Marx, Historical Materialism and the Asiatic Wde Of

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Marx, Historical Materialism and the Asiatic Wde Of MARX, HISTORICAL MATERIALISM AND THE ASIATIC WDE OF PRODUCTION BY Joseph Bensdict Huang Tan B.A. (Honors) Simon Fraser University 1994 THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULLFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS IN THE SCHOOL OF COMMUN ICATION @Joseph B. Tan 2000 SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY July 2000 Al1 rights reserved. This work may not be reproduced in whole or in part, by photocopy or other means, without permission of the author. uisitions and Acguiiiet raphii Senrices senrices bibiiihiques The author has granted a non- L'auteur a accordé une licence non exclusive licence allowing the exclusive permettant à la National Li'brary of Canada to BibIiothèque nationale du Canada de reproduceYloan, distriiute or sel1 reproduireyprêter, distribuer ou copies of this thesis in microh, vendre des copies de cette thèse sous papa or electronic formats. la fome de micro fi ch el^ de reproduction sur papier ou sur format électronique. The author tetains ownership of the L'auîeur conserve la propriété du copyright in this thesis*Neither the droit d'auteur qui protège cette thèse. thesis nor substantial extracts iÏom it Ni la thèse ni des extraits substantiels may be printed or otherwise de celle-ci ne doivent être imprimés reproduced without the author's ou autrement reproduits sans son permission. autorisation. ABSTRACT Historical materialism (HM), the theory of history originally developed by Marx and Engels is most comrnonly interpreted as a unilinear model, which dictates that al1 societies must pass through definite and universally similar stages on the route to communism. This simplistic interpretation existed long before Stalin and has persisted long after the process of de-Stalinization and into the present. This interpretation has caused many theoretical and practical problems over the years for Marxism. Most notably, a teleological interpretation denigrates the importance of the active or conscious side of HM and leads to the widespread acceptance of a hisrarical fatalism in the field of theory and political quietism in place of conscious class struggle and revolutionary politics. The Asiatic mode of production (AMP) offers concrete evidence that Marx and Engels, as well as generations of Marxists proceeding them, understood hurnan history as a very different, and much more cornplex, rnultilinear totality. This thesis will prove that despite its controversial nature, the AMP consistently remained an integral aspect of Marx and Engels' model of HM throughout their lives, It will be argued that the two authorsr development of the AMP spanned many decades and was based on careful and considered analysis of how historical developments in other parts of the world both conformed and .. * lu diverged from the five stage mode1 of development they had extrapolated from the history of Europe. This thesis will also suggest that the two authors were undogrnatic and flexible in their treatment and understanding of historical phenomena, often willing to change or adapt their conception of HM, and the historical process in general, to accommodate new facts and empirical evidence as these arose or manifested themselves. It will be argued that it was precisely the 'abandonment' of the AMP by later Marxists which helped, in part, facilitate the widespread acceptance of unilinear interpretations of historical materialism. An acceptance of the AMPfs existence definitively demolishes any unilinear understanding of the historical process and hence, eliminates the notions of fatalism and historical inevitability from revolutionary Marxism. Thus, the thesis ends with a reaffirmation of the centrality of class struggle, not just in the thoughts of Marx and Engels, but also for the altered historical reality of a post-communist 21St century. It concludes by arguing that the choice, first offered to humanity by Rosa Luxemburg over 80 years ago, is more pertinent and urgent than ever before: "socialism or barbarism". Table of Contents Approval. .......................ii Abstrrct. ......................iii Table of Contents. ...................v Listof figures. ....................vi Prefrce ........................vii Introduction. ......................1 Chapter One: The Controversial Nature of the Asiatic Mode ofProduction. .....................0 Chapter Two: The Origins of the Asiatic Mode of Production in the Thought of Marx and Engels. .......43 Chapter Three: The Place of the Asiatic Mode of Production Within Historical Mat.rirlism. ............ .83 Conclusion. ......................124 Bibliography. .....................129 List of Figures Figure 1: Melottirs multilinaar mo&l of historical blstsrialirm. 118 Pref ace 1 originally intended to launch into a big anti-capitalist rant in this preface. 1 was going ta point out how capitalism is an obscene, exploitative, destructive and irrational form of social organization that must be attacked, destroyed and thoroughly abolished by humanity before it soon kills the world. 