emphasis was on subjective marginal utility—not objective, physical realities. Houmanidis stresses the great importance of the Austrian school to the science of economics. Part one emphasizes both the subjective and the theoretical feature of the Austrian school. Both features are also extensively discussed from a non-Austrian, especially neo-institutionalist perspective too. Houmanidis concludes that Austrian and Institutional economics when combined can offer the expected solution to the crisis in economic theory from a humanistic point of view. In the second part of the book, Leen mainly describes the modern Austrian School of economics. He describes modern Austrian economics as an extension of Menger’s older static subjectivism: the market is first and foremost a process. In other words, subjective value is merely an implication of vi Preface the subjective appreciation of the economic process. Leen emphasizes the two essential features of this process: ignorance and entrepreneurial alertness. Ignorance is the foundation of the systematic quality of market processes and alertness drives the Mengerian market process. After an extensive overview of the method of Austrian economics, Leen then goes on to stress the role of the consumer in the market. He applies the modern Austrian vision on the market to the calculative and entrepreneurial role of the consumer. Consumers shape the pattern of resource use and the assignment of resource rewards according to their preferences. The role of the consumer, however, has been largely ignored in modern Austrian economics, as a result of the debate on rational economic calculation under central planning during the period between the wars. Though the debate in and of itself brought to the fore the idea of the market as a competitive-entrepreneurial process of discovery, the emphasis on the producer pushed the role of the consumer to the side in modern Austrian economics. Hoping for a logical and just critique of our efforts on the subject of older and modern Austrians economics, we offer our research to the reader who can help us to judge our work better. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS We are deeply grateful to J.A. Bijkerk, Annelies Coppelmans, Karen van der Heide, Karla ter Horst-van Domburg, Gerry van Nieuwenhoven, P. Odunga, Juanita Rothman, C. Tjovas, Dineke Wemmenhove, and Margeret van Wissen for transforming our work into a finished typescript. The making of the manuscript into a ready-for-publication form owes everything to their professionalism and care. CONTENTS PART I AUSTRIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT: ITS EVOLUTION 1 THE MAIN PROBLEM 15 1.1 The significance of value: Wicksell versus Cassel 15 1.1.2 Two basic and controversial elements in the determination of value 18 1.1.3 The theory of marginal utility and its precursors 20 1. 2 The paradox of value in Smith’s thought 23 1. 2.1 The differentiation of some classicists from the objective value theory 26 1. 3 Naturalism and voluntarism 30 2 THE OLDER AUSTRIAN SCHOOL ON VALUE AND DISTRIBUTION 35 2.1 Subjectivism and marginal utility 37 2.1.1 Some other precursors of marginal utility 39 2.1.2 A Prelude 40 2.1.3 The debate of methods and the new horizons in economics 41 2.2 Carl von Menger 43 2.2.1 Some complementary remarks on Menger’s theories 50 2.3 Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk 54 2.3.1 Böhm-Bawerk’s theories on distribution 56 2.3.2 Complementary remarks 57 2.4 Friedrich von Wieser 58 2.4.1 Complementary ideas and aspects on Wieser’s theories 62 2.4.2 Concluding remarks 64 x Contents 3 THE NEO AUSTRIANS 73 3.1 The new horizons in the evolution of marginalism 73 3.1.1 Economic calculation and the role of time 75 3.1.2 Human action under the exploration of Neo Austrians 77 3.2 Complementaries and final remarks 79 3.2.1 Some doctrinaire discussions 87 3.2.2 Can the Austrian School be combined with the Institutional School? 