Scrutinizing Strategy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Scrutinizing Strategy Scrutinizing Strategy The effect of coalition expectations on strategic voting in the Netherlands Arnal Kuntze 24-03-2016 Student number: 0591939 Supervisor: Dr. Jonas Lefevere Master Thesis Political Communication Graduate School of Communication University of Amsterdam 1 Introduction While cycling to the voting booth, Bert Bakker (36) deliberates on which party to vote for during the Dutch general elections. He doubts if a switch from his lifelong favourite, labour party PvdA, is necessary. These last few days he has read several news articles regarding possible future coalitions. According to the latest information the PvdA has absolutely no chance of governing after the elections. Especially the fact that the polls show that his second choice, social democratic party D66, is in a close battle to win a spot in the coalition with the right wing party PVV, his least preferred party, makes the choice even harder. Fifteen minutes and counting before he makes his final call. This case, while fictional, gives a small insight into how during the last decades the habits of the Western voter have changed significantly. As can be seen from the literature, a growing share of the electorate no longer feels connected to longstanding predispositions based on social divisions or identification with a particular party (Hansen et al., 2011; Irwin & Holsteyn, 2008; Meer et al., 2015; Meffert & Gschwend, 2011; Schmitt-Beck & Partheymüller, 2012). Whereas the classic voter had the tendency to engage in a lifelong relationship with a party, the modern-day voter seems to be more rational when choosing which party or candidate to vote for (Fischer, 2004; Meer et al., 2015). The Netherlands is no exception to this rule of changing voting habits. Whereas half a century ago Dutch voting preferences could largely be explained by social class and religion, nowadays these sociological and structured models lack explanatory power (Irwin & Holsteyn, 2008). When a voter casts a ballot on a party other than their preferred party based on strategical considerations this is referred to as strategic voting or tactical voting (Blais & Nadeau, 1996; Cox, 1997; Fischer, 2004; Irwin & Holsteyn, 2012; Mc Cuen & Morton, 2010; Meffert & Gschwend, 2011). The importance of this behaviour is that it has a significant impact on the outcome of an election (Hansen et al., 2011). 2 Many scholars have placed this behaviour within a rational choice theory framework (Blais et al., 2006; Cox, 1997; Downs, 1957; McCuen & Morton, 2010; Meffert & Gschwend, 2009). This implies that these voters are using the information available to them to make rational decision based on the costs and benefits of voting for a particular party. This opens up the space for an inquiry into what kind of information this could be, and in what way it could be instrumental in this consideration. One of the main tasks of a voter in a proportional representation system like the Netherlands is to determine which coalitions are likely to govern after the elections and try to increase the odds of the coalition of their preference (Downs, 1957). They do this mainly on the basis of media coverage based on political polls (Irwin & Holsteyn, 2012). These polls predicts what coalition is likely to be made up after elections. In order to investigate the influence of this media coverage on voters, this study uses an experimental design to present respondents with future coalitions via manipulated news articles (the independent variable) and investigates to what degree these possible outcomes affect the respondent’s vote intention (the dependent variable). For this study, the following research question has been maintained: To what extent does exposure to coalition expectations influence actual strategic voting? This study will extend the literature on strategic voting in the Dutch context by not only testing the relationship between coalition expectations and voting behaviour but also by introducing the influence of an individual’s least preferred party in this matter. This new insight could help parties to understand how to position themselves in the media and what would be the most appropriate way to react to certain other parties in order to obtain more votes in future elections. 3 Furthermore, several studies have shown the influence of political knowledge on an individual’s political behaviour (Dolan & Holbrook, 2011; Gschwend, 2007; Meffert & Gschwend, 2011). For example it could be said that political knowledge influences strategic voting behaviour in a negative way, as those with the highest political sophistication are less inclined to change (Dassonneville & Dejaeghere 2014). This study will also take into account the moderating role of voter’s political knowledge, by testing the following sub question: To what extent is the influence of exposure to coalition expectations on strategic voting moderated by a voter’s political knowledge and a voter’s political orientation? In this thesis I will first discuss the literature already written on the subject, from which I will derive five hypotheses. After this, I will elucidate my methodological framework, showing which choices have been made in order to go about answering the research question. I will then turn to the results derived from several different statistical applied to the data derived from the experimental survey that was conducted amongst 225 participants. Finally, I reflect on these results in the conclusion and discussion by reiterating the connection with the literature discussed. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK The Dutch context This study will examine strategic voting within the Dutch multiparty system. The Dutch electorate is known to drift in their voting choices (Mair, 2008), and nowadays is even considered to be the most volatile in Western Europe (Meer et al., 2015). Distinguishing characteristics of the Dutch political system are the high amount of parties and the relatively open structure of party competition (Mair, 2008). Another important point to take into account 4 when focusing on this context is that the Netherlands is characterized by opposing a ruling minority government. In the Dutch multiparty system the government is expected to possess more than half of the 150 seats in parliament. As in practice no party is able to achieve this amount by its own, this means that parties are forced to rely on post-election bargaining, in order to form a government that is based on a coalition between different parties (Mair, 2008). Downs’ conditions One of the first scholars to write on strategic voting is the American economist Anthony Downs. According to Downs (1957) three conditions need to be satisfied for a voter to act in such a strategic manner. First, it has to be known what possible coalitions each party would enter after the elections. Second, an estimated probability of these different coalitions should be known. Finally, it should be clear which different policies these coalitions would implement if they would be in power. According to Downs these conditions cannot be fulfilled within the context of proportional representation systems such as the Netherlands, because precarious post-election bargaining will determine which coalitions are actually formed and which policies will consequently be implemented (Downs, 1957). This conclusion has been questioned by many authors, including Irwin and Holsteyn (2012). They suggest that adjusting these conditions slightly could make them applicable to a proportional representation system such as the Dutch political system. They rephrase the first condition by stating that voters should have expectations not on the exact coalition that will be formed but rather on what other voters will vote and on what size a party will be after the elections. Results showed that this made the first condition applicable to the Dutch context as Dutch voters in general were able to come up with a fairly accurate estimation on these points (Irwin & Holsteyn, 2012). 5 The second condition focusses on the expectation of a voter in relation to the likelihood of certain coalitions post-election. As Dutch parties will not indicate what possible coalition preferences they might have prior to the elections (Blais et al., 2006), it seems impossible for the Dutch voter to fulfil this condition. Despite this seemingly crucial lack of information, voters have still found ways to come up with fairly correct expectations to anticipate the future government compositions (Armstrong & Duch, 2010). One key source for the Dutch voter are public opinion polls, as it is shown that Dutch voters rely mostly on them to form their expectations (Irwin & Holsteyn, 2012). Finally, the third condition of Downs is rephrased as voters being able to estimate what compromises a party will make in the coalition bargaining stage of forming a governmental program. This condition for a Dutch voter is not possible to know, as the party elite does not even know what compromises will be made (Fischer, 2004; Irwin & Holsteyn, 2012). On the other side it is shown that if Dutch voters are presented with coalition expectations, they will be able to make optimal strategic voting decisions, beneficial to their own preferences (Irwin & Holsteyn, 2012). This study follows Irwin and Holsteyn’s conclusion that Down’s conditions are in some respect applicable to proportional representation systems. Strategic voting Now we have established that strategic voting can occur within the Dutch multiparty system, a closer look into the topic of strategic voting is useful
Recommended publications
  • Lessons on Voting Reform from Britian's First Pr Elections