1 was also going to point out how, in the unrelenting long scale of historical time, it is capitalismCs own ruthlessly efficient destructiveness which is destined to make it the most transient, fleeting and, ultimately, short-lived mode of production in al1 of human history. But 1 realized that there is nothing 1 could Say that has not been said far more elegantly, forcefully and eloquently by generations of revolutionaries before me. Instead, the following quote by the most brilliant mind in human history succinctly summarizes my thoughts and feelings about the need for humanity to finally transcend this most glorious-and nightmarish-phase in our existence: From the standpoint of a higher economic form of society, private ownership of the globe by single individuals will appear quite as absurd as private ownership of one man (sic) by anather. Even a whole society, a nation, or even al1 simultaneously existing societies taken together, are not the owners of the globe. They are only its possessors, its usufructuaries, and, like boni patres familias, they must hand it dom ta succeeding generations in ar? improved condition. ' ' Karl Marx, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume 3. Edited by Frederick Engels. (Moscow: Progreçs Publishers, 1977), p. 776 Introduction The Asiatic mode of production (NP) has had a strange and insecure existence within Marxist theory. It has had an even stranger, star-crossed relationship with the theory of history which it nominally rernains a part of, historical materialism. More than any other concept, the theoretical status of the AMP has never been fully secure or finalized within a theory of history that was, and is, forever in the process of being altered, revised and revitalized in order to comprehend a historical movement that is itself forever in flux. To some Marxists, the AMP was nothing more than an embarrassing display of Eurocentric arrogance on the part of Marx and Engels, a theoretical mistake which was founded upon a misinterpretation of the historical situation in Asia and which was soon forgotten and abandoned by both authors. To others, the AMP is not only a central component of historical materialism, but also forms the foundation upon which Marx's entire analysis of capitalist political economy was built upon. Over the years, a great number of Marxists have attempted, for a variety of reasons (including sheer ignorance of its importance and relevance to historical materialism) to remove the AMP from the arsenal of Marxism and deny its well documented existence in the writings of Marx and Engels. Many of the reasons for this denial (theoretical expediency, the immediate requirements of polemical debate and political strategy- including the defense of the building of Socialism in One Country in the USSR, etc.) are discussed in detail in this thesis. To varying degrees, these reasons al1 contributed to the eventual 'official abolition1 of the AMP in a 1931 Communist Party conference in Leningrad and its subsequent elimination from official Marxist 'orthodoxy'. However, it will be argued that the single, most overriding reason for both the desire to deny and abandon the AMP, as well as the obstinate refusal to resume research into this social formation, has been the long-standing hegemony of unilinear interpretations of historical materialism. Contxary to conventional belief, these unilinear interpretations of history predated the Marxism of the Second International and linger to the present-long after de-Stalinization and the collapse of 'actually existing Commwiismi. More than any other concept in Marxist theory, the AMP provides concrete evidence that Marx, and Engels meant their theory of history to be interpreted in a multilinear fashion, in a manner that helped shed light on the vast differences and diversities in the histories of the cultures, nations and social formations of which historical materialism sought to assist in both analyzing and changing. Brendan OrLeary observed that "historical materialisrn is damned if it retains the Asiatic Mode of Production, and damned if it doesn' t ."' By this he meant that an acceptance of the theoretical validity of the AMP destroys any unilinear interpretation of historical materialism, just as the attempt to retain a unilinear understanding of the theory raust also necessarily require abandoning the AMP yet again. However, the evidence presented in this thesis will corroborate the informed belief that historical materialism will be far better off with the AMP than without it. In his influential Marxism and ~hilosophy~,Karl
Recommended publications
  • Wars, Revolutions and the First Real World Revolution
    HAOL, Núm. 19 (Primavera, 2009), 7-27 ISSN 1696-2060 WARS, REVOLUTIONS AND THE FIRST REAL WORLD REVOLUTION Petri Minkkinen University of Helsinki, Finland. E-mail: [email protected] Recibido: 3 Marzo 2009 / Revisado: 1 Abril 2009 / Aceptado: 15 Abril 2009 / Publicación Online: 15 Junio 2009 Abstract: The purpose of this article is to Eurocentric actors as the main protagonists of engage in a conceptual discussion for a broader these global rules and thus global power- publication on “The Cycles of Imperialism, War relations, especially in an emerging situation in and Revolution”. It departs from a which also material factors support their presupposition that our common world is possibilities and capabilities to set these rules.1 experiencing a transition from a broad Another presupposition is that this global Eurocentric historical context into a non- transition is an interactive process of world level Eurocentric broad historical context. It proceeds processes and transformations and revolutionary by a historical discussion on the concepts related and power-political transitions at macro- to wars, reforms and revolutions and explains regional, national and local levels. A related why, in the context of the actual phase of global presupposition is that, as was the case of transition and the First Real World War, it is, Mexico’s revolution of 1910 which had national, despite earlier discussions on revolutions and macro-regional and global transformative world revolutions, meaningful to suggest that implications, the new long revolutionary process our common world is experiencing a First Real in Mexico has produced, is producing and will World Revolution. produce similar implications but which take Keywords: Broad Eurocentric historical context, place in a different world historical situation.