96 PART II AUSTRIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT: ITS CONTRIBUTION TO CONSUMER BEHAVIOR 4 THE DEMISE OF THE CONSUMER: THE SOCIALIST CALCULATION DEBATE 101 4.1 How the consumer became lost 101 4.2 The consumer: somewhere along the way of the market process 104 5 PRAXEOLOGY 108 5.1 The method of Austrian economics 108 5.1.1 The older roots of praxeology 108 5.1.2 The modern Austrian roots of praxeology 109 5.2 The different parts of praxeology 112 5.3 Concepts and laws of human action 114 5.3.1 Praxeological concepts of action 114 5.3.1.1 Valuation 115 5.3.1.2 The marginal unit 115 5.3.3 Indifference curves 116 5.3.3.1 Indifference and preference 117 5.3.3.2 Indifference and exchange 118 5.4 Praxeological laws 121 5.4.1 The law of decreasing returns 122 5.4.1.1 What the neoclassicals say 123 Contents xi 5.4.1.2 What the Austrians say 124 5.5 Praxeology versus the natural sciences 126 5.6 Praxeology versus quantitative economics 129 5.6.1 Mathematical economics 129 5.6.2 Econometrics 132 6 THE MARKET PROCESS 135 6.1 Equilibrium states versus disequilibrium processes 135 6.1.1 Negative and positive externalities 139 6.2 What drives the market process? 141 6.2.1 Menger’s goods characteristics 142 6.2.2 Böhm-Bawerk’s goods characteristics 144 6.2.2.1 Ryle on knowing how and knowing that 145 6.2.3 The entrepreneurial consumer 148 6.3 What constitutes the market process? 151 6.3.1 Short cuts in equilibrium: the first and second generation 151 6.3.2 Short cuts in equilibrium: the third generation 153 6.3.3 Short cuts in disequilibrium: Schönfeld-Illy 155 6.3.3.1 Schönfeld-Illy: a modern-Austrian forerunner 155 6.3.3.2 Schönfeld-Illy’s three principles 158 6.3.3.3 Böhm-Bawerk versus Schönfeld-Illy on total value 160 6.3.4 The discovering consumer 162 6.4 What characterizes the market process? 164 6.4.1 Competition among consumers: the why not 164 6.4.2 Competition among producers and consumers 167 6.4.3 The competing consumer 172 7 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS OF PART II 174 Bibliography 179 Part 1 Austrian Economic Thought: its evolution “And marginal utility is subjectively estimated; it corresponds to a subjective maximization of the total utility” —Perroux 1 THE MAIN PROBLEM 1.1 The significance of value: Wicksell versus Cassel he most important phenomenon and the cornerstone of economics is the phenomenon of value. Lewis Haney rightly writes, “Value being the heart of economics, the economist’s philosophy is bound to shape his value theory” ([1949], 1951, p. 16). Unfortunately, the theory of value presents great difficulties as it is connected with two conflicting views: the objective and the subjective one. Concerning the endeavor for the best approach, William Smart argues: "Yet the history of economic science is strewn with the wrecks of value” (1966, p. 1). Gustav Cassel ([1918], 1927) from his point of view observed that price is important for economics, since it determines the phenomenon of goods and services.
Recommended publications
  • Keynes's Investment Theory As a Micro-Foundation for His Grandchildren
    Vol. 14, 2020-24 | July 03, 2020 | http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2020-24 Keynes's investment theory as a micro-foundation for his grandchildren Sergio Nisticò Abstract In contrast with the ‘missing micro-foundations’ argument against Keynes’s macro- economics, the paper argues that it is the present state of microeconomics that needs more solid ‘Keynesian foundations’. It is in particular Keynes’s understanding of investors’ behaviour that can be fruitfully extended to consumption theory, in a context in which consumers are considered as entrepreneurs, buying goods and services to engage in time- consuming activities. The paper emphasizes that the outcome in terms of enjoyment is particularly uncertain for those innovative and path-breaking activities, which Keynes discussed in his 1930 prophetic essay about us, the grandchildren of his contemporaries. Moreover, the Keynes-inspired microeconomics suggested in the paper provides an explanation of why Keynes’s prophecy about his grandchildren possibly expanding leisure did not materialize yet. The paper finally points at the need for appropriate economic policies supporting consumers’ propensity to enforce innovative forms of time use. JEL B41 D11 D81 Keywords Keynesian microeconomics; consumption; time use; uncertainty; Keynes’s grandchildren Authors Sergio Nisticò, Creativity and Motivations Economic Research Center, Department of Economics and Law, University of Cassino and Southern Lazio, Italy, [email protected] Citation Sergio Nisticò (2020). Keynes's investment theory as a micro-foundation for his grandchildren. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 14 (2020-24): 1–15. http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2020-24 Received January 22, 2020 Published as Economics Discussion Paper February 14, 2020 Revised June 8, 2020 Accepted June 18, 2020 Published July 3, 2020 © Author(s) 2020.
