IMPACT OF ECONOMIC LIBERALISATION ON EMPLOYMENT STRUCTURE IN

DISSERTATION Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Award of the Degree of fD^^tnt of pf|ilo;8tipIiy IN '^ ^ GEOGRAPHY v*^.

^\ v\'' \ -f . By ^ fi' t. /' Sharqua Iloori Bnsari

"-'tsc. -•"^

Under the Supervision of Pnof. Saveed ilhmad Khan

DEPARTMENT OF GEOGRAPHY MUSLIM UNIVERSITY ALIGARH () 2010 DS4215

2 2 M 2C13 ftA tn Cr.mt)tit^ DEPARTMENT OF GEOGRAPHY FACULTY OF SCIENCE ALIGARH MUSLIM UNIVERSITY, ALIGARH - 202 002 (INDIA)

Phone: 0571-2700683 Fax: 0571-2700528

(Dated.. AP.:.K.^.'L'.'i Certificate

This is to certify that Ms, Sharqua No&ri Ansari has . ' * ' ' ' ' completed her M.Phil, dissertation entitled "!Bb» Imptict of

Economic Liberalisation on Employment Structure in

Uttar Pradesh'^, under my supervision. To the best of my knowledge, the work is original.

A^r i (Prof Sayeed Ahmad Khan) Supervisor H 1

to m^ "Barents

L— , ji CONTENTS

Page No.

Acknowledgement

List of Tables

List of Figures

Chapter -1 Economic Liberalisation (Conceptual framework) 1

Origin of the Concept

Globalisation

Impact of Liberalisation on Economy

Impact of Liberalisation on Employment

Organised and Unorganised Sector

Chapter - 11 The Economic Liberalisation in India 19

The Beginning

Consequences of Economic Liberalisation

Chapter-III Literature Review 36 Chapter - IV Uttar Pradesh: A Geographical Outline 51

Physical Aspects

Social Aspects

Chapter - V Impact of Economic Liberalisation on 69

Employment Structure in Uttar Pradesh:

An Analysis

Trends of Employment Change in Three Sectors of the

Economy

Correlation Coefficient Technique

Conclusion

Proposed Plan for Ph.D. Work 111

Bibliography 112

Annexure 120 Acknowledgement

I express my deep sense of gratitude to my respected supervisor Prof. Sayeed Ahmad Khan, Department of Geography, Aligarh Muslim University, for his inspiring thought, provoking suggestions, constructive criticism, support and sympathy during the course of this work. I am also grateful to Prof. Farasat AH Siddiqui, Chairman Department of Geography, Aligarh Muslim University, for providing me all possible help during the.course of my work. I offer my sincere most thanks to all my teachers, my seniors, research mates, and juniors for their help and support. I am also thankful to the staff of central and departmental library for their help and cooperation. And veiy special thanks to Dr. Fatma Maher Sultana, and Dr. Sabah Aapa. for their continuous support and encouragement, that made this dissertation possible. I feel bestowed with an honor in acknowledging my indebtedness and heartful thanks to my parents. Their constant support and encouragement made my dissertation possible. I would especially like to thank my mother, in particular for her strength and support, who stood by my side in all odds. I would like to share my deep sense of love and affection to my brothers Md. Ishraque and Md. Afaque for their unfailing love and support throughout my life. Last but not the least, I am highly thankful to my loving friends and caring room mates namely, Nazia, Nigar, Mariyam, Shabana, Aliya, Shaista, Shama, Shaista Khan, Laxmi, Bushra, Anjum, Nikhat for their continuous support and help.

(Sharqiia Noori Ansari) List of Tables

Table No. Titles

2.1 Trends in India's FDI and Trade Flows (1980 to 2003)

2.2 Distribution of India's Total Workers, and its Change

2.3 Trends in Employment Structure in India (in Million)

2.4 Workforce Participation Rate of Male and Female in Urban

and Rural areas in India

4.1 Trends in Population Growth in Uttar Pradesh & India

4.2 Sector Wise Share of GDP (%) in Uttar Pradesh

4.3 Trends of Urbanisation in India

5.1 Distribution of Workforce across Sectors and its Change

in Uttar Pradesh

5.2 Loss of Primary Activities

5.3 Loss of Secondary Activities

5.4 Gains in Tertiary Activities

5.5 Per Capita Income of India and Uttar Pradesh (Rs.)

5.6 District wise Per Capita Income of Uttar Pradesh, 1997-98 (Rs.)

5.7 Distribution of Per Capita Income

5.8 Sectoral Distribution of Workforce in Primary Sector

5.9 Sectoral Distribution of Workforce in Secondary Sector

5.10 Sectoral Distribution of Workforce in Tertiary Sector

5.11 Showing Correlations between District Wise Per Capita Income

With Primary, Secondary, Tertiary Sectors List of Figures

Figure No. Titles

2.1 Estimated Increase in Labour Force

4.1 Location Map - Uttar Pradesh

4.2 Districts in Uttar Pradesh

4.3 Distribution of GSDP of Uttar Pradesh

5.1 Loss of Primary Activities

5.2 Loss of Secondary Activities

5.3 Gains in Tertiary Activities

5.4 Uttar Pradesh - Per Capita Income Chapter -1 Economic Liberalisation -

(Conceptual framework)

Origin of the Concept

Globalisation

Impact of Liberalisation on Economy * Impact of Liberalisation on Employment

Organised and Unorganised Sector Chapter -1

Economic Liberalisation - Conceptual framework

Economic Liberalisation means removal of barriers from inter-country trades. It refers to the process of a country opening its market to outside forces as a way of becoming more integrated into the global economy. The term emerged in the late 18th and early 19th centuries and emphasised the pre­ eminence of the individual and its freedom. Economic liberalisation is defined, as any act that would make the trade regime more neutral, nearer to trade system free of government intervention (Papageorgion et.al.l990). It is a policy of promoting liberal economics by limiting the role of government to the market economy that works efficiently, this can include privatisation and deregulation. Thus, liberalisation refers to a decrease in usually the intervention of the state/government in particular areas of social and economic policy.

Liberalisation, in the globalisation context is normally used to refer to a more

'Laissez Faire' approach to economic matters. This classically involves privatisation of previously state run enterprises as well as the opening up of economic borders for the purpose of trade and foreign investment. Such policies and actions are also referred to as being neoliberal. Privatisation and general deregulation are core features of liberalisation. Global financial institutions such as International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Trade

Organisafion (WTO) are largely predicated on the positive value of liberalisation. Liberalisation also refers to a modem view of society that can be seen as threat to social values, particularly those of social cohesion and community (Rodrik 1997, Tomell 2005). The process of economic liberalisation and market oriented economic reforms had started in many developing countries in early 1980's but intensified after 1991. Recent developments in trade policy literature focus on the potential dynamic effects

of trade liberalisation in reducing rent seeking behavior and in accelerating the

flow of technical knowledge from the world market. The benefits are derived

from the greater access to new capital and intermediate goods, and also due to

greater knowledge leading to faster imitation of advanced techniques (Romer

1994, Grossman and Helpman 1995). Finally, an increase in openness is

equated with an increase in the importance of trade in the economy as

percentage of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) (Pritchet 1996). A good measure

of trade policy ought to capture differences between neutral, inward oriented

and export promoting regime (Harrison 1996). Some scholars, (Nishimizu and

Robinson 1984) argue that, there is an implicit, 'Challenge-Response'

mechanism induced by competition from trade reforms. This argument assumes

that, there is a satisfying and optimising behavior on part of the finns as

regards the business objective. This is due to insufficient competitive pressure

prevailing in a regime closed to foreign trade. (Rodrik 1992), has pointed out it

is possible to argue analytically that a protected market, by ensuring a large

market share for the domestic producers, will make it worth while to invest in

productivity enhancing technology. Trade Liberalisation also enables cheaper

and easier access to foreign technologies and global capital and makes possible greater international exchange of information. Lowering of trade restrictions make possible the import of capital and intermediate goods which embody superior technology and this helps in reducing costs and also in turn increasing

productivity growth in the sectors those uses these using products.

Origin of the Concept

The liberal theory of economics is believed, to be first fully formulated

by Adam Smith which advocates minimal interference of the government in the

economy. The case for economic liberalism which began to be argued in the

eighteenth centur\' was, then startling claim that, if everyone is left to their own

economic devices instead of being controlled by the state, then the result would

be a harmonious and more equal society of ever increasing prosperity. It is the

economic component of the political ideology of classical liberalism. The

concept of economic liberalism or market liberalism underpinned the move

towards a free market capitalist economic system in the late 18th century, and

the subsequent demise of the mercantilist system. Today, the liberal theory of

economics is strongly associated with libertarianism, neoliberal economics.

Initially, the liberal theory of economics had to contend with the supporters of

feudal privileges for the wealthy, aristocratic traditions and the rights of kings

to run national economies in their own personal interests. By the end of the

19th century and the beginning of the 20th, these were largely defeated. Neoliberalism

Neoliberalism refers to a political movement that espouses economic liberalism as a means of promoting economic development and securing political liberty. The movement is sometimes described as an effort to revert to the economic policies of the 18th and 19th century's classical liberalism.

Strictly in the context of English language usage the term is an abbreviation of

'neoclassical liberalism', since in other languages 'liberalism', minus any modifier such as 'social' (as in social liberalism), has more or less retained its classical meaning. Neoliberalism refers to a historically specific re-emergence of economic liberalism's influence among economic scholars and policy makers during the 1970s and late 1990s, and possibly into the present. In many respects, the term is used to denote a group of neoclassical by influenced economic theories, right wing libertarian political philosophies, and political rhetoric that portrayed government control over the economy as inefficient, comipt or otherwise undesirable. Neoliberal arguments gained a great deal of clout after the Stagflation Crisis of the 1970s, the Developing World Debt

Crisis of the 1980s, and the Soviet Collapse of the early 1990s. Neoliberalism is that it is to bring compassion to the people of a nation through social equality and employment freedom and civil right. Globalisation

Globalisation, describe as an ongoing process by which regional economies, societies, and cultures have become integrated through a globe spanning network of communication and execution. The term is sometimes used to refer specifically to, Economic Globalisation: the integration of national economies into the international economy through trade, foreign direct investment, capital flows, migration, and the spread of technology. However, globalisation is usually recognised as being driven by a combination of economic, technological, socio-cultural, political and biological factors. It had achieved widespread use in the mainstream press by the later half of the 1980s.