    WHAT WE ALREADY KNOW: LESSONS ON VOTING REFORM FROM BRITIAN'S FIRST PR ELECTIONS by Philip Cowley, University of Hull John Curtice, Strathclyde UniversityICREST Stephen Lochore, University of Hull Ben Seyd, The Constitution Unit April 2001 WHAT WE ALREADY KNOW: LESSONS ON VOTING REFORM FROM BRITIAN'S FIRST PR ELECTIONS Published by The Constitution Unit School of Public Policy UCL (University College London) 29/30 Tavistock Square London WClH 9QU Tel: 020 7679 4977 Fax: 020 7679 4978 Email: [email protected] Web: www.ucl.ac.uk/constitution-unit/ 0 The Constitution Unit. UCL 200 1 This report is sold subject ot the condition that is shall not, by way of trade or otherwise, be lent, hired out or otherwise circulated without the publisher's prior consent in any form of binding or cover other than that in which it is published and without a similar condition including this condition being imposed on the subsequent purchaser. First published April 2001 Contents Introduction ................................................................................................... 3 Executive Summary ..................................................................................4 Voters' attitudes to the new electoral systems ...........................................................4 Voters' behaviour under new electoral systems ......................................................... 4 Once elected .... The effect of PR on the Scottish Parliament in Practice ..................5 Voter Attitudes to the New Electoral Systems ............................................6
    [Show full text]
  • Strategic Coalition Voting: Evidence from Austria Meffert, Michael F.; Gschwend, Thomas
    www.ssoar.info Strategic coalition voting: evidence from Austria Meffert, Michael F.; Gschwend, Thomas Veröffentlichungsversion / Published Version Zeitschriftenartikel / journal article Zur Verfügung gestellt in Kooperation mit / provided in cooperation with: SSG Sozialwissenschaften, USB Köln Empfohlene Zitierung / Suggested Citation: Meffert, M. F., & Gschwend, T. (2010). Strategic coalition voting: evidence from Austria. Electoral Studies, 29(3), 339-349. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.electstud.2010.03.005 Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Dieser Text wird unter einer Deposit-Lizenz (Keine This document is made available under Deposit Licence (No Weiterverbreitung - keine Bearbeitung) zur Verfügung gestellt. Redistribution - no modifications). We grant a non-exclusive, non- Gewährt wird ein nicht exklusives, nicht übertragbares, transferable, individual and limited right to using this document. persönliches und beschränktes Recht auf Nutzung dieses This document is solely intended for your personal, non- Dokuments. Dieses Dokument ist ausschließlich für commercial use. All of the copies of this documents must retain den persönlichen, nicht-kommerziellen Gebrauch bestimmt. all copyright information and other information regarding legal Auf sämtlichen Kopien dieses Dokuments müssen alle protection. You are not allowed to alter this document in any Urheberrechtshinweise und sonstigen Hinweise auf gesetzlichen way, to copy it for public or commercial purposes, to exhibit the Schutz beibehalten werden. Sie dürfen dieses Dokument document in public, to perform, distribute or otherwise use the nicht in irgendeiner Weise abändern, noch dürfen Sie document in public. dieses Dokument für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke By using this particular document, you accept the above-stated vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, aufführen, vertreiben oder conditions of use. anderweitig nutzen. Mit der Verwendung dieses Dokuments erkennen Sie die Nutzungsbedingungen an.
    [Show full text]
  • The Many Faces of Strategic Voting
    Revised Pages The Many Faces of Strategic Voting Strategic voting is classically defined as voting for one’s second pre- ferred option to prevent one’s least preferred option from winning when one’s first preference has no chance. Voters want their votes to be effective, and casting a ballot that will have no influence on an election is undesirable. Thus, some voters cast strategic ballots when they decide that doing so is useful. This edited volume includes case studies of strategic voting behavior in Israel, Germany, Japan, Belgium, Spain, Switzerland, Canada, and the United Kingdom, providing a conceptual framework for understanding strategic voting behavior in all types of electoral systems. The classic definition explicitly considers strategic voting in a single race with at least three candidates and a single winner. This situation is more com- mon in electoral systems that have single- member districts that employ plurality or majoritarian electoral rules and have multiparty systems. Indeed, much of the literature on strategic voting to date has considered elections in Canada and the United Kingdom. This book contributes to a more general understanding of strategic voting behavior by tak- ing into account a wide variety of institutional contexts, such as single transferable vote rules, proportional representation, two- round elec- tions, and mixed electoral systems. Laura B. Stephenson is Professor of Political Science at the University of Western Ontario. John Aldrich is Pfizer- Pratt University Professor of Political Science at Duke University. André Blais is Professor of Political Science at the Université de Montréal. Revised Pages Revised Pages THE MANY FACES OF STRATEGIC VOTING Tactical Behavior in Electoral Systems Around the World Edited by Laura B.