    [Show full text]
  • Raya Dunayevskaya Papers
    THE RAYA DUNAYEVSKAYA COLLECTION Marxist-Humanism: Its Origins and Development in America 1941 - 1969 2 1/2 linear feet Accession Number 363 L.C. Number ________ The papers of Raya Dunayevskaya were placed in the Archives of Labor History and Urban Affairs in J u l y of 1969 by Raya Dunayevskaya and were opened for research in May 1970. Raya Dunayevskaya has devoted her l i f e to the Marxist movement, and has devel- oped a revolutionary body of ideas: the theory of state-capitalism; and the continuity and dis-continuity of the Hegelian dialectic in Marx's global con- cept of philosophy and revolution. Born in Russia, she was Secretary to Leon Trotsky in exile in Mexico in 1937- 38, during the period of the Moscow Trials and the Dewey Commission of Inquiry into the charges made against Trotsky in those Trials. She broke politically with Trotsky in 1939, at the outset of World War II, in opposition to his defense of the Russian state, and began a comprehensive study of the i n i t i a l three Five-Year Plans, which led to her analysis that Russia is a state-capitalist society. She was co-founder of the political "State-Capitalist" Tendency within the Trotskyist movement in the 1940's, which was known as Johnson-Forest. Her translation into English of "Teaching of Economics in the Soviet Union" from Pod Znamenem Marxizma, together with her commentary, "A New Revision of Marxian Economics", appeared in the American Economic Review in 1944, and touched off an international debate among theoreticians.
    [Show full text]
  • Leninism Or Trotskyism.Pdf
    LENINISM TROTSKYISM BY G. E. ZINOVIEV I. STALIN L. KAMENEV PRICE 20 CENTS r PUBLISHED FEBRUARY 1925 FOR THE Workers Party of America BY THE DAILY WORKER PUBLISHING CO. 1113 W. WASHINGTON BLVD., CHICAGO, ILL. LENINISM OR TROTSKYISM BY G. E. ZINOVIEV I. STALIN L. KAMENEV PRICE 20 CENTS PUBLISHED FEBRUARY 1925 FOR THE Workers Party of America BY THE DAILY WORKER PUBLISHING CO. 1113 W. WASHINGTON BLVD.. CHICAGO. ILL. pllllllllllllllilllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllfllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllH | READY! I 1 To Fill Every Need of the American 1 1 Working Class for 1 | INFORMATION | | The Daily Worker Publishing Co. | | 1113 W. Washington Blvd., | | Chicago, 111. i S Publishers of: H 1 THE DAILY WORKER, contains the news of the world | = of labor. It is the world's only Communist daily appearing j| j£ in English. It is the only daily in America that fights for the = = interests of the working class. Participants of the struggle ^ 5 against capitalism find the DAILY WORKER indispensable ji 5 for its information and its leadership. || j SUBSCRIPTION RATES: I = 1 year—$6.00; 6 mos.—$3.50; Smos.—$2.00. |j 5 In Chicago: = 1 1 year—$8.00; 6 mos.—$4.50; 3 mos.—$2.50. = 1 THE WORKERS MONTHLY as the official organ of the | j= Workers Party and the Trade Union Educational League re- s S fleets the struggles of the American working class againsj 5 5 capitalism. Every month are printed the, best contributions =j = to American working class art and literature together witt 5 £j theoretical and descriptive articles on timely labor subjects = j= by the leading figures of the American and International = §= Communist movement.