Since its inception, the concept of globalisation has inspired numerous competing definitions and interpretations. The United Nation, has written that globalisation is a widely used term that can be defined in a number of different ways, when used in an economic context, it refers to the reduction and removal of barriers between national borders in order to facilitate the flow of goods, capital, services and labour, although considerable barriers remain to the flow of labour. Globalisation is not a new phenomenon, it began in the late nineteenth century, but it slowed down, from the start of the First Worid War and remained the same till, the third quarter of the twentieth century.-Herman

E. Daly, argues that sometimes the terms intemationalisation and globalisation are used interchangeably but there is a significant formal difference. The term

'intemationalisation' refers to the importance of international trade, relations, treaties etc. owing to the hypothetical immobility of labour and capital between or among nations. Globalisation is the process that arises spontaneously in the

market and acts by developing a progressive international division of labour,

eliminating restrictions on individual liberties, reducing transportation and

communication costs, and increasingly integrating the individuals that compose

the great society. It is expressed as: economic globalisation, namely, the

opening and deregulation of commodity, capital and labour markets which led

to the present form of neoliberal globalisation, political globalisation, cultural

globalisation, i.e., the worldwide homogenisation of culture, ideological

globalisation, technological globalisation, and social globalisation. The whole

idea of globalisation therefore, revolves around other new realities and

terminologies as, information technology, deregulation, trade liberaHsation,

economic competition or free enterprises and an emergent poHtical

structure/system that is people oriented etc. More explicitly, perhaps, it refers

to a process of increasing economic openness, growing economic

interdependence and deepening economic integration between countries of the

world. It is associated to not only a phenomenal spread and volume of cross

border economic transactions, but also with an organisation of economic

activities which straddles national boundaries. The breakdown of boundaries as

barriers to economic exploitation that globalisation represents means that every

country of this world, rich/developed or poor/developing would have access to

every other country. That is, the developing nations would have access to the

markets of the developed countries, unrestricted and vice versa, 'it will be a borderless world'. Roseanne and Giddiness, define 'globalisation is a central 7 driving force behind the rapid social, poHtical and economic changes that are reshaping modem societies and world order'. According to their views,

'contemporary patterns of globalisation are conceived as historically unprecedented such that the governments (states) and societies across the globe

are having to adjust to a world in which there is no longer a clear distinction

between international and domestic, external and internal affairs'. It is also true

that globalisation is seen here as a powerful transformative force which is

responsible for a 'massive shake-out' of societies, economies, institutions of

governance and world order. Globalisation is a multi-sided phenomenon

involving increasing interdependence and interaction between people

worldwide across a range of economic, political, cultural and environmental

dimensions. Globalisation has been facilitated by advancement in

communication and transport, which have reduced the cost and extended the

range of available options for global commerce and cultural interaction.

Furthermore, this has been associated with a significant increase in the level of

global economic production, which, in turn, has led to global environmental

consequences such as those arising from increased levels of greenhouse gases.

In addition, rapid communication and global media coverage often result in

localised environmental and social issues receiving worldwide attention and

increasingly outside intervention of one kind or another in foreign countries.

Processes making for globalisation have been operating for centuries but the

history involved is varied and complex. Such factors as the rise of nation states, the establishment of regional trading blocks, European geographical 8 discoveries, the rise and fall of empires, as well as technological advances, have all played a role. A major influence in recent decades has been the push to reduce man made trading barriers between nations, and consequently facilitates greater freedom of international trade. In the last three decades or so, reduction in international trade barriers (such as those posed by tariffs, import quotas and qualitative restrictions) have significantly facilitated economic globalisation.

The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and its successor, the

World Trade Organisation (WTO), have played a major role in this process. So, have the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank in terms of advice given to governments and conditions imposed on loans to nations requiring economic assistance. Such international institutions have put pressure on all nations (including Bangladesh) to embrace international free trade and make maximum use of free market mechanisms in organising economic activity within their own countries. The general principles involving small government and free markets are contained in the so called 'Washington

Consensus.' Benefits claimed by international bodies such as the Wodd Bank and WTO for global economic liberalisation, include the following:

• Greater efficiency in satisfying human wants in relation to resource use,

as predicted by neoclassical economic theory,

• Poverty alleviation, particularly in the longer term,

• Acceleration of economic growth.

According to Herman E. Daly, globalisation serves the vision of a single, cosmopolitan, integrated global economy. This definition focuses on the cross border movement of goods, services and resources (financial and human) impact on the domestic and global assets and employment. Globalisation focuses on an integrated economic world in which the economy is a single market characterised by trade and investment flows, cross border economic activities in production, investment financing, movement of capital, technology, labor, intemationalisation of consumption, capital, and services.

Economic liberalisation is the gateway of globalisation and financial liberation plays the most crucial role in integration of one country's economy on the global economic network. In the very beginning, important instruments of liberalisation are regulation of financial market to allow foreign capital, foreign investment, to and fro flow of capital, reduction of tariff and non tariff barriers of trade, simplifications of customs measures. For successful global integration a country must move to economic liberalisation by dismantling entry barriers and licensing system, reduction in physical restrictions on imports, reduction in control on capital and current account, reforming financial system and opening up financial market to private (domestic and foreign) players, removing controls on foreign capital (FDI) flow to the country etc. Liberalisation and globalisation produces immense benefits to the countries integrated with each other. Liberalisation creates conducive climate for faster economic growth, allows upgradation of technology, provide scale economy, expansion of markets domestically and internationally. Economic integration through liberalisation can also expand job opportunities in domestic market and migration of labour in general. Financial Globalisation produces higher 10 economic growth through direct and indirect impact on economy.

Liberalisation and globalisation produce immense benefits to the countries integrated. Financial Liberalisation has forced many countries to open up financial markets and relax the rules of intermediation allowing financial services institutions like investment banks, asset management companies, mutual funds, pension funds, to operate in newly liberalised markets. The forces of change unleashed by financial globalisation, reflected in disintermediation of banking system, increase in cross border financial activity increased competition in savings market convergence in financial services industry. A major breakthrough was achieved in 1997 with an agreement of liberalisation of financial services following which 102 countries committed to remove entry barriers and liberalise their markets. The General Agreement on

Tariffs and Trade (GATT) agreement offers legal security and protection to global insurance players. Impact of Liberalisation on Economy

There are many studies based on the orthodox supply tradition which explain the impact of trade liberalisation on export growth in developing countries. Some such investigations confirm that the countries that embarked on liberalisation programmes have improved their export performance (Thomas et al. 1991, Weiss 1992, Joshi and Little 1996, Helleiner 1994, and Ahmed

2000). Regardless, surveying in the 1990s, (Bhalla 2005) believes that India has had the best of both worlds, combining growth with equity, and that it has been to reduce poverty and place a considerable degree of restraint on inequality while maintaining high economic growth. The implication is that the sectors that gain in productivity are exportable sectors and the import competing sectors have a non positive impact as far as technological change is concerned. (Nagarj 2005) examine, that some positive features show, in India's record its industry is more competitive, largely dependent on local demand and local content, and predominantly domestically owned. Besides sustained industrial growth, globalisation and liberalisation have made possible breakthrough in new areas of economic strength, information technology, pharmaceuticals, and automobile components. In the case of computer software, India has emerged as a major economic power. It is hard to imagine that such development would have been possible without globalisation and liberalisation. On the other hand, there is little evidence to uphold the relationship between trade liberalisation and export growth (UNCTAD 1989,

Agosin 1991, Greenaway and Sapsford 1994, Shafaeddin 1994, and Jenkins 12

1996). The literature suggests that, export growth and economic growth are positively correlated. Those economies that are more open are more likely to have a better economic performance than those that are closed. It is also recognized that externalities are an important source of rapid productivity and growth, particularly through the spillover effect to the rest of the economy of exports of manufactured goods (World Bank 1993). Impact of Liberalisation on Employment

The impact of trade liberalisation on employment is of particular significance. The level of employment is a key determinant of overall economic welfare, both in developed and developing countries. Studies for

Latin American countries show, that the impact of trade liberalisation on productivity growth is mixed. In Mexico, Chile, Colombia and Bolivia the impact is either weak or negative. Brazil and Peru confirm the presence of a positive association between trade liberalisation and productivity. It is interesting to note that the last two countries fall into the category of late reformers. It is however important to add that the trade and macro economic policies of the late reformers prior to reform differ rather considerably from those of the early reformers (Dean et al. 1994). Hadded et al. (1996) undertake a quantitative assessment of the impact of trade liberalisation on productivity growth using data on Moroccan industrial firms during the period 1984-89.

Two important results emerge from the study. First, there is no indication that greater competition from imports enhances productivity growth at the industry level. Second a positive correlation is found between Total Factor Productivity 13

(TFP) growth and export only at the firm level. Taiwan was the first developing country to bring a shift, in a major way to outward orientation in the late 1950's by unifying and devaluating the exchange rate and adopting measures which gave exporters more or less free trade status. Korea followed Taiwan with a five year lag and by 1985 had removed most quantitative restrictions and was well on way to tariff levels of developed countries. Sri Lanka is an exception in

South Asia and replaced virtually all quantitative restrictions with tariffs by

1977 and by mid 1980s there were no bans, import quotas and domestic content requirements. (Wignaraja 1994) and (Forouton 1991) observes that productivity in the private sectors was higher than in the public sector. (Kim

2000) examines the dynamic impact of trade liberalisation on productivity, competition and scale efficiency. The study of (Goldar and Kumari 2002) covering the period till 1997-98 shows that a reduction in effective rate of protection to industries appeared to have a favorable effect on productivity growth in Indian industries. However the observed fall in productivity in the

1990s may be attributable partly to the gestation lags in investment projects.

(Sen and Chand 2002) shows that a reduction in the price wedge has a positive impact on productivity growth. Their study however covers the much of the period 1973-88 before the onset of major trade liberalisation attempts. 14

Organised and Unorganised Sectors

The primary impact of trade liberalisation, has been on the manufacturing and other organised sectors of the economy. Much of the economic activity in the urban informal sector and in subsistence agriculture consists of non tradable goods. The impact of trade liberalisation on employment is thus largely indirect, occurring through changes in relative prices and in the probability of obtaining employment in the organised sector.

A particular concern that has surfaced over the impact of trade liberalisation on workers and producers outside the organised sector is that of their possible exclusion from the benefits of that liberalisation. From a labour market perspective, the concern is that, even where trade liberalisation results in a rapid increase in employment opportunities e.g. in the labour intensive manufacturing sector, illiterate or poorly educated workers from the rural and urban informal sectors would be unable to benefit from these new opportunities. The reason for this is that even unskilled jobs in the organised sectors require at least a primary education that these workers do not have.

(Greenhalgh et. al. 1998) found that international trade has a negative effect on the wages of less skilled workers in the UK. (Deaton and Dreze 2002) have noted several other recent adverse trends such as impoverishment among specific regions or social groups, and growing uncertainty and hidden hardships associated with recent patterns of economic changes, particularly, of the disadvantageous section of India's unorganised segment. 15

References

Agosin, Manuel R. (1991): Trade Policy Reform and Economic Performance:

A Review of the Issues and Some Preliminary Evidence, UNCTAD Discussion

Papers No.41, UNCTAD, Geneva.

Ahmed, N. (2000): Export Responses to Trade Liberalisation in Bangladesh: A

Co Integration Analysis, Applied Economics, 32, pp. 1077-1084.

Bhalla. (2005): Earn Poor, Spend Rich: Jadu Economics. Business Standard

Online, January 22.