    [Show full text]
  • Thresholds Quantifying Proportionality Criteria for Election Methods
    THRESHOLDS QUANTIFYING PROPORTIONALITY CRITERIA FOR ELECTION METHODS SVANTE JANSON Abstract. We define several different thresholds for election methods by considering different scenarios, corresponding to different proportion- ality criteria that have been proposed by various authors. In particular, we reformulate the criteria known as DPC, PSC, JR, PJR, EJR in our setting. We consider multi-winner election methods of different types, using ballots with unordered lists of candidates or ordered lists, and for comparison also methods using only party lists. The thresholds are cal- culated for many different election methods. The considered methods include classical ones such as BV, SNTV and STV (with some results going back to e.g. Droop and Dodgson in the 19th century); we also study in detail several perhaps lesser known methods by Phragm´en and Thiele. There are also many cases left as open problems. Contents 1. Introduction 2 2. Notations and general definitions 5 2.1. Some notation 5 2.2. Proportionality thresholds 7 3. General properties 11 4. Party ballots 13 4.1. Unordered and ordered ballots 17 5. Unordered ballots: Block Vote, SNTV, Limited Vote, . 17 6. JR, PJR, EJR 24 7. Phragm´en’s and Thiele’s unordered methods 30 arXiv:1810.06377v1 [cs.GT] 12 Oct 2018 7.1. The party list case 30 7.2. Phragm´en’s method 30 7.3. Thiele’s optimization method 32 7.4. Thiele’s addition method 33 7.5. Thiele’s elimination method 41 7.6. Thiele’s optimization method with general weights 42 7.7. Thiele’s addition method with general weights 45 8.
    [Show full text]
  • Rational Behavior and Information in Strategic Voting
    RATIONALITY AND INFORMATION IN STRATEGIC VOTING DISSERTATION Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate School of Ohio State University By Andrew R. Tomlinson, M.A. * * * * * The Ohio State University 2001 Dissertation Committee: Approved by Professor Herbert F. Weisberg, Adviser Professor Paul Allen Beck __________________________________ Adviser Professor Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier Political Science Graduate Program ABSTRACT In recent years, third parties and independent candidacies have become an important part of the American political system. Yet few of these parties or candidates have been able to win office. Strategic voting by supporters of third party and independent candidates often siphons off potential votes for those candidates, and leads to their loss. Much of the work that has been done on strategic voting leaves out some crucial elements of the voting process. In this dissertation I fill some of the gaps in the extant literature. Using data from the 1998 Gubernatorial election in Minnesota and the 1994 U.S. Senate election in Virginia, I show how the amount of strategic voting was drastically different in the two elections. I then use the Virginia data to model the vote choice of supporters of the third- place candidate with the correct, theoretically-based model. Next, I content analyze newspaper coverage of the two elections, in order to examine the role of the media in shaping the decision to vote strategically or sincerely. I find that there was more coverage of candidate negativity and more coverage of the horserace aspect of the campaign in Virginia than in Minnesota.
    [Show full text]
  • Tactical Voting and How the Left Should Deal with the Governing Coalition
    NEW POLITICS Tactical voting and how the left should deal with the governing coalition Neal Lawson and Joe Cox NEW POLITICS Tactical voting and how the left should deal with the governing coalition Neal Lawson and Joe Cox 3 Introduction to compromise with anyone outside Labour’s ranks who are viewed with varying degrees of In the run up to the 2010 general election consid- suspicion. Socialism, to the tribalist, is largely erable polling showed support moving away from seen as what a Labour government does. If it is the Labour Party in favour of the Conservatives not said or done by Labour, then it is unlikely and the Liberal Democrats. to be viewed as progressive. Pluralists on the With Election Day fast-approaching, on 23 other hand see power as more diffuse; there are April the Compass Management Committee many competing centres of power that have to balloted all members on whether to support a be recognised, respected and dealt with through policy of tactical voting in order to help deprive dialogue, cooperation and competition. For the the Conservative Party of a majority government pluralist, engagement with others is felt to be a in the general election. With the biggest return positive process through which we learn, adapt Compass has had in an internal ballot, 72% (467) and build coalitions. Pluralism and tribalism of members backed the call for tactical voting are thus very different ways of trying to make with only 14% (93) against.1 change happen. We know that some in the Labour Party opposed and continue to be critical of this move, but it is important not for the past but for the “Compass is continually trying to develop and future that the issue is fully aired and discussed.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Extent of Strategic Voting∗
    On the Extent of Strategic Voting Jorg¨ L. Spenkuch University of Chicago November 2012 Abstract Social scientists have long speculated about individuals' tendencies to manipulate elections by misrepresenting their preferences. The fact that preference orderings are generally unobserved, however, has made it very difficult to document strategic behavior empirically. Exploiting the incentive structure of Germany's voting system to solve the fundamental identification problem, this paper estimates the extent of strategic voting in large, real-world elections. Evidence from reduced form as well as structural methods indicates that almost one third of voters abandons their most preferred candidate if she is not in contention for victory. As predicted by theory, tactical behavior has a non-trivial impact on individual races. Yet, as one aggregates across districts, these distortions partially offset each other, resulting in considerably more modest effects on the overall distribution of seats. I am especially grateful to Gary Becker, Roland Fryer, Steven Levitt, and Roger Myerson for many helpful conversations and continued encouragement. Moreover, I have benefitted from comments by Scott Ashworth, Eric Budish, Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, Dana Chandler, Tony Cookson, Will Dobbie, Alex Frankel, Richard Holden, Kenneth Mirkin, Matthew Notowidigdo, Elisa Olivieri, Jesse Shapiro, Jan Stoop, Philipp Tillmann, David Toniatti, and Richard Van Weelden, as well as seminar participants at the University of Chicago and the Calvo-Armengol Prize Workshop (Barcelona GSE). I am also indebted to Gabriele Sch¨omelat the office of the Bundeswahlleiter for assistance in acquiring the data used in this paper, and to Che-Lin Su and Jeremy Fox for supplying me with their computer programs.