    [Show full text]
  • Lucas on the Relationship Between Theory and Ideology
    Discussion Paper No. 2010-28 | November 17, 2010 | http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2010-28 Lucas on the Relationship between Theory and Ideology Michel De Vroey IRES, University of Louvain Please cite the corresponding journal article: http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2011-4 Abstract This paper concerns a neglected aspect of Lucas’s work: his methodological writings, published and unpublished. Particular attention is paid to his views on the relationship between theory and ideology. I start by setting out Lucas’s non-standard conception of theory: to him, a theory and a model are the same thing. I also explore the different facets and implications of this conception. In the next two sections, I debate whether Lucas adheres to two methodological principles that I dub the ‘non-interference’ precept (the proposition that ideological viewpoints should not influence theory), and the ‘non-exploitation’ precept (that the models’ conclusions should not be transposed into policy recommendations, in so far as these conclusions are built into the models’ premises). The last part of the paper contains my assessment of Lucas’s ideas. First, I bring out the extent to which Lucas departs from the view held by most specialized methodologists. Second, I wonder whether the new classical revolution resulted from a political agenda. Third and finally, I claim that the tensions characterizing Lucas’s conception of theory follow from his having one foot in the neo- Walrasian and the other in the Marshallian–Friedmanian universe. JEL B22, B31, B41, E30 Keywords Lucas; new classical macroeconomics; methodology Correspondence Michel De Vroey, IRES, University of Louvain, Place Montesquieu 3, B- 3458 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium: e-mail: [email protected] A first version of this paper was presented at seminars given at the University of Toronto and the University of British Columbia.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics, Neurobiology and Pharmacology of Intertemporal Choice in Humans
    The Economics, Neurobiology and Pharmacology of Intertemporal Choice in Humans A thesis submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Alexander J Pine University College London September 2009 2 Preface I, Alexander J Pine confirm that the work presented in this thesis is my own. Where information has been derived from other sources I confirm that this has been indicated in the thesis. AJ Pine 3 Abstract In intertemporal choice, decision-makers must choose between options whose outcomes occur at different times in the future and are associated with different magnitudes of gain or loss. Previous neuropsychological research on this problem is dominated by a behavioural- economic model which proposes that choice outcome is solely determined by a process of devaluing rewards with time, termed temporal discounting. This thesis investigates the veracity of this assumption by developing a new mathematical model of choice which takes into account another fundamental feature of human preference, namely the non-linearity of the relationship between the utility and magnitude of gains. Using behavioural data, methodologies are developed to demonstrate that this model is superior to previous models in accounting for human intertemporal choices. Specifically, using existing terminologies ‘impulsive’ and ‘self-controlled’ to describe preference in choices between smaller-sooner and larger-later monetary rewards, it is shown that the discounting of increasing magnitudes implied by the law of diminishing marginal utility exerts a significant effect in determining choice outcome. In addition to high rates of temporal discounting, it is shown that impulsivity can be engendered by higher rates of diminishing marginal utility and vice-versa.
    [Show full text]
  • Hermann, Rau, Mangoldt : Les Origines De La Fonction D’Offre De Marché En Allemagne (1830 - 1870) Paola Tubaro
    Hermann, Rau, Mangoldt : les origines de la fonction d’offre de marché en Allemagne (1830 - 1870) Paola Tubaro To cite this version: Paola Tubaro. Hermann, Rau, Mangoldt : les origines de la fonction d’offre de marché en Allemagne (1830 - 1870). Recherches Economiques de Louvain - Louvain economic review, De Boeck Université, 2005, 71 (2), pp.223 - 243. 10.3917/rel.712.0223. hal-01648314 HAL Id: hal-01648314 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01648314 Submitted on 28 Nov 2020 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. HERMANN, RAU, MANGOLDT : LES ORIGINES DE LA FONCTION D'OFFRE DE MARCHÉ EN ALLEMAGNE (1830 - 1870) Paola Tubaro De Boeck Supérieur | « Recherches économiques de Louvain » 2005/2 Vol. 71 | pages 223 à 243 ISSN 0770-4518 ISBN 2-8041-4747-9 Document téléchargé depuis www.cairn.info - 176.183.201.126 25/11/2017 13h00. © De Boeck Supérieur Article disponible en ligne à l'adresse : -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- https://www.cairn.info/revue-recherches-economiques-de- louvain-2005-2-page-223.htm -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Pour citer cet article : -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Paola Tubaro, « Hermann, Rau, Mangoldt : les origines de la fonction d'offre de marché en Allemagne (1830 - 1870) », Recherches économiques de Louvain 2005/2 (Vol.