Dean, M., Seema D., and James R. (1994): Trade Policy Reform in Developing

Countries Since 1985: A Review of the Evidence. World Bank Discussion

Papers, 267.

Deaton, A. and J. D. Sahu. (2002): Poverty and Inequality in India: A Re-

Examination. Economic and Political Weekly, 37(36).

Goldar, B.N. and A. Kumari. (2002): Import Liberalisation and Productivity

Growth in Indian Manufacturing Industries in the 1990s: Working Paper,

E/219/2002, Institute of Economic Growth, .

Greenhalgh, C, Gregory, M. and Zissimos, B. (1998): The Labor Market

Consequences of Technical and Structural Changes. Discussion Paper No. 29,

Centre for Economic Performance LSE/University of Oxford. Grossman, G. and E. Helpman. (1995): Technology and Trade, in G. Grossman and K. Rogoff (ed.), Handbook of International Economics V01.3, Amsterdam:

North Holland.

Government of India. (2001): Report of the Task Force on Employment.

Hadded, M. (1993): Hoe Trade Liberalisation Affected Productivity in

Morocco: PRE Working Paper. 1096. Policy Research Department, World

Bank, Washington, DC.

Hadded, M. J. de Melo, and B. Horton. (1996): Trade Liberalisation Exports

and Industrial Performance: Roberts, M. and J.R.Tybout, (ed.) Industrial

Evolution in Developing Countries: Micro Patterns of Turnover, Productivity

and Market Structure, Oxford University Press for The World Bank.

Jenkins, R. (1996): Trade Liberalisation and Export Performance in Bolivia:

Development and Change. 27(4), pp.693-716.

Nagaraj, R. (2005): Industrial Growth in China and India: A Preliminary

Comparison. Economic and Political Weekly 40, no. 21, May 21: 2,163-71.

Nish imizu, M. and S. Robinson. (1984): Trade Policies and Productivity

Change in Semi Industrialisation Countries: Journal of Development

Economics. Vol. 16, 117-206.

Papageorgiou A., Choksi A.M., and Michaely, M. (1990): Liberalising Foreign

Trade in Developing Countries: Washington, DC, World Bank. 17

Rodrik, D. (1992): Closing the Technology Gap: Does Trade Liberalisation

Really Help? In Helleier, G.K.(ed). Trade Policy Industrilisation and

Development: New Perspectives, Clarendron Press, Oxford.

Rodrik, D. (1997): Trade Policy and Economic Performance in Sub-Saharan

Africa, November. A Study Commissioned by the Swedish Ministry of Foreign

Affairs..

Rodrik, D. (1997): Has Globalisation Gone Too Far? Washington, D.C:

Institute National Economics.

Romer, P. (1994): New Goods Old Theory and The Welfare Costs of Trade

Restrictions. Journal of Development Economics. 43, pp. 5-3 8.

Shafaeddin, S.M. (1994): The Impact of Trade Liberalisation on Export and

GDP in Least Developed Countries: UNCTAD Discussion Papers No.85,

UNCTAD, Geneva.

Thomas, V., John N., and Sebastian E. (1991): Best Practices in Trade Policy

Reform, Oxford University Press for the World Bank, Oxford.

UNCTAD. (1989): Trade and Development Report, UNCTAD, Geneva.

Weiss, J. (1992): Export Response to Trade-Reforms: Recent Mexican

Experience. Development Policy Review. 10(1), pp. 43-60. Wignaraja, G. (1994): Trade and Industrial Policies and Experience in Sri

Lank, in Hilleiner, G.K. (ed). Trade Policy and Industrialisation in Turbulent

Times, Routledge, London and New York.

World Bank (1993). The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public

Policy. Washington, DC, Policy Research Department, World Bank.

Website Accessed www.wikipedia.org. www.economist.com. www.encyclopedia.farlex.com/mixed+economy. www.search.com/reference/Neoliberalism. Chapter - II The Economic Liberalisation in India

The Beginning

Consequences of Economic Liberalisation

^ J 19

Chapter - II

Economic Liberalisation in India

After independence in 1947, India adhered to socialist policies. In the

1980s, Prime Minister Rajiv Gandhi initiated some reforms. In 1991, after the

International Monetary Fund (IMF) had bailed out the bankrupt state, the government of P. V. Narasimha Rao and his finance minister Manmohan Singh

started breakthrough reforms. The new policies included opening of domestic

market for international trade and investment, deregulation, initiation of

privatisation, tax reforms, and inflation controlling measures. The overall

direction of liberalisation has since remained the same, irrespective of the

ruling party, although no party has yet tried to take on powerful lobbies such as

the trade unions and farmers, or contentious issues such as reforming labour

laws and reducing agricultural subsidies. Thus, economic liberalisation in India

refers to ongoing reforms that started on a large scale since 1991.

The Beginning

The germination of the seeds of economic liberalisation in India started

since the Sixth Five Year Plan (1980-85) was originally scheduled by the

Janata Government for the period of 1978-83, but it was actually launched after

Indira Gandhi came back into power as the Prime Minister in January 1980.

'New Industrial Growth with Direct Measures for Poverty Eradications' was

the development strategy of this Plan. Just before the Sixth Five Year Plan

document was published, a new Industrial Policy Statement was issued by Mrs. 20

Gandhi's government in July 1980. In fact, this Statement was a special effort to stimulate and accelerate industrial growth against the background of India's

slower growth/stagnation in the industrial sphere during the late sixties and the

seventies. The Statement emphasised the necessity of a set of pragmatic

policies which will remove the lingering constraints to industrial production

and, at the same time, act as catalyst for faster growth in coming decades.

Although no special designation was given to the 'directional changes' that, the

Statement was pushing forward, but in retrospect the shift was in favour of

'liberalisation' and 'export promotion' two thrusts of the industrial policy

which came to be explicitly recognised afterwards by the government of Rajiv

Gandhi since the mid-eighties. During the regime of Mr. Gandhi, a number of

steps were taken to reform the overall industrial policy in such a way that it

could become more conducive to the promotion of competition, modernisation

and cost efficiency. The reform measures had three basic objectives, namely, to

facilitate capacity creation, to facilitate output expansion, and to remove

procedural impediments. Support for these policy reforms is also reflected in

the underlying development strategy of the Seventh Five Year Plan (1985-90)

of'Industrial Growth and Liberalisation'.

After the assassination of Rajiv Gandhi on 21 May 1991, a minority

Congress government of the Prime Minister P.V. Narasimha Rao was voted to

power in June 1991. Faced with India's foreign exchange reserves in a state of

near bankruptcy, the Rao government, while making a proposed request for a

loan of USS 2.26 billion from the IMF, succumbed to the World Bank, IMF 21 prescription in embarking on the, so called stabilisation and structural adjustment programmes. Because the World Bank already had a ready made report on India, 'Strategy for Trade Reform', the government, with the initiatives taken by the then Finance Minister, Manmohan Singh, was able to hastily introduce the New Economic Policy (NEP) in early July 1991. The NEP can be divided into two parts: the stabilisation programmes and the structural adjustment and reform programmes (Dutt 2002). Whilst the former part basically aims at reducing macroeconomic imbalances (such as fiscal and current account deficits) by restraining aggregate demand, the latter essentially aims at increasing growth, by eliminating supply bottlenecks that hinder competitiveness, efficiency and dynamism to the economic system.

Consequences of Economic Liberalisation

The implementation of economic liberalisation in India has impacted both in positive and negative ways as well, as outlined below.

A. External Control

The growth of the economy has definitely been favorable so far. At the same time Indian economy has clearly tended towards monopolies and towards integration with the global economy. In this context following trends are visible. Proportion of trade to Gross National Product (GNP) has gone up steadily 14.1 percent in 1990-91 to 18.2 percent in 1998-1999. India's economy has become increasingly interdependent on the global economy. The remittances of Indians broad has been to the tune of 2.5 percent of GDP during the liberalising decade compared to just 1.0 percent in the late 1980's. Prior to 22 liberalisation these remittances were declining. Indians are now one of the major contenders in the global labour flows today. The Foreign Direct

Investment (FDI) to India in 1991 was $ 200 million (0.02 percent) while US$

14.6 billion worth of FDI was approved in 1997, although the actual inflow as just $ 3.2 billion. Even this amount was a major advance compared to the situation prior to liberation. However, out the estimated $ 684 billion (6.84 percent) FDI flow worldwide in 1994, India's share was a pittance. Besides most of the FDI flow in Indian so far has been directed towards the non- manufacturing sector and for acquisition of already existing units. Along with the rapidly increasing trade volumes, Actual FDI flows rose from around USD

300 million (0.03 percent) in 1992-93 to more than USD 3 billion (0.03 percent) in 1997-98 and reached USD 7.5 billion in the financial year 2006.

FDI as a percentage of gross capital formation increased from around 0.31 per cent in the 1990 to 2.6 per cent in 2002. Liberalisation has facilitated Indian companies raising resources in western stock exchanges. External debt has become much more manageable after embracing the liberalising measures. A healthy foreign exchange reserve has been built up of about US $ 35 billion

(0.35 percent) in 2000. Changes in Foreign Exchange Regulation Act have removed shareholding and business restrictions. Restrictions on income repatriation have been removed. Similarly, policies related to foreign technology purchase and licensing have been liberalised. Following liberalisation, Indian trade has registered a substantial increase and its foreign exchange position has definitely improved. The manufacturing base of India, 23 however, has not seen any substantial expansion. Indian economy today has integrated with the global economy in terms of transnational capital. The economic reforms programme initiated by the Indian government in 1991 aimed at rapid and substantial integration of the Indian economy with the global economy in a harmonised manner. India has opened up its market since the beginning of the last decade of the twentieth century (especially from July

1991), by lowering tariff and Non-tariff Barriers (NTBs), and liberalising investment policy. The Industrial Policy resolution of 1948 and subsequent resolutions mark the beginning of the import-substitution (IS) era in India.

Although these resolutions recognised the importance of foreign capital and technology in industrialisation, the government evolved a complex legal and institutional control under the Foreign Exchange Restriction Act (FERA), and

Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practice Act (MRTPA) to ensure a marginal and highly circumscribed role of FDI in the economy. In accordance with the tariff reforms, there has been a considerable and consistent improvement in the trade flows as a proportion of GDP as shown in (Table No. 2.1), while trade as a percentage of GDP increased from 15.7 per cent in 1990 to 30.8 per cent in

2002, the post reform period witnessed a marked acceleration in the growth of both exports and imports. During the period 1970-71 to 1979-80 real export as a ratio of GDP grew at a rate of 3.7 per cent per annum, and in the period 1990-

91 to 1998-99 the growth was around 4.6 per cent per annum (Goldar 2002).

On the other hand, real imports as a ratio of GDP grew at a rate of 1.1 per cent 24 per annum, 0.3 per cent per annum and 7.9 per cent per annum in the corresponding periods.