    [Show full text]
  • Voting Systems: from Method to Algorithm
    Voting Systems: From Method to Algorithm A Thesis Presented to The Faculty of the Com puter Science Department California State University Channel Islands In (Partial) Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree M asters of Science in Com puter Science b y Christopher R . Devlin Advisor: Michael Soltys December 2019 © 2019 Christopher R. Devlin ALL RIGHTS RESERVED APPROVED FOR MS IN COMPUTER SCIENCE Advisor: Dr. Michael Soltys Date Name: Dr. Bahareh Abbasi Date Name: Dr. Vida Vakilian Date APPROVED FOR THE UNIVERITY Name Date Acknowledgements I’d like to thank my wife, Eden Byrne for her patience and support while I completed this Masters Degree. I’d also like to thank Dr. Michael Soltys for his guidance and mentorship. Additionally I’d like to thank the faculty and my fellow students at CSUCI who have given nothing but assistance and encouragement during my time here. Voting Systems: From Method to Algorithm Christopher R. Devlin December 18, 2019 Abstract Voting and choice aggregation are used widely not just in poli­ tics but in business decision making processes and other areas such as competitive bidding procurement. Stakeholders and others who rely on these systems require them to be fast, efficient, and, most impor­ tantly, fair. The focus of this thesis is to illustrate the complexities inherent in voting systems. The algorithms intrinsic in several voting systems are made explicit as a way to simplify choices among these systems. The systematic evaluation of the algorithms associated with choice aggregation will provide a groundwork for future research and the implementation of these tools across public and private spheres.
    [Show full text]
  • Proportional Representation in Theory and Practice the Australian Experience
    Proportional Representation in Theory and Practice The Australian Experience Glynn Evans Department of Politics and International Relations School of Social Sciences The University of Adelaide June 2019 Table of Contents Abstract ii Statement of Authorship iii Acknowledgements iv Preface vi 1. Introduction 1 2. District Magnitude, Proportionality and the Number of 30 Parties 3. District Magnitude and Partisan Advantage in the 57 Senate 4. District Magnitude and Partisan Advantage in Western 102 Australia 5. District Magnitude and Partisan Advantage in South Eastern Jurisdictions 132 6. Proportional Representation and Minor Parties: Some 170 Deviating Cases 7. Does Proportional Representation Favour 204 Independents? 8. Proportional Representation and Women – How Much 231 Help? 9. Conclusion 247 Bibliography 251 Appendices 260 i Abstract While all houses of Australian parliaments using proportional representation use the Single Transferable Vote arrangement, district magnitudes (the numbers of members elected per division) and requirements for casting a formal vote vary considerably. Early chapters of this thesis analyse election results in search for distinct patterns of proportionality, the numbers of effective parties and partisan advantage under different conditions. This thesis argues that while district magnitude remains the decisive factor in determining proportionality (the higher the magnitude, the more proportional the system), ballot paper numbering requirements play a more important role in determining the number of (especially) parliamentary parties. The general pattern is that, somewhat paradoxically, the more freedom voters have to choose their own preference allocations, or lack of them, the smaller the number of parliamentary parties. Even numbered magnitudes in general, and six member divisions in particular, provide some advantage to the Liberal and National Parties, while the Greens are disadvantaged in five member divisions as compared to six or seven member divisions.
    [Show full text]
  • Phragm\'En's and Thiele's Election Methods
    PHRAGMEN’S´ AND THIELE’S ELECTION METHODS SVANTE JANSON Abstract. The election methods introduced in 1894–1895 by Phragm´en and Thiele, and their somewhat later versions for ordered (ranked) bal- lots, are discussed in detail. The paper includes definitions and examples and discussion of whether the methods satisfy some properties, includ- ing monotonicity, consistency and various proportionality criteria. The relation with STV is also discussed. The paper also contains historical information on the methods. Contents 1. Introduction 2 1.1. Background 3 1.2. Contents of the paper 4 2. Assumptions and notation 4 2.1. Some notation 6 3. Phragm´en’s unordered method 6 3.1. Phragm´en’s formulation 6 3.2. An equivalent formulation 8 3.3. An example 10 4. Thiele’s unordered methods 12 4.1. Thiele’s optimization method 13 4.2. Thiele’s addition method 14 4.3. Thiele’s elimination method 15 4.4. An example 15 5. House monotonicity 17 arXiv:1611.08826v2 [math.HO] 12 Oct 2018 6. Unordered ballots, principles 18 7. Unordered ballots and decapitation 19 8. Ordered ballots, principles 20 9. Phragm´en’s ordered method 20 9.1. First formulation 21 9.2. Second formulation 21 9.3. Third formulation 22 9.4. An example 23 10. Thiele’s ordered method 24 10.1. An example 25 11. Phragm´en’s and Thiele’s methods generalize D’Hondt’s 25 Date: 27 November, 2016; revised 25 April, 2017 and 28 September, 2018. 1 2 SVANTE JANSON 12. Electing a single person 26 13. Examples 27 14.
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral Terminology.Pdf
    Terminology for Concurrence on Voter Representation / Electoral Systems (provided by proposers) Voter Representation/ Electoral System Concurrence Position Why? The League of Women Voters currently does not have a position on how we elect our representatives Our Mission, our Principles (“We believe in Representative Government”) and our trademark “Making Democracy Work” all speak to empowering voters through representation. When voters are denied representation because of where they live, the way district lines are drawn, or because they are an ethnic or political minority, apathy shouldn’t be a surprise. The purpose of having this position is to provide a clear, but flexible base of principles, for evaluating electoral systems that empower voters. (language is from 14 State LWV positions) The electoral systems we use can enhance or deny representation of voters just as how, and who draws district lines, can do the same. The position does not support a particular electoral system as no system is perfect. However, some are better than others at enhancing representation for voters. This position is based on criterion, (not ballot systems) to consider when evaluating electoral options that meet the needs of a community and the voters. This position does not require local/state League action. Like many of our positions, it is there when we need it. For instance, many California communities are looking at options to plurality voting as a result of California Voting Right Act violations. There may be a different scenario in your state, but one in which this concurrence would apply. Terminology (in alpha order) Electoral systems are tied to representation of voters, so we are providing some basic information on electoral terminology.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Extent of Strategic Voting
    On the Extent of Strategic Voting Jorg¨ L. Spenkuch University of Chicago November 2012 Job Market Paper Abstract Social scientists have long speculated about individuals’ tendencies to manipulate elections by misrepresenting their preferences. The fact that preference orderings are generally unobserved, however, has made it very dicult to document strategic behavior empirically. Exploiting the incentive structure of Germany’s voting system to solve the fundamental identification problem, this paper estimates the extent of strategic voting in large, real-world elections. Evidence from reduced form as well as structural methods indicates that almost one third of voters abandons their most preferred candidate if she is not in contention for victory. As predicted by theory, tactical behavior has a non-trivial impact on individual races. Yet, as one aggregates across districts, these distortions partially oset each other, resulting in considerably more modest eects on the overall distribution of seats. I am especially grateful to Gary Becker, Roland Fryer, Steven Levitt, and Roger Myerson for many helpful conversations and continued encouragement. Moreover, I have benefitted from comments by Scott Ashworth, Eric Budish, Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, Dana Chandler, Tony Cookson, Will Dobbie, Alex Frankel, Richard Holden, Kenneth Mirkin, Matthew Notowidigdo, Elisa Olivieri, Jesse Shapiro, Jan Stoop, Philipp Tillmann, David Toniatti, and Richard Van Weelden, as well as seminar participants at the University of Chicago and the Calv´o-Armengol Prize Workshop (Barcelona GSE). I am also indebted to Gabriele Sch¨omel at the oce of the Bundeswahlleiter for assistance in acquiring the data used in this paper, and to Che-Lin Su and Jeremy Fox for supplying me with their computer programs.
    [Show full text]