    [Show full text]
  • Microeconomics
    AQA A Level Economics Course Companion Year 2 Topics Microeconomics Author: Geoff Riley www.tutor2u.net Copyright tutor2u: www.tutor2u.net/economics 1 Individual economic decision making ................................................................................................ 4 Imperfect Information ........................................................................................................................ 6 Behavioural Economics ...................................................................................................................... 8 Public and Private Sector Organisations ...................................................................................... 15 Profit and Not-for-Profit Organisations ........................................................................................ 15 Production and productivity ............................................................................................................ 18 Specialisation, division of labour and exchange ............................................................................... 18 The Law of Diminishing Returns ....................................................................................................... 21 Long Run Returns to Scale ............................................................................................................ 22 Costs of Production .......................................................................................................................... 24 Costs of production in the short
    [Show full text]
  • The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: a Critique of Received Explanations
    The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: A Critique of Received Explanations Joseph T. Salerno or roughly the first three quarters of the nineteenth century, the "liberal school" thoroughly dominated economic thinking and teaching in F France.1 Adherents of the school were also to be found in the United States and Italy, and liberal doctrines exercised a profound influence on prominent German and British economists. Although its numbers and au- thority began to dwindle after the 1870s, the school remained active and influential in France well into the 1920s. Even after World War II, there were a few noteworthy French economists who could be considered intellectual descendants of the liberal tradition. Despite its great longevity and wide-ranging influence, the scientific con- tributions of the liberal school and their impact on the development of Eu- ropean and U.S. economic thought—particularly on those economists who are today recognized as the forerunners, founders, and early exponents of marginalist economics—have been belittled or simply ignored by most twen- tieth-century Anglo-American economists and historians of thought. A number of doctrinal scholars, including Joseph Schumpeter, have noted and attempted to explain the curious neglect of the school in the En- glish-language literature. In citing the school's "analytical sterility" or "indif- ference to pure theory" as a main cause of its neglect, however, their expla- nations have overlooked a salient fact: that many prominent contributors to economic analysis throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries expressed strong appreciation of or weighty intellectual debts to the purely theoretical contributions of the liberal school.
    [Show full text]
  • Firmin Oulès and the “New Lausanne School”
    Firmin Oulès and the "New Lausanne School" David Sarech (University of Lausanne, Ph.D. Student) In this paper I will present Firmin Oulès’ “harmonized economics” and interrogate the relationship between state and market in his thought. “Harmonized economics” were conceived as the continuation of Léon Walras’ theory. The key concept of the first Lausanne school is the notion of equilibrium. Indeed, Walras forged it in order to “scientifically” demonstrate the superiority of a competition-based economy. However, the mathematical approach he chose, as well as his disdain for the orthodox economy of his time, led him to be misunderstood and he did not receive the recognition he was expecting. Thus the concept of general equilibrium would be forgotten until the mid 1950’s when it would become the core of microeconomics. However, as recent studies in history of economic thought have shown, the concept of equilibrium in Walras’ thought has to be understood in a broader context than a purely economical one. Indeed, the main goal of Walras was to bring an answer to “the social question”. Contrary to Marx, he did not think of it as being a problem of profit distribution between labor and capital. Instead he thought the goal of the economist was to create an economic system were everyone would be able to exert its inner abilities and in which inequalities would be based solely on merit. The incentive created by private property and profit-seeking being the groundwork of a flourishing economy, the equilibrium had to be understood as a tool to establish this idealistic society.
    [Show full text]
  • Networks of Modernity: Germany in the Age of the Telegraph, 1830–1880
    OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 24/3/2021, SPi STUDIES IN GERMAN HISTORY Series Editors Neil Gregor (Southampton) Len Scales (Durham) Editorial Board Simon MacLean (St Andrews) Frank Rexroth (Göttingen) Ulinka Rublack (Cambridge) Joel Harrington (Vanderbilt) Yair Mintzker (Princeton) Svenja Goltermann (Zürich) Maiken Umbach (Nottingham) Paul Betts (Oxford) OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 24/3/2021, SPi OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 24/3/2021, SPi Networks of Modernity Germany in the Age of the Telegraph, 1830–1880 JEAN-MICHEL JOHNSTON 1 OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 24/3/2021, SPi 3 Great Clarendon Street, Oxford, OX2 6DP, United Kingdom Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press in the UK and in certain other countries © Jean-Michel Johnston 2021 The moral rights of the author have been asserted First Edition published in 2021 Impression: 1 Some rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, for commercial purposes, without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press, or as expressly permitted by law, by licence or under terms agreed with the appropriate reprographics rights organization. This is an open access publication, available online and distributed under the terms of a Creative Commons Attribution – Non Commercial – No Derivatives 4.0 International licence (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), a copy of which is available at http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/.
    [Show full text]
  • Marginal Revolution
    MARGINAL REVOLUTION It took place in the later half of the 19th century Stanley Jevons in England, Carl Menger in Austria and Leon walras at Lausanne, are generally regarded as the founders of marginalist school Hermann Heinrich Gossen of Germany is considered to be the anticipator of the marginalist school The term ‘Marginal Revolution’ is applied to the writings of the above economists because they made fundamental changes in the apparatus of economic analysis They started looking at some of the important economic problems from an altogether new angle different from that of classical economists Marginal economists has been used to analyse the single firm and its behavior, the market for a single product and the formation of individual prices Marginalism dominated Western economic thought for nearly a century until it was challenged by Keynesian attack in 1936 (keynesian economics shifted the sphere of enquiry from micro economics to macro economics where the problems of the economy as a whole are analysed) The provocation for the emergence of marginalist school was provided by the interpretation of classical doctrines especially the labour theory of value and ricardian theory of rent by the socialists Socialists made use of classical theories to say things which were not the intention of the creators of those theories So the leading early marginalists felt the need for thoroughly revising the classical doctrines especially the theory of value They thought by rejecting the labour theory of value and by advocating the marginal utility theory of value, they could strike at the theoretical basis of socialism Economic Ideas of Marginalist School This school concentrated on the ‘margin’ to explain economic phenomena.
    [Show full text]
  • Karl Helfferich and Rudolf Hilferding on Georg Friedrich Knapp's State
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Greitens, Jan Conference Paper — Manuscript Version (Preprint) Karl Helfferich and Rudolf Hilferding on Georg Friedrich Knapp’s State Theory of Money: Monetary Theories during the Hyperinflation of 1923 Suggested Citation: Greitens, Jan (2020) : Karl Helfferich and Rudolf Hilferding on Georg Friedrich Knapp’s State Theory of Money: Monetary Theories during the Hyperinflation of 1923, Annual Conference of the European Society for the History of Economic Thought (ESHET) 2020, Sofia., ZBW - Leibniz Information Centre for Economics, Kiel, Hamburg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/216102 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available
    [Show full text]
  • Adam Smith and the Austrian School of Economics: the Problem of Diamonds and Water
    Stefan Poier 1st year Part-time Doctoral Studies Adam Smith and the Austrian School of Economics: The Problem of Diamonds and Water Keywords: Adam Smith, Austrian School of Economics, Value Paradox, Marginal Utility, Decision Making Introduction When end of 2017 Leonardo da Vinci's painting "Salvator Mundi" was auctioned off for over $450 million, it was nearly three times as expensive as the second most expensive painting, a Picasso, and it could have compensated for the state deficit of Lithuania. An absurdly high sum for a piece of wood and oil paint. How do you explain such a price? Neither the amount of time spent working on it, nor the benefits from this work alone could justify it. Why do we often pay high prices for goods with little use, but low prices for things that are sometimes partially vital? Generations of economists and philosophers have tried to resolve this apparent paradox. An explanation for this price is - quite simply - an individual’s willingness to pay this price. The prestige gain of owning one of only fifteen paintings of the probably most important artist and universal scholar of all time can already provide an enormous increase in status. It is the scarcity, the uniqueness of the artwork, which justified the high increase in utility or satisfaction. If there were any number of similar works, no one would pay more than the utility value for it. This – today rational – economic inference was not always granted. It is based on the recognition that the benefits of consumption of a good decreases with the amount consumed (and thus with the saturation of the consumer).
    [Show full text]
  • Imputation and Value in the Works of Menger, Böhm-Bawerk and Wieser
    E-LOGOS/2005 ISSN 1121-0442 _____________________________________________ Imputation and Value in the works of Menger, Böhm-Bawerk and Wieser Šimon Bi ľo University of Economics, Prague [email protected] Alford Fellow, The Ludwig von Mises Institute, July 21, 2004 Version January 10, 2005 1 Abstract: Analysis of the discussions within the first two generations of the Austrian school of economics constitutes an inevitable cornerstone of every further inquiry on the fields of the theory of value and imputation theory. Only with knowledge of Menger’s, Wieser’s and Böhm-Bawerk’s understanding of cardinalism and problems related with utility, value and their interdependence, we are apt to understand correctness or incorrectness of their positions and also positions of their followers. Thus, we could trace back cardinalist notions of utility seeded by Menger and understand later Mises’- Čuhel reformulation of the whole value theory into an ordinalistic one. Mises fully escaped the Mengerian tradition in this point and also transformed the whole theory of imputation into the theory of pricing of the factors of production. The only exception, from the point of view of imputation theory of highest importance, is his insistence on the value equation of means and ends that confused his successors and was investigated only recently. Within the context of present state of value and imputation theories, two related problems arise: “What constitutes theory of imputation, theory of value and valuation of the factors of production, today?” and “Is Menger-Böhm-Bawerkian solution of imputation theory really suitable for the explanation of the pricing process and isn’t Wieser’s objection of circularity of the imputation theory applied in price-creation justified?” These are the questions that are badly needed to be answered in order to clarify the theory in the field.
    [Show full text]