Table 2.1: Trends in India's FDI and Trade Flows (1980 to 2003)

Percent of Gross Domestic Product

Year Trade* FDI** 1980 15.7 0 1981 14.9 0 1982 14.5 0 1983 14 0 1984 14.4 0 1985 13.2 0 1986 12.5 0 1987 12.9 0.1 1988 13.7 0 1989 15.4 0.1 1990 15.7 0.1 1991 17.2 0 1992 18.7 0.1 1993 20 0.2 1994 20.4 0.3 1995 23.2 0.6 1996 22.4 0.6 1997 23 0.9 1998 24.1 0.6 1999 25.5 0.5 2000 28.5 0.5 2001 27.6 0.8 2002 30.8 0.7 2003 30.5 0.7 Source: Wor d Development Indicators * Export & Import ** Net Inflo w

However, it is interesting to note that as the Indian economy became more open and receptive to the world, growth of trade has been much faster than that of FDI. The net inflow of FDI as a percentage of GDP remained less than 1% though there has been a rapid rise in FDI inflows. The result indicates the trade liberalisation had a favorable effect on FDI flows. It was also found 25 that the regions having greater involvement in international trade were able to attract greater amount of FDI.

B. Internal control

Follow^ing domestic impacts can be seen.

1. Growing Economy

India's compound rate of economic growth in the second half of 1980's was 5.8 per annum. The average growth rate for 1992-98 increased to 6.5 percent per annum. Industrial growth for the period has been 8.1 percent and it

is slightly higher than 7.94 percent that prevailed in the second half 1980's.

The growth of the industry, however, has been very unsteady. The rate of

industrial growth reached a height of 12.8 percent in 1995-1996 but during

1996-1999 it has been low and unsteady. The fiscal deficit in the reform period

has remained 5.7 percent as compared to 8.8 percent of GDP in the second half

of 1980's. Inflation has been on the decline during the reform period. However

the growth of consumer index relative to the wholesale index shows that the

prices of food and other goods of mass consumption are increasing at a faster

pace affecting the weaker section. India has generally lagged behind in

Research & Development effort. Ever since India embraced the path of

liberalisation and globalisation its spending in Research & Development has

fallen. India spent 0.96 percent of its GDP on Research & Development in

1988 which came down to 0.8% in 1999. The corresponding amount is 2-3% of

the GDP for developed countries. There has been an unprecedented rise in

mergers and acquisitions in the Indian corporate sector after liberalisation. 26

After liberalisation there is more flexibility for firms to make their investment decisions and in choosing plant capacities. Unprecedented restructuring of the

Indian industry to meet the challenges of the global market has taken place during the last one decade. Dilution of the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade

Practices (MRTP) act has removed many restrictions on corporate investments and growth.

2. Unemployment and Poverty

Scholars in India are deeply divided into rival camps on this issue. One group argues that unemployment and poverty have worsened following liberalisation and the other group suggesting that it is not so. The latter argues that either liberalisation has turned the slide or established the framework and

conditions for reduction of unemployment and poverty. The incidence of

poverty declined for all categories of workers over the first decade of

liberalisation. However the rate of decline in poverty ratios was lowest for

casual workers and it was highest for regular workers. It means less gain for

weaker section. As per NSS data, 1997, poverty in India was around 37 (rural

38 and urban 34) percent. However, the 1980s recorded a faster decline in rural

poverty and the decline slowdown considerably after the reforms. The share of

self-employed workers came down from 61.4 percent in 1972-73 to 54.8 percent in 1993-94. There was increase in the proportion of casual labourers

from 23.2 percent to 32 percent. There is a decline in the rural non-farm employment. Casualisation of labour got accentuated with liberalisation.

Quality of employment has deteriorated on that account. Real wages for casual 27 labourers increased in 1990s but the growth has been very slow. Although rural poverty decreased in most of the state (except Assam, Bihar, Haryana & Punjab and Uttar Pradesh) in 1993-94 as compared to 1987-88, this decline was lower than during the period 1983 to 1987-88-and 1977-78 to 1983. Urban poverty

showed a higher rate of decline in nine out of 17 states during 1987-88 to 1993-

94 as compared to the earlier periods. In India child labour is also on the

decline; it declined from 23 percent in 1980 to 16 percent in 1997. Educated

unemployment was declining over the time and there has been no sign of its

increase after liberalisation. However, in rural areas unemployment among

graduates, both boys and girls, has increased during the decade of

liberalisation.

3. Regional Disparities

Inequality between rich and poor states has increased during the years of

liberalisation. However, it is difficult to bracket any one of the state as rich and

poor with respect to all the indicators. However, certain states such as Gujarat,

Maharashtra, Kamataka, Andhra Pradesh, and Tamil Nadu have consistently

remained rich. In Andhra Pradesh, Gujarat, Kamataka, Maharashtra, West

Bengal and Punjab, Poverty started to decline under liberalisation to an

appreciable extent while there is no such decline in Bihar, Madhya Pradesh,

Orissa, Rajasthan and Uttar Pradesh. The inter-state inequalities in per capita

income increased significantly in 1990's while there was no evidence of

convergence and divergence during the period 1965-85. Rich states showed

much higher growth while poor states recorded lower growth during 1985-96. 28

4. Declining Infrastructure and Basic Industries

There has been a sharp decHne in government capital investment from

5.5 percent to 3.6 percent of the GDP from 1990-91 to 1998-99. It has led to

the relative neglect of the infrastructural sectors. The government has not

succeeded in ploughing FDI's towards the basic industries and infrastructural

sector to any significant extent. The private sector in India has not elicited

much interest in making investment in the basic industries and infrastructure.

India may not be able to sustain, alone by improving the kind of advantage that

it has enjoyed in basic industries for long.

5. Declining Social Sector

There is declining expenditure in social sectors also such as education,

health, and poverty alleviation in the liberalising decade in India. The

expenditure of central and state governments on education on the percentage of

GDP is found to have declined from 3.6 percent in 1992 to 3.4 percent in 1996-

97, showing a declining trend during this period. The worst affected has been

the sector of higher education. Even the priority sector of primary education

does not seem to have received any significantly larger allocation during the

reform period. In the states too, the overall developmental expenditure has

declined. The allocation to health sector has declined from 1.7 percent in Vll

plan (1985-89) to 1.0 percent during 1997-98. While the central government

has taken on a larger share of the social sector over the years, central assistance

to the states in these areas has declined. For instance, the share of education in 29 centrally sponsored schemes was 12.1 percent in 1991. It declined to 8.0 percent in 1997-98.

6. Affecting Employment Structure

Table 2.2: Distribution of India's Total Workers, and its Change

Workers (%) Change in Percentage Point

Sectors 1971 1981 1991 2000 1981- 1991- 2000- 1971 1981 1991 Primary 72.10 68.80 66.80 56.70 -3.3 -2.0 -10.1 Sector

Secondary 11.20 13.50 12.70 17.50 + 2.3 -0.80 + 4.8 Sector

Tertiary 16.70 17.70 20.50 25.80 + 1.0 + 2.8 + 5.3 Sector

Source: www.mpra.ub.uni.

The structural change in employment that has occurred during the second half of 20th century provides the credence to the view that engme of growth of the Indian economy is service sector. However, when we analyze the sectoral distribution of the work force, the primary sector is still the largest sector. The primary sector of the Indian economy has been continuously absorbing the largest size of work force. The work force engaged in the primary sector was 72.10 per cent in the 1971 and declined thereafter at a very slow rate, but the fast declined occurred during the liberalised regime, the change of workforce in primary sector, it was -3.3, during 1981-1971, but it was as high as -10.1, during 2000-1991. The workforce shifted from primary sector to secondary and tertiary sector, after 1951 but the significant increase 30 occurred during the liberalised regime. The secondary and tertiary sectors are increasingly absorbing more workforce during the present time. It means the primary sector or agriculture is in great loss.

Organised and Unorganised Sectors

In India, a major chunk of labor force is employed in the unorganised sector. "The unorganised / informal employment consists of causal and contributing family workers, self employed persons, in unorganised sector and private households, and other employed in organised and unorganised enterprises that are not eligible either for paid, sick or annual leave or for any social security benefits given by the employer." According to the results of the

National Sample Survey conducted in 1999-2000, total work force as on 1.1,

2000 was of the order of 4.06 million. Only seven per cent of the total work force is employed in the, formal or organised sector (all public sector establishments and all non-agricultural establishments in private sector with 10 or more workers) while remaining 93% work in the informal or unorganised sector. One of the structural indicators of employment is the extent of organised sector employment which is dominated by the private sector. The total organised sector employment occupies about 10 percent of the total workers. The increase in the organised sector employment was from 15.63 lakhs in 1991 to 16.45 lakhs in 1996, which worked out to an annual growth rate of 1.03 per cent, equivalent to 0.92 percent in five years (1991 to 1996).

After that period, a continuous decline in the organised sector employment was witnessed. The NSS 55th round, 1999-2000 also covered non-agricultural 31 enterprises in the informal sector in India. As per that survey, there were 44.35 million enterprises and 79.71 million workers employed thereof in the non- agricultural informal sector of the economy. Among these 25.01 million enterprises employing 39.74 million workers were in rural areas whereas 19.34 million enterprises with 39.97 million workers in the urban area. Among the workers engaged in the informal sector, 70.21 million are full time and 9.5 million part times. Percentage of female workers to the total workers is 20.2 percent. The Table 2.3 below describes major employment trends in the organised and unorganised sector for the years 1983, 1987-88, 1993-94 and

1999-2000. It is evident that throughout this period a large portion of the workforce in India is found to be employed in the unorganised sector. Out of

397million workers in 1999-2000, it is estimated that 369 million workers

(nearly 93 per cent) are employed in the unorganised segment of the economy whereas only 28 million workers (7 per cent) are engaged in the organised

sector. The share of unorganised employment in the economy has displayed

remarkable steadiness over the years. The share of informal employment has risen from 92 per cent (nearly 276 million out of 300 million) in 1983 to 93 per

cent in the 1999-2000. It is clear that employment opportunity in the organised

sector has remained more or less stagnant, showing only a marginal increase

from 24 million in 1983 to 28 million, in 1999-2000. The largest numbers of informal workers are in agriculture. In fact, 98.84 percent of the employment in agriculture is informal. In the non-agricultural sector, the highest numbers of informal employees are in retail trade, construction, land transport, textiles etc. 32

Table 2.3: Trends in Employment Structure in India (in Million)

Percentage of Total Employment

1983 1988 1994 1999 - 2000

Labour Force 3.08 3.33 3.91 4.06

Employed 3.02 3.24 3.74 3.97

Unemployed 0.058 0.092 0.0749 0.090

Employment in 0.240 0.257 0.273 0.281

Organised Sector

Employment in 2.78 2.98 3.47 3.68

Unorganised Sector

Source: www, oreanised-aiid-unorganise c -labor.html

Thus, the unorganised sector plays a vital role in terms of providing employment opportunity to a large segment of the working force in the country and contributes to the national product significantly. The contribution of the unorganised sector to the net domestic product and its share in the total NDP at current prices has been over 60%. In the matter of savings the share of household sector in the total gross domestic saving mainly unorganised sector is about three fourth. Thus unorganised sector has a crucial role in our economy in terms of employment and its contribution to the National Domestic Product, savings and capital formation. 33

Labour force & Work force

Labour Force

All the active persons categorised as working (employed) and as a seeking or available for work (or unemployed) together constitute the labour force. Workers and unemployed together constitute the labour force.