    [Show full text]
  • The Russian Revolutions: the Impact and Limitations of Western Influence
    Dickinson College Dickinson Scholar Faculty and Staff Publications By Year Faculty and Staff Publications 2003 The Russian Revolutions: The Impact and Limitations of Western Influence Karl D. Qualls Dickinson College Follow this and additional works at: https://scholar.dickinson.edu/faculty_publications Part of the European History Commons Recommended Citation Qualls, Karl D., "The Russian Revolutions: The Impact and Limitations of Western Influence" (2003). Dickinson College Faculty Publications. Paper 8. https://scholar.dickinson.edu/faculty_publications/8 This article is brought to you for free and open access by Dickinson Scholar. It has been accepted for inclusion by an authorized administrator. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Karl D. Qualls The Russian Revolutions: The Impact and Limitations of Western Influence After the collapse of the Soviet Union, historians have again turned their attention to the birth of the first Communist state in hopes of understanding the place of the Soviet period in the longer sweep of Russian history. Was the USSR an aberration from or a consequence of Russian culture? Did the Soviet Union represent a retreat from westernizing trends in Russian history, or was the Bolshevik revolution a product of westernization? These are vexing questions that generate a great deal of debate. Some have argued that in the late nineteenth century Russia was developing a middle class, representative institutions, and an industrial economy that, while although not as advanced as those in Western Europe, were indications of potential movement in the direction of more open government, rule of law, free market capitalism. Only the Bolsheviks, influenced by an ideology imported, paradoxically, from the West, interrupted this path of Russian political and economic westernization.
    [Show full text]
  • Dictatorship of the Proletariat’
    Revolution and the ‘Dictatorship of the Proletariat’ Vanessa Walilko DePaul University March 2004 V.I. Lenin has been accused of being “power-crazed” and “a fanatic believer in a Communist utopia” (Getzler: 464).1 To others, Lenin is considered to be the “greatest thinker to have been produced by the revolutionary working class movement since Marx” (Lukacs: 10). By still others, he is considered a “cynical authoritarian” or a “revolutionary idealist”2 (Rereading: 19). It has also been proposed that Lenin “had a compulsive need to dominate” and that he “was indeed a revolutionary fanatic” (ibid: xvii). Yet Lenin identified one reason for his writings: to clear up those aspects of Marx’s and Engels’ theories which had been “ignored and distorted3 by the opportunists” (State and Revolution: 384, Rereading: 5).4 Despite the fact that Marx and Lenin agreed on many points regarding revolution and the role the proletariat would play after they had secured power for themselves, many of Lenin’s ideas are at the same time quite distinct from the theories that Marx put down in The Communist Manifesto and The Class Struggles in France 1848-1850. This paper will address their similarities and differences in views regarding the necessity of the revolution and the dictatorship of the proletariat. Marx understood that the material conditions of life, particularly the political economy determined human consciousness (Theory and Revolution: 34). Marx believed that history was driven by the class struggle.5 This class antagonism eventually evolved into an open fight which “either ended in a large revolutionary reconstitution of society at large, or in the common ruin of the contending classes” (Manifesto: 1).6 The revolution,7 therefore, was the catalyst for radical social change.
    [Show full text]
  • The Discontents of Marxism
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The discontents of Marxism Freeman, Alan London Metropolitan University 30 December 2007 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/48635/ MPRA Paper No. 48635, posted 27 Jul 2013 14:16 UTC The discontents of Marxism Alan Freeman London Metropolitan University Abstract This is a pre-publication version of a full-length review of Kuhn, R. (2007) Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism. Urbana and U of Illinois. Please cite as Freeman, A. 2008. ‘The Discontents of Marxism’. Debatte, 16 (1), April 2008 pp. 122-131 Keywords: Economics, Marxism, Value Theory, Marxist political economy, Marxist Economics, Kondratieff, Grossman JEL Codes: B14, B31, B51 2008j Grossman Review for MPRA.doc Page 1 of 9 Alan Freeman The discontents of Marxism Review of Kuhn, R. (2007) Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism By Alan Freeman, London Metropolitan University In 1977, volumes 2 and 3 of Capital and Class, journal of the seven-year old Conference of Socialist Economists, carried Pete Burgess’s translation of Henryk Grossman’s 1941 review article Marx, Classical Political Economy and the Problem of Dynamics. Of this Kuhn (p190) justly remarks ‘It was and remains one of the most impressive critiques of the methodological underpinnings of the body of ideas known as economics in most universities and the media’. The second part of this article offers a devastating dissection of the approach known as ‘general equilibrium’, which now dominates not only orthodox but ‘Marxist’ economics. Had the participants in the next thirty years of debate around Marx’s economic theories treated this article with even normal professional diligence, most of what passes for ‘theory’ in this field would probably never have been written.