Workforce

The International Conference on Labour Statistics therefore included

"all persons of either sex who fiimish the supply of economic goods and services" in the work force.

The chart below describes the estimated increase in the labors force from 1977-78 to 2004-05. The labor force has grown from 276.3 million to

385.5 million between 1977-78 andl993-94 showing an increase of 6.6 percent. During the 6 years, the workforce was estimated to be 407million.

Figure 2.1: Estimated Increase in Labour Force

Estimated Increase in Labour Force

-^ 600

i 500 ^ 400 I 300 °] •2 200 o 100 —

1977-78 1993-94 1999-2000 2004-05 2 005-06 Years 34

Male and Female Employment

Table 2.4: Workforce Participation Rate of Male and Female in

Urban and Rural areas in India

Census Male Female

Rural Urban Rural Urban

1971 53.6 48.8 15.5 • 6.7

1981 53.8 49.1 23.2 8.3

1991 52.5 48.9 26.7 9.2

2001 52.4 50.9 31.0 11.6

Source: NSSO.

Workforce participation rate compare to rural and urban areas of male and female in India. However, when we analyse that, rural male in 1971 it was

53.6, in 1991 it was 52.5, and in 2001 it was 52.4, it means a slightly decline

0.1% WPR after liberalisation and rural female in 1971 it was 15.5, 1991 it was 26.7, and 2001 it was 31.0, it mean 4% of WPR after liberalisation, urban male in 1971 it was 48.8, inl991 it was 48.9 and in 2001 it was 50.9, it means

2% increase WPR after liberalisation and urban female in 1971 it was 6.7,

1991 it was 9.2 and 2001 it was 11.6, it mean WPR of urban female increase

2% after liberalisation period. 35

References

Dutta (2002): Effects of Globalisation on Employment and Poverty in Dualistic

Economies: The Case of India. School of Economics and Political Science

University of Sydney NSW: 2006.

Goldar, B. (2002): Trade Liberalisation and Manufacturing Employment: The

Case India. ILO 2002/34.

Website Accessed www.egyankosh.ac.in. www.mpra.ub.uni http://industrialrelations.naukrihub.com/organised-and-unorganised-labor.html www.linkinghub.elsevier.com. s*

Chapter - III Literature Review

Ms ipC 36

Chapter - III

Literature Review

In this chapter, an attempt has been made to look at the work done earHer, the impact of liberalisation on employment structure. Here some emphasis has been given to cover the literature on various aspects of liberalisation and employment structure in the region, which provides the insight in selecting methodology. The measures employed by different scholars in the particular area a help in many ways. An assessment of important works is presented here.

Joshi (1976) argued in his study, "Surplus Labour and the City: A Study of Bombay", that it is evident even from the statistics presented so far that there is no clear link between globalisation and the staggering preponderance of informal labour in India. In fact, the imbalance always existed, and the decline in informal sector employment goes back at least to the 1960s, long before there was any thought of liberalisation.

Minhas and Majumdar (1987), "Unemployment and Casual Labour in

India: An Analysis of Recent NSS Data", in their work described that turning to changes over time, the unemployment rate fell between 1983 and 1987/88 by a substantial 2.3 percentage points and remained stable until 1993/94. In the six years to 1999/2000, it registered one percentage point increase. The proportion of casual workers in the labour force has been increasing continuously through 37 the last three decades, apparently no more quickly in the wake of economic reforms than before.

The World Bank (1989) an in the article "India: Poverty, Employment and Social Services: A World Country Study", brings out that, in organised and unorganised sectors wage inequality has generated concern for distributional reasons. It is a widespread belief that government protection of labour and product markets has contributed to the isolation of the factory sector from the rigors of the market. This has generated two concerns; first, a concern with inequality created by undeservedly high wages. Second, excessively high wage discouraging labour demand in the organised sector.

The International Labour Organisation (ILO) in its report (1989),

"Employment and Structural Change in Indian Industries", argues that, decline of employment in organised textile sector in India was because of structural changes resulting in product preferences, modernisation and deliberate labour reduction by many mills to cut costs.

Van Wersch (1992) in his report, "The Bombay Textile Strike 1982-83", revealed that employment conditions in the informal sector have not changed significantly and indeed could hardly have got worse than they were to begin with the formal sector, which was characterised by high levels of job security, union density and collective bargaining up to the 1970s, suffered a catastrophic erosion of job security from the 1980s onwards. Textile mills for example, went through a spectacular decline in employment. It is estimated that the Bombay Textile strike of 1982-83 was followed by the loss of roughly 38

75,000 jobs due to closures and downsizing, excluding jobs where older workers were replaced by new recruits.

Singh (1993), Papola (1994) in their study, "New Economic Policy and

Challenges Before the Labour Economists" and "Structural Adjustment,

Labour Market Flexibility and Employment", they argued that, economic reform will be associated with greater labour market flexibility and with a shift towards labour intensive techniques and industries in response to an increased openness to trade.

Fallon and Lucas (1993) in their paper, "Job Security Regulations and the Dynamic Demand for Industrial Labour in India and Zimbabwe", concluded, that the labour demand in the large scale industries suffered, more as compared to the small scale units thus indicating the dependence of the effects of regulations on the scale of operation as a notion of implement ability.

Further, even among the large scale units, the negative effect of job security legislation on employment is low with a relatively less unionized labour force.

Nagaraj (1994) in his work, "Employment and Wages in Manufacturing

Industries: Trends, Hypotheses and Evidence", states that, it is inherently difficult to arrive at strong conclusions about the impact of the economic reforms as (a) they are not a controlled experiment and there is no available counter factual (b) the reforms are still in progress and some of the adjustments to reform may still be working themselves out, and (c) they are a package of changes, different parts of which may have very different effects on the object of interest (employment in this case). 39

Bhalla (1997) and Sen (1996) in their papers, "Trends in Poverty, Wages and Employment in India" and "Economic Reforms, Employment and Poverty:

Trends and Options", explain that, the Indian in line with the share of casual workers rising from 27 per cent in 1977/78 to 33 per cent in 1999/2000, the share of self employment has fallen continuously from 59 per cent in 1977/78 to 53 per cent in 1999/2000. There has been a noticeable shift of workers from rural non-farm employment to agriculture which has been attributed to declining public expenditure in the reform period.

Business Standard (1999) an article on 12 November, "Factory Jobs

Keep Growing", appears that employment in organised manufacturing, both private and public sector, (where the majority of formal workers would be found) grew at a rate of 3.8 per cent per annum between 1970-71 and 1980-81,

0.53 per cent per annum between 1980-81 and 1990- 91, and 2.69 per cent per annum between 1990-91 and 1997-98. Thus after a sharp drop in the 1980s, the growth rate recovered somewhat in the 1990s (i.e. post liberalisation).

Goldar (2000) in his study, "Employment Growth in Organised

Manufacturing in India", employment in organised manufacturing sector grew at 4.03 per cent per annum during the first half of the 1990s, this growth has taken place despite the prevalence of unaltered statutory regulations impacting on employment decisions of the firms, possibly owing to the change in the size structure in favour of small and medium industries and the slowdown in the growth in real wages. 40

Dev (2000) in his study, "Economic Liberalisation and Employment in

South Asia", examines the impact of economic liberalisation on employment

and labour incomes in South Asia based on a Computable General Equilibrium

(CGE) model. The results indicate a higher growth of employment in informal

and private sectors despite a jobless growth in the 1980s. This indicates that

labour rigidities have affected the employment growth. However, grovv'th rate

of organised manufacturing sector has increased in the post-reform period,

while that of the unorganised part has fallen.

Mahendra Dev. S. (2000) in his work, "Economic Liberalisation and

Employment in South Asia-I", asserted that total employment (formal and

informal) grew by 2.17 per cent per annum between 1977-78 and 1983, 1.54

per cent per annum between 1983 and 1987-88, and 2.43 per cent per annum

between 1987-88 and 1993-94.

His another estimate is that while employment growth in organised

manufacturing declined from 1.86 per cent per annum during 1978-83 to -0.45

per cent per annum during 1983-88 and recovered to 2.31 in 1988-94,

employment growth in unorganised manufacturing changed little from 3.69 per

cent per annum during 1978-83 to 3.97 per cent per annum during 1983-88,

and declined to 1.08 per cent per annum during 1988-94.

Goldar (2000) in his paper "Employment Growth in Organised

Manufacturing in India, stated that. Central Statistical Organisation (CSO), too

estimated that there was a 2.26 per cent compound annual growth of employment in the organised manufacturing sector during the period 1992-98. 41

Economic Times (2000) an article published in "90m Working Children in India: ILO", published on 29 April, stated that the total labour force was

314.13 million in the 1991 census while the Economic Survey 1997-98 estimated the labour force as being 397.2 million in 1997. According to the

Statistical Outline of India 1998-99, employment in the organised sector, in millions, rose from 26.73 in 1991 to 28.25 in 1997, so the proportion of permanent employees in the organised sector declined from 8.5 per cent to 7.1 per cent in the period 1991-97. Finally, it was estimated that organised sector employment fell from 8 per cent of total employment in 1994 to 7 per cent m

1999-2000.

Sundaram (2001) "Employment-Unemployment Situation m the

Nineties: Some Results from NSS 55th Round Survey", finds, a dechne in the crude worker population ratio for men and women in rural and urban areas and

in all of the age groups in the 5-59 year range.

Planning Commission (2001) in its work: "Report of the Task Force on

Employment Opportunities", suggested that, (a) the encourage growth of GDP with an emphasis on sectors is likely to ensure the spread of income to the low income segments of the labour force, (b) pursuit of sectoral and regional policies consistent, with acceleration of GDP (for example, investment in agricultural infrastructure, especially in the poorer states) and (c) special programmes for employment and income generation amongst vulnerable groups. 42

An article published in Economic Times (2001) "Organised Sector

Sheds Flab, but there's Work Elsewhere," on 9 May, emphasized that while jobs in organised sector increased at an average annual rate of 0.5 per cent

during 1993-99, non-agricultural unorganised sector jobs also grew at an

average rate of 2.8 per cent per annum.

Sundaram (2001) in his paper "Employment-Unemployment Situation m

the Nineties: Some Results from NSS 55th Round Survey", the survey report

shows, a decline in both rural and urban poverty in this period. By this

criterion, there is some evidence of an improvement in the quality of

employment in the wake of economic reform.

Patel (2001) in his paper "Socio Economic Marginalisation of Displaced

Textile Mill Workers in Ahmedabad: Gujarat. India", explained that, in

Ahmedabad, textile centre, the decline started in 1982, with the closure of 50

private mills and 20 government owned mills and the loss of almost 100,000

jobs over the next fifteen years, the majority in the 1980s. Other textile centre's

like witnessed a similar decline. The vast majority of these job losses

were not due to natural wastage or voluntary early retirement but they were

involuntary and sometimes bitterly resisted.

Goldar (2002) in his paper, "Trade Liberalisation and Manufacturing

Employmenf, explained acceleration in output growth with shifting structures

that have led to a significant step up in organised manufacturing employment

growth during the 1990s. At the sectoral level, these are largely identified to be

labour intensive export oriented industries. Even though the data does not show 43 any increase in employment in export oriented industries during trade liberalization. The study finds an increase in employment elasticity m manufacturing as a result of increase in the elasticity in export-oriented industries.

Lall (2002) in his paper, "The Employment Impact of Globalisation in

Developing Countries", pointed that the employment impact of globalisation varies across developing countries depending on their ability to cope with liberalised trade, investment and technology flows. Further, even though trade impacts sectoral composition of demand for labour in a significant way, it is not often the alone factor in determining post-trade reforms employment.

Rather, a range of factors including labour market regulations, rigidities and institutions, sector specific structure, etc. influence labour market outcomes of developing countries to a large extent.

Rana and Ramaswamy (2003) in their work, "Trade Reforms, Labour

Regulations and Labour Demand Elasticities: Empirical Evidence from India", asserted that a positive impact of trade liberalisation and degree of flexibility of labour regulations across states and sectors on the labour-demand elasticity in the Indian manufacturing sector. According to this study, the trade refonns of

1991 have positive effects on the labour demand elasticity directly and indirectly.

Unni (2003) in his work "Labour Market Institutions in India: 1990s and

Beyond, Chapter Economic Refonns and Labour Markets in India: Organised and Unorganised Sectors", suggests a post-reform shift of labour force from the 44 organised to unorganised sector despite an existence of positive linkages between them.

Uchikawa (2003) in his work, "Labour Market Institutions in India:

1990s and Beyond, Chapter Employment in Manufacturing Organised Sector in

India", asserted that, though the removal of labour market rigidities that arise from reforms in India has caused a change in the structure of the labour market.

However, this has not necessarily resulted in a decline in the employment. This is because of the enhanced investment owing to the reduced regulations, which might have progressive effects on employment.

Sakthivel (2003) "Economic Reforms and Jobless Growth in India in the

1990s", finds a sharp deceleration in employment growth across sectors m the

1990s. The study finds zero employment elasticity for the primary sector during the post-reforms phase and declining elasticity for the secondary and tertiary sectors.

Sarkar (2004) in his study, "Reforms and Employment Elasticity in

Organised Manufacturing", shows increase in organised manufacturing employment growth in the 1990s. This is partly explained by changes in the size structure in favour of small and medium sized factories and large!) on the declining growth of real wages in the industrial sector.

Nagaraj (2004) in his paper, "Fall in Organised Manufacturing

Employment: A Brief Note", has found that there is widespread joblosses in organised manufacturing accounting for about 15 per cent of the workforce between 1995- 96 and 2000-01, 5 per cent with the exception of the tobacco, 45 textiles, chemicals and other manufacturing businesses. Such sluggish employment growth during a period of economic reforms has been explained in terms of a variety of reasons.

Here, I have concluded the ideas of some scholars which show that, the implications of economic reforms for employment growth have attracted a great deal of discussion and speculation amongst Indian scholars and policy makers of which most have been pessimistic. 46

References Bhalla, S. (1997): Trends in Poverty, Wages and Employment in India: The

Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Delhi, Indian Society of Labour

Economics, Vol.40, No. 2.

Bhattacharya, B. B. and S. Sakthivel (2003): Economic Reforms and Jobless

Growth in India in the 1990s. Indian Journal of Labour Economics. 46 (4):

845-865.

Business Standard, (1999): Factory Jobs Keep Growing: 12 November.

Dev, M. (2000): Economic Liberalisation and Employment in South Asia:

ZEF- Discussion Papers on Development Policy No: 29.

Dev, S. Mahendra (2000): Economic Liberalisation and Employment in South

Asia-I: Economic and political Weekly Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 8 Jan., pp.

40-51.

Economic Times, (2000): 90m working Children in India: ILO, 29 April.

Economic Times, (2001): Organised sector sheds ilab, but there's work elsewhere, 9 May.

Fallon, P. and Lucas, R. (1993): Job Security Regulations and the Dynamic

Demand for Industrial Labour in India and Zimbabwe: Journal of Development

Economics, 40(2):241-275. 47

Goldar, B. (2000): Employment Growth in Organised Manufacturing in India:

Economic and Political Weekly, pages 191-195.

Goldar, B. N. (2002): Trade Liberalisation and Manufacturing Employment:

The Case of India. Employment Paper, 2002/34. Geneva: International Labour

Organization.

ILO-ARTEP (1989): Employment and Structural Change in Indian Industries:

A Trade Union View-point. International Labour Organization and Asian

Regional Team for Employment Promotion, New Delhi.

Joshi, H., and Joshi, V. (1976): Surplus Labour and the City: A Study of

Bombay, Oxford. University Press, New Delhi.

Lall, S. (2002): The Employment Impact of Globalisation in Developing

Countries. QEH Working Paper No. 93. Oxford: Queen Elizabeth House,

Oxford University.

Mundle, S. (1992): The Employment Effect of Stabilization and Related Policy

Changes in India: 1991-92 to 1993-94: Indian Journal of Labour Economics

Delhi, Indian Society of Labour Economics, Vol. 35, No.2, July-Sep., pp. 227-

37.

Mahendra Dev, S., (2000): Economic Reforms, Poverty, Income Distribution

and 48

Employment: Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. XXXV No. 10, 4 March,

823-35.

Mahendra Dev, S., (2000): Economic Liberalisation and Employment in South

Asia -I: Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. XXXV Nos.l&2, 8 January, 40-

51.

Mazumdar, D. and S. Sarkar. (2004): Reforms and Employment Elasticity in

Organised Manufacturing: Economic and Political Weekly. 39(27): 3017- 29.

Minhas, B.S. and Majumdar, G. (1987): Unemployment and Casual Labour in

India: An Analysis of Recent NSS Data, Indian Journal of Industrial Relations,

Pune, Indian School of Political Economy, 32(3).

Nagaraj, R. (1994): Employment and Wages in Manufacturing Industries:

Trends, Hypotheses and Evidence, Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai,

Sameeksha Trust, 22 Jan.

Nagaraj, R. (2004): Fall in Organized Manufacturing Employment: A Brief

Note, Economic and Political Weekly, 39(30): 3387-3390.

Rana, Hasan. Mitra, D. and Ramaswamy, K. (2003): Trade Reforms, Labour

Regulations and Labour Demand Elasticities: Empirical Evidence From India.

National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No: 9879. 49

Papola, T.S. (1994): Structural Adjustment, Labour Market Flexibility and

Employment, Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Delhi, Indian Society of

Labour Economics, Vol.37, No.l, Jan.-Mar., pp.3-16.

Planning Commission (2001): Report of the Task Force on Employment

Opportunities, New Delhi, Government of India, June.

Patel, B.B., (2001): Socio Economic Marginahsation of Displaced Textile Mill

Workers in Ahmedabad: Gujarat, India, Paper presented to IDPAD Workshop on Collective Care Arrangements among Workers and Non-workers in the

Informal Sector, Centre for Economic and Social Studies, Hyderabad, 1-2

March.

Sundaram, K. (2001): Employment-Unemployment Situation in the Nineties:

Some Results from NSS 55th Round Surve\', Economic and Political Week!}'

Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 17 Mar., pp.931-940.

Sen, A. (1996): Economic Reforms, Employment and Poverty: Trends and

Options, Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, Vol. 31,

Nos. 35-37.

Singh, M. (1993): New Economic Policy and Challenges Before the Labour

Economists: Inaugural Address to the 34th Conference of the Indian Society of

Labour Economics, Jawaharlal Nehru University, in Indian Journal of Labour

Economics, Delhi, Indian Society of Labour Economics, Vol.36, No. 1. 50

Uchikawa, S. (2003). Labour Market Institutions in India: 1990s and Beyond,

Chapter Employment in Manufacturing Organised Sector in India: The Rise of

Medium Scale Units, pages 39-65. Manohar Publishers, New Delhi.

Unni, J. (2003). Labour Market Institutions in India: 1990s and beyond,

Chapter Economic Reforms and Labour Markets in India: Organised and

Unorganised Sectors, pages 65-95. Manohar Publishers, New Delhi.

Van Wersch, H., (1992): The Bombay Textile Strike 1982-83, Oxford

University Press.

World Bank (1989): India: Poverty, Employment and Social Services, A

World

Bank Country Study (Washington D.C), Chapter 4. r

Chapter - IV Uttar Pradesh: A Geographical Outline

Physical Aspects

Social Aspects 51

Chapter - IV

Uttar Pradesh: A Geographical Outline

Uttar Pradesh is the fifth largest state of India with its capital located at . The state has the largest urban area and population.

It has the largest number of million plus cities. It is the most populous state of India which supports 16.44 percent of Indian population and

9.65 percent of the area of the country.

Physical Aspects Location

The state hes between 23°52' to 31°28'N latitudes and 77^04' to

84°38'E longitudes, enjoying the central position in northern India. It covers an area of 2, 94,411 sq.km. of which 16.30 percent forms a hilly tract and the remaining 83.70 percent lies in the plain region. The northern limit of the state is demarcated by an international boundary with China and Nepal. The southern boundary of the state runs with

Madhya Pradesh. In the northwest and west, the boundary touches the states of Himachal Pradesh, Haryana, Rajasthan and Delhi. The eastern border runs with Bihar. The Yamuna river forms part of the western boundary and the Gandak makes the part of the eastern boundary. 52

Location Map — Uttar Pradesh

Figure 4.1 53

Districts in Uttar Pradesh

UTTARAKHAND

Oauiam' DELHI BudiUia HARYANA

MATHUR

RAJASTHAN

BIHAR

Miizapur rcfcadauh

JHARKHAND

CHHATTISGARH

Figure 4.2 54

Relief

The present relief of the state is not much diversified. The relief

features of the state are the resultant forms of recent structural

formations. The state has been divided into following two major

physiographic regions,

(i) Indo-Gangetic Plain

(ii) Hill and Plateau Region.

(i) Indo-Gangetic Plain

This is the core of the state, claiming more than half of the total

state's area extending form northwest to southwest. Remarkably

homogeneous in topography, this region is made up of fertile alluvial

soil deposited by the perennial rivers of Ganga, Yamuna, Ghaghara and

its tributaries. Important cities of the state are situated in these plains.

Being a fertile land throughout and with a good rainfall, this region is

one of the most populated area of the country. Climatically this region

may be divided into three parts.