    [Show full text]
  • The Workers' Inquiry from Trotskyism to Operaismo
    the author(s) 2014 ISSN 1473-2866 (Online) ISSN 2052-1499 (Print) www.ephemerajournal.org volume 14(3): 493-513 The Workers’ Inquiry from Trotskyism to Operaismo: a political methodology for investigating the workplace Jamie Woodcock abstract This article discusses different approaches to conducting a workers’ inquiry. Although there is a certain level of ambiguity in the term, it is taken to mean a method for investigating the workplace from the point of view of the worker. The article aims to examine the methodological concerns involved with conducting a contemporary inquiry and to consider the different debates that have emerged from its use. It examines a particular set of examples from Marx, the breaks from orthodox Trotskyism with the Johnson-Forest Tendency and Socialisme ou Barbarie, and early phase of Operaismo or Italian Workerism. It is intended as a specific intervention that aims to understand what can be learned from an unorthodox Trotskyist interpretation of a workers’ inquiry and how this moment can provide an inspiration for the rethinking and reapplication of Marxism, both in terms of theory and practice, to the changing world. Introduction The aim of this article is to consider what can be learned from a number of different attempts at workers’ inquiries. This will be neither an exclusive nor an exhaustive study, but examine particular moments of interest. The different groups that broke with orthodox Trotskyism and the later Italian tradition sought to critically reassess the changing world around them, something that remains an important task today. The current conjuncture in the UK is characterised by the continuing impact of austerity.
    [Show full text]
  • The Personal, the Political, and Permanent Revolution: Ernest Mandel and the Conflicted Legacies of Trotskyism*
    IRSH 55 (2010), pp. 117–132 doi:10.1017/S0020859009990642 r 2010 Internationaal Instituut voor Sociale Geschiedenis REVIEW ESSAY The Personal, the Political, and Permanent Revolution: Ernest Mandel and the Conflicted Legacies of Trotskyism* B RYAN D. PALMER Canadian Studies, Trent University, Traill College E-mail: [email protected] JAN WILLEM STUTJE. Ernest Mandel: A Rebel’s Dream Deferred. Verso, London [etc.] 2009. 460 pp. $34.95. Biographies of revolutionary Marxists should not be written by the faint of heart. The difficulties are daunting. Which revolutionary tradition is to be given pride of place? Of many Marxisms, which will be extolled, which exposed? What balance will be struck between the personal and the political, a dilemma that cannot be avoided by those who rightly place analytic weight on the public life of organizations and causes and yet understand, as well, how private experience affects not only the individual but the movements, ideas, and developments he or she influenced. Social history’s accent on the particular and its elaboration of context, political biography’s attention to structures, institutions, and debates central to an individual’s life, and intellectual history’s close examination of central ideas and the complexities of their refinement present a trilogy of challenge for any historian who aspires to write the life of someone who was both in history and dedicated to making his- tory. Ernest Mandel was just such a someone, an exceedingly important and troublingly complex figure. * The author thanks Tom Reid, Murray Smith, and Paul Le Blanc for reading an earlier draft of this review, and offering suggestions for revision.
    [Show full text]
  • Marxism and the Solidarity Economy: Toward a New Theory of Revolution
    Class, Race and Corporate Power Volume 9 Issue 1 Article 2 2021 Marxism and the Solidarity Economy: Toward a New Theory of Revolution Chris Wright [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower Part of the Political Science Commons Recommended Citation Wright, Chris (2021) "Marxism and the Solidarity Economy: Toward a New Theory of Revolution," Class, Race and Corporate Power: Vol. 9 : Iss. 1 , Article 2. DOI: 10.25148/CRCP.9.1.009647 Available at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower/vol9/iss1/2 This work is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts, Sciences & Education at FIU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Class, Race and Corporate Power by an authorized administrator of FIU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Marxism and the Solidarity Economy: Toward a New Theory of Revolution Abstract In the twenty-first century, it is time that Marxists updated the conception of socialist revolution they have inherited from Marx, Engels, and Lenin. Slogans about the “dictatorship of the proletariat” “smashing the capitalist state” and carrying out a social revolution from the commanding heights of a reconstituted state are completely obsolete. In this article I propose a reconceptualization that accomplishes several purposes: first, it explains the logical and empirical problems with Marx’s classical theory of revolution; second, it revises the classical theory to make it, for the first time, logically consistent with the premises of historical materialism; third, it provides a (Marxist) theoretical grounding for activism in the solidarity economy, and thus partially reconciles Marxism with anarchism; fourth, it accounts for the long-term failure of all attempts at socialist revolution so far.
    [Show full text]
  • Theory of History in Which the Proletariat Inevitably End up the Dominant Order; This Has Proven Historically to Be False
    9/24/07 Marxism • Marxism is many different kinds of theories at once: • theory of history in which the proletariat inevitably end up the dominant order; this has proven historically to be false. • a critique of capitalism. This body of theory can be relevant to literature, but we’re not going to get into it explicitly. Barry and Richter give some sense of this; for the midterm, I’ll have you learn some terms so that you’ll be at least somewhat conversant with this kind of thinking if you run into it again. • a sort-of-literary theory. I say “sort of” because what Marx and others theorize is larger than literature: “consciousness and its expressions,” which would include not only literature but all of the arts, religion, politics, law, and so on. This is the part of Marxist theory we’re going to center on, because it raises a really huge problem for post-NC Theory in general, or least for all political theories (and we know that, as Barry says, “politics is pervasive” in post-NC theory, so ALL Theory is political according to this view). • Starting point: 410: “In the social production…determines their consciousness.” Some things to point out: • base/superstructure. “Relations of production”--economic system, more or less. At the most fundamental level, people have to survive, and the way we do that as a species is to produce stuff. But we don’t do that on our own; we do it as part of some kind of economic system that we are born into.
    [Show full text]
  • Keywords—Marxism 101 Session 1 Bourgeoisie
    Keywords—Marxism 101 Session 1 Bourgeoisie: the class of modern capitalists, owners of the means of social production and employers of wage labour. Capital: an asset (including money) owned by an individual as wealth used to realize a fnancial proft, and to create additional wealth. Capital exists within the process of economic exchange and grows out of the process of circulation. Capital is the basis of the economic system of capitalism. Capitalism: a mode of production in which capital in its various forms is the principal means of production. Capital can take the form of money or credit for the purchase of labour power and materials of production; of physical machinery; or of stocks of fnished goods or work in progress. Whatever the form, it is the private ownership of capital in the hands of the class of capitalists to the exclusion of the mass of the population. Class: social stratifcation defned by a person's relationship to the means of production. https://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/b/bf/Pyramid_of_Capitalist_System.png Class struggle: an antagonism that exists within a society, catalyzed by competing socioeconomic interests and central to revolutionary change. Communism: 1) a political movement of the working class in capitalist society, committed to the abolition of capitalism 2) a form of society which the working class, through its struggle, would bring into existence through abolition of classes and of the capitalist division of labor. Dictatorship of the Proletariat: the idea that the proletariat (the working class) has control over political power in the process of changing the ownership of the means of production from private to collective ownership as part of a socialist transition to communism.
    [Show full text]
  • Karl Marx's Conception of International Relations
    Knrl Marx's Conception of International nelations Karl Marx's Conception of International Relations Regina Buecker Even though Marx was not widely read during his own time and Marxism, as a political system may be outdated, at least from the present perspective, Karl Marx remains an iconic figure of the 19th century. One of its most influential and controversial philosophers, his thinking has influenced not only the ideology of former and present communist countries, but also the international system as a whole. His theories have had a deep impact on academic studies, and while he did not address the field of international relations directly, much may be derived from his writings on certain phenomena, such as colonialism and nationalism, which are crucial in international relations. The purpose of this paper is to provide a better understanding of Marx's notions of international society. In the following essay, a short overview of Marx's world, concept of man, the state, class and international relations will be given. Finally, the relevance and contributions of Marx's thought to the theory and practice of international relations is analyzed. Historical Context Europe, during Marx's life, was a place "of tremendous social, political and economic change".1 Until Bismark declared on "18th January 187l...the foundation of the German Empire ... " Germany was divided into 38 states of different size and power, and was economically underdeveloped. Almost within one generation, Germany overtook Britain, with respect to 'dynamic development'. The Prussian government, the major political and military unit in Germany, in Marx's time, was conservative and opposed to most reforms.2 Marx was born in 1818 in Trier, a Prussian city near the French border.
    [Show full text]