(a) Eastern Plain: (Bahraich, Sravasti, Balrampur, Sidharthnagar,

Mharajganj, Kushinagar, Gonda, Basti, Sant Kabir Nagar, ,

Deoria, , Sultanpur, Azamgarh, Maunath Bhanjan, Ballia,

Paratapgarh, Jaunpur, Varansi, Ghazipur, Kaushambi, St. Ravidas

Nagar, Mirzapur, Chaundauli, , Sonbhadra.) 55

(b) Central Plain: (Lakhimpur Kheri, Sitapur, Hardoi, Unno, Lucknow,

Barabanki, Raebareli, Fatehpur, Kanpur Urban, Kanpur Rural).

(c) Western Plain: (, Muzafamagar,Baghpat, , Bijnor,

Ghaziabad, Jyotiba Phule Nagar, Gautambudha Nagar, Buland Shahar,

Moradabad, Rampur, , Baudan, Aligarh, , Hathras,

Eath, Farrukhabad, Shahjahanpur, Pillibhit, Manipuri, Firozabad, ,

Etawah, Kannauj, Auraiya.)

The eastern plain comprises the districts of Gorakhpur, Basti,

Gonda, Bahraich, Deoria, Ghazipur, , Ballia, Jaunpur, and Azamgarh. The climate of the area is damp with rainfall ranging between 100 and 150 cm. This is the most populous area but as compared with central and western plains; it is industrially backward.

The central plain has a soothing climate and moderate rainfall. Ihe districts of this plain are Kanpur, Lucknow, Allahabad, Faizabad,

Barabanki, Pratapgarh, Unnao, Sultanpur, Fatehpur. Rai Bercli, Sitapur and Hardoi. This region is more advanced economically than the eastern plain region. Out of the five bog cities - the (KAVAL) towns, three are located in this region. These cities are Kanpur, Lucknow and Allahbad.

The western zone is comparatively an area of poor rainfall (0-50 cm). It is most developed part of Ganga Plain. Agra, the third biggest city of the state is situated in this region. Other important cities like Meerut,

Moradabad, Aligarh, Bareilly, Mathura and Saharanpur are also situated

')^x ^IIS 56 in this region. Industrially, commercially, and culturally this is the most advanced region of the state.

(ii) Hill and Plateau Region: (Jalaun, , Lalitpur, Hamirpur,

Mahoba, Banda, Chittrakut)

On the Southern extreme of the state the region is marked by east- west trends of low rounded hills. These hills generally remain dry as the annual rainfall in very poor and scattered. As a result the area is not

important for agricultural purposes. Ravines and barren lands are the characteristics features of the area. The district of Mirzapur lies m the

southeast, in the southwest are the district of Banda, Jalaun, Jhansi,

Lalitpur and Hamirpur. The region is backward both agriculturally and

industrially. However, some mineral deposits are found in considerable

amount.

Drainage

Uttar Pradesh has a very well established drainage system. The

general slope of the land is form west-northwest to east-southeast with

the exception of right bank tributaries of Yamuna. Almost all other rivers of the state rising in the Himalayas flow from west to east. Except

Ghaghara which flow more or less in straight course, all other rivers have a tendency to flow in sinuous courses across the plain forming

'meanders' and 'ox-bow' lakes. The principal rivers of the state are

Ganga, Yamuna, Ghaghara, Gomti and Ramganga in the north and

Chambal, Sindh, Betwa, Sone and Ken in the south-west. The 57

Himalayan rivers are more active than those coming from the Vindhyan range in filHng up the great plain with silt, and they also provide more important sources if irrigation and power since they have perennial supplies of water from monsoon rainfall supplemented by snow melts.

Climate and Natural Vegetation

The climate of state on the whole is healthy, except the swampy tract of the Tarai. The entire state has tropical monsoon climate, except the Himalayan region, where the climate may be designated as temperate. It is characterised by a rhythm of seasons which is caused by the southwest and northeast monsoons. Taking into consideration the temperature and precipitation, the whole year is divisible into three

distinct seasons.

(i) The cold weather season (November to February)

(ii) The hot weather season (March to Mid-June)

(iii) The rainy season (Mid-June to October)

(i) The Cold Weather Seasons

During the month of November a high pressure beh extends from northwestern India and covers the whole of the Ganga valley. The prevailing direction of the wind is from west to east. The temperature starts decreasing and reaches up to 2°-3°C in December and January.

The month of January is the coldest month of the year ad records lowest temperature conditions accompanied by mist and fog known as kohra 58 which often reduces the visibihty to almost nil. February is generally the month of clear sky with increasing temperature. The rainfall through small in quantity is highly beneficial to the winter crops, as it comes at a time when the plants are flowerings. It ranges from 180 mm. at Nainital in the northwest and north to 38 mm. at Deoria in the east,

(ii) The Hot Weather Season

Severe hot and dry weather conditions mark the summer season beginning from March. The mercury shows a tendency to rise abruptly m

May-June, when temperature as high as 40° to 45°C may be recorded.

The month of May and half of June is the period of intense hot dry west winds, locally known as 'Loo'. The occurrence of dust storms locally known as Andhi forms a significant feature of the season. These storms are short lived and frequently end up in the light shov^'ers of rain. The total average rainfall in hot weather season is small. It ranges from

100mm at the northern station of state to 20mm at some of the stations in the extreme southwest. The amount of rainfall decreases from east to west due to the increasing distance from the sea as the air gets progressively drier. Rainfall received during hot weather season gives temporary relief from the heat and helps in the sowing of early rice crop. 59

(iii) The Rainy Season

With the monsoon burst that normally starts from the middle of

June and lasts till October a complete change in the weather is brought about with the immediate fall in the temperature and upward trend m humanity. Nearly 85 to 90 percent of the annual precipitation is received during these months (June to October). However, July and August-are the rainiest months of the year. The rainfall is heaviest in the Himalayan region and decreases as one go from north to south and from east to west. On an average the Himalayan region experiences rainfall from

140 to 200 cms. In the sub Himalayan belts the rainfall exceeds 120 cms. The western part of the Ganga Plain has an average rainfall of 60-

100 cms., while the eastern part of the plain receives from 100 to 120 cms, the southern hills receive from 100 to 120 cms., annually. Rainy season is marked by high percentage (80 percent) relative humidity.

October is the month of retreating monsoon, the mean maximum temperature remains as high as in September. Rainfall through little, is useful for the rabi crops and for maturity of late rice. The monsoon climate and fertile soil help to grow the luxurious vegetation particularly in the Tarai region of Himalayan foothills. The natural vegetation in the plains such as Dhak (Butea frondosa), Bargad (Banyan) and, Neem

(Margosa) are planted according to choice. Babul (Acacia) is \er> common in . Due to increased inigation facilities and pressures of fast growing population, more and more land is being 60 taken under cultivation. As a result, some of the good forests have

actually submerged and disappeared.

Soil

Soil constitutes the natural medium which supports the growth of

plants on the earth's surface. On the basis of texture, colour, availability

of water and the level of land, the soils of the state are classified. A

wide range of soils both of residual and alluvial origin are found within

the state. A major part of the state is occupied by the alluvial soils. The

soil may be broadly classified into;

i) Forest or Hill Soils

ii) Alluvial Soil

iii) Mixed Red and Black Soil

The hill soils are found in the northern mountainous regions and in

the foothills. They are mostly red loan, brown, podsol and meadow soil.

The soils found in the sub-montane tract are pebbly and porous, which

are rich in organic matter. The Bhabur and Tarai soil are mostly

swampy. Alluvial soil is the biggest and most extensive soil formation

in the state, claiming 61.78 percent in its total area. These soils have

developed from the alluvium deposited by the rivers Ganga and

Yamuna and other tributaries mainly the Ghaghara, the Gandak, the

Gomti and the Ramganaga. The best of the new alluvium is called

Khaddar and the older one Bhangar. As regards the fertility situation of

the alluvial soils, it is highly productive, giving adequate response to

high yielding varieties and fertilizers. The mixed red or black soils 61 characterise the southern plateau region. These soils are adhesive and calcareous as they are developed from stony bases. Due to poor soil, coupled with scarcity of water, agriculture is in bad shape in this soil zone. Except in the black soil which is often devoted to rabi crops, the remaining soil types are used in kharif season only for producing javvar, small millets and tills which happen to be the principal crops.

Social Aspects

Uttar Pradesh is one of the most important states from the view point of population and area but economically it is a backward state.

The progress in the various sectors of the economy has been so poor that it has remained more than one plan behind the all India progress.

Both agriculturally, in which more than 75 percent population is engaged, as well as industrially the state is backward. Similarly, the progress in the field of various social and economic overheads has been so inadequate that it has failed in meeting even barest infrastructural requirement of the economy. A brief survey of resources has been given in the following heads. 62

Population

Population is wealth of a nation or state. Due to wide spread plain with fertile soil and good rainfall, the state of Uttar Pradesh has a sizeable population and high population density. It ranks first among the states of Indian union in terms of population. According to 1991 census the total population of the state is 139 million which is 16.4 percent of the total population of India. The rural population of the state is 80.16 percent and engaged in primary activities basically in agriculture. The urban population of the state is 19.84 percent. The population density is

473 persons per square kilometer. The percentage of literate is 41.7 which accounts for about 13 percent of the total literate population of

India. The male and female literates are 55.4 and 26.0 percent respectively.

Population is amounted to a total of 166,052,859 according to the results of the last held census in 2001. Uttar Pradesh is by far the most populated state in India, despite the creation of the state of Uttarkhand from within it. The decadal variation rate of Uttar Pradesh population has settled close to a growth of 25 percent over the last two census reports. That shows a growth rate that is marginally higher than the national average. The density of population is also high at 473 people per square km. as against the national average of 274. However, the brighter side of the picture is that the sex ratio as well as the literacy rate has considerably improved from last held census. 63

Table 4.1: Trends in Population Growth in Uttar Pradesh & India

Years Population Decadal Growth Percentage (in crores) Rate (in percent) Share of India's Population

U.P. India U.P. India U.P.

1901 4.86 23.83 - - 20.4 1911 4.82 25.20 -0.8 5.7 19.1 1921 4.67 25.13 -3.1 -0.3 18.5 1931 4.98 27.89 6.6 11.0 17.8 1941 5.65 31.86 13.5 14.2 17.7 1951 6.32 36.10 11.8 13.3 16.7 1961 7.37 43.92 16.6 21.5 16.1 1971 8.83 54.81 19.8 24.8 16.1 1981 11.08 68.38 25.5 23.8 16.44 1991 13.91 84.63 25.5 23.8 16.44 2001 16.60 102.70 25.8 21.34 16.2

Sources: National Commission Agenda, 2001,

Economy

Uttar Pradesh has an economy that is well divided between

industrialisation and agriculture. At the same time the per capita income rate is also lower than most other states of India. Most of the occupational groups within the population of Uttar Pradesh are invoked in agricultural, which contribute to 41 percent of the state's economy.

Skilled laborers are sought after m the urban centers of the state which 64 are experiencing a tremendous growth specially in the information technology and the telecommunication sector

Table 4.2: Sector Wise Share of GDP (%) in Uttar Pradesh

Percentage Distribution of GSDP of Uttar Pradesh Year Primary Secondary Tertiary 1 1999-00 35.5 21.8 42.8 2 2000-01 35.2 21.1 43.7 3 2001-02 34.6 20.1 45.3 4 2002-03 33.8 20.3 45.8 5 2003-04 33.2 20.2 46.5 6 2004-05 32.1 20.6 47.3 7 2005-06 31.8 21.7 46.5 8 2006-07 31.2 21.9 46.8 Sources: www.upgov.nic Q-Quick Estimates P-Provisional Estimates

Looking at the figures shown in above tables, it is noticed that the sectoral composition of Gross State Domestic Product (GSDP), in Uttar

Pradesh, in the year 1999-00 was 35.5, 21.8 and 42.8 percent for the primary, the secondary and the tertiary sectors respectively, while the coixesponding all

India figures were 27.3, 23.0 & 49.7 percent. In the year 2006-07, the corresponding figures of Uttar Pradesh, are 31.2, 21.9 and 46.8 percent whereas for India, they are 21.0, 26.6 and 52.4 percent. 65

Figure 4.3: Distribution of GSDP of Uttar Pradesh

Percentage Distribution of GSDP of Uttar Pradesh

100%

80% — I 60% nteiitary • secondary 40% Bprimafy 20% —

0% 1 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003^ 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 year

The above table shows that in Uttar Pradesh, the shares of primary and

tertiary sectors in 1999-2000 were 35.5 and 42.8 percent respectively, and the

share of secondary sector was 21.8 percent. In 2006-07 (Q) the tertiary sector

surged ahead and reached 46.8 percent while the share of secondary sector

remained same i.e. nearly 22 percent. At all India level the tertiary sector share

was nearly 50 percent and primary sector share was 27.3 percent in 1999-00 and in the year 2006-07 tertiary sector share has risen to 52.4 percent and primary sector share has fallen to 21.0 percent. This analysis depicts that in

Uttar Pradesh, as in die case of India the tertiary sector is growing in the same direction. However, primary sector is still a dominant sector in Uttar Pradesh. 66

Urbanisation

The pace of urbanisation has been lower in the state. The level of urbanisation has been lower than most other states. The numbers of urban centers with more than one lakh population have grown slov/ly over last thirty years. The growth of urban centers with population less than five thousand have, on the other hand, have grown more significantly and these centers have grown in larger numbers in the western part of the states. 67

Table 4.3: Trends of Urbanisation in India

Census Total Urban % of Urban Decadal Annual Year Population Population Growth Growth 1901 5223025 11.20 - -

1911 4720939 10.26 -9.61 -1.01

1921 4728727 10.61 0.16 0.02

1931 5354962 11.28 13.24 1.24

1941 6749767 12.52 26.06 2.31

1951 8225068 13.65 21.86 2.31

1061 8983900 12.81 9.23 0.88

1971 11653740 13.90 29.72 2.60

1981 18740079 17.83 60.89 4.76

1991 25971891 19.68 38.52 3.26

2001 34512624 20.78 32.88 2.84

Sources: CCensu s of India, 2001. Jttar Pradesh. 68

References

Ahmad, H. (1995). Regional Disparities in the Levels of Education in Uttar

Pradesh. DS. 2760. Department of Geography, Aligarh Muslim University,

Aligarh. (INDIA).

Website Accessed www.mapsofindia.com/iittar-pradesh. www.indianetzone.com/uttar-pradesh. www.upgov.nic/upinfo/up_eco.htm]. www.ibef.org. i

Chapter - V Impact of Economic Liberalisation on

Employment Structure in Uttar Pradesh: j

An Analysis

Trends of Employment Change in Three

Sectors of the Economy

Correlation Technique

Conclusion

J 69

Chapter- V

Impact of Economic Liberalisation on Employment Structure in Uttar Pradesh: An Analysis

Employment is clearly one of the most significant issues in terms of the living conditions, of the people of Uttar Pradesh today. Quite simple, there are not enough jobs for all the people who are wiling or forced to work. The rate of employment generation in terms of aggregate main work has been lower than the rate of expansion of the population, and substantially lower than the rate of income growth. As a result, the pattern of job creation has inclined towards more casual, marginal, part time and insecure contracts or self-employment. This pattern has increased following the adoption of liberal policies.

The analysis of this chapter, 'The impact of economic liberalisation on employment structure in Uttar Pradesh', has made a link of liberalisation and employment, the analysis show that level and quality of employment is strongly dependent on the level of economic growth.

Employment is a key determinant of economic welfare and levels of development .In addition, the impact of economic liberalisation on the level and structure of employment is also an important determinant of its impact on poverty, wage and income distribution, and on the quality of employment. 70

Table 5.1: Distribution of Worliforce across Sectors and its Change in Uttar Pradesh

Total Percentage Change (Percentage Point)

Sectors 1981 1991 2001 1991-1981 2000-1991 (%) (%) (%) Primary 74.9 74.46 66.24 -0.4 -8.22 Sector Secondary 9.5 8.8 5.67 -0.6 -3.13 Sector

Tertiary 14.9 17.00 27.4 +2.1 + 10.4 Sector

Source: Various Census Reports

The analysis shows with the help of above table 5.1 that before liberalisation the distribution of workforce engaged in primary sector in 1981 was 74.9 and in 1991, it was 74.46, the change shows a declining trend from

1981 to 1991, which is -0.4 percentage points. Like wise, in secondary sector workforce engaged in 1981 is 9.5, in 1991, 8.8; the change shows the secondary sector has also declined from 1981 to 1991 which is -0.6 percentage points. The third sector is tertiary sector where workforce rises, from 1981 to

1991, which is from 14.9 percent to 17.00 percent. The change shows the increase of + 2.1 p.p. Before liberalisation the rate was lower in primary sector and higher in secondary and tertiary sector. After liberalisation workforce of primary sector declined 66.24 percent from 1991 to 2001, but primary and secondary sectors have declined. The primary sector is in great loss. It clearly shows that after liberalisation tertiary sector rises at higher rate and both primary sector and secondary sector have shown negative growth table 5.1 71 which particularly have significant impact on the primary sector of economy.

The secondary sector has been affected less than half of the primary sectors.

The tertiary sector has gained fairly. Let us see the position at district level in each of these three sectors of economy.

Trends of Employment Change in Three Sectors of the Economy

Trend of Employment Change in Primary Sector 1991-2001

1. Primary Sector:

The primary sector of the economy extracts or harvests products from the earth. The primary sector includes the production of raw material and basic

food items. Activities associated with the primary sector include agriculture both subsistence and commercial, mining, forestry, farming, grazing, hunting

and gathering, fishing, and quarrying. In Uttar Pradesh economic viability goes

in loss in primary sector, due to the shifting of workforce from primary sector

to secondary and tertiary sector.

Table 5.2: Loss of Primary Activities

Categories Name of District's and their Percentage Point

Very High (- Nil. 40.0 and above) High (- 30.0 Aligarh (-32.65), Banda (-37.89). — .40.0)

Medium Varansi (-20.35). (. 20.0 — - 30.0) 72

Low Shaharanpur (-12.22), Muzaffamagar (-10.46),

(-10.0 — - Moradabad (-12.52), Meerut (-18.74), (-

20.0) 15.59), Bulandshar (-15.8), Firozabad (-13.84), Etawah

(-10.81), Kanpumagar (-12.67), Allahabad (12.84),

Sultanpur (-10.14), Deoria (-10.72).

Very Low Mathura (-7.73), Agra (-8.01), Etah (-7.3), Mainpun (- (

Shahjanpur (-7.66), Kheri(-8.59), Sitapur (-6.6), Hardoi

(-7.38), Unno (-7.24), Lucknow (-8.42), Raebareii{-

4.15), Farukhabad (-9.26), Jalaun (-4.37), Jhansi (-2.7),

Lalitpur (-2.93), Hamirpur(-6.38), Fatehpur (-5.13),

Pratapgarh (-6.04), Barabanki (-5.82), Faizabad( -4.49),

Bahraich (-5.33), Gonda (-4.89), Basti (-5 18),

Maharajganj (-4.8), Gorakhpur (-6.12), Azamgarh (-

7.27), Mau (-8.54), Ballia (-9.48), Jaunpur(-4.6),

Ghazipur(-7.82), Mirzapur (-4.55), Sonbhadra (-5.8).

Result: Negative or loss. 73

Uttar Pradesh - Loss of Primary Activities,( 1991-2001)

fig I (-10 0 — -20 0)

Very Low (

Fig. 5.1 74

Table 5.2 & Figure 5.1 shows the loss in primary activities in Uttar

Pradesh due to the shifting of workforce from primary sector to secondary and tertiary sector. All districts of Uttar Pradesh are categorised in to five levels.

Name of the district that include in first level very high loss (- 40.0 and above) nil or no district has found, the district that include in second level high loss (-

30.0 to -40.0) Aligarh (-32.65), Banda (-37.89), the district that include in third level medium loss (-20.0 to -30.0) Varansi (-20.35), the district that include in forth level low loss (- 10.0 and -20.0) Shaharanpur (-12.22), Muzaffamagar (-

10.46), Moradabad (-12.52), Meerut (-18.74), Ghaziabad (-15.59), Bulandshar

(-15.8), Firozabad (-13.84), Etawah (-10.81), Kanpumagar (-12.67), Allahabad

(12.84), Sultanpur (-10.14), Deoria (-10.72), the district that include in fifth level very low loss (< than -10.0) Mathura (-7.73), Agra (-8.01), Etah (-7.3),

Mainpuri (-2.93), Budaun (-7.78), Bareilly(-9.48), Pilibhit (-9.22), Shahjanpur

(-7.66), Kheri(-8.59), Sitapur (-6.6), Hardoi (-7.38), Unno (-7.24), Lucknow (-

8.42), Raebareli(-4.15), Farukhabad (-9.26), Jalaun (-4.37), Jhansi (-2.7),

Lalitpur (-2.93), Hamirpur(-6.38), Fatehpur (-5.13), Pratapgarh (-6.04),

Barabanki (-5.82), Faizabad( -4.49), Bahraich (-5.33), Gonda (-4.89), Basti (-

5.18), Maharajganj (-4.8), Gorakhpur (-6.12), Azamgarh (-7.27), Mau (-8.54),

Ballia (-9.48), Jaunpur(-4.6), Ghazipur(-7.82), Mirzapur (-4.55), Sonbhadra (-

5.8). Finally, the result shows negative or loss that primary sector workforce level goes in loss in Uttar Pradesh due to the shifting of workforce level. 75

Trend of Employment Change in Secondary Sector 1991-2001

2. Secondary Sector:

The secondary sector of the economy manufactures finished goods. All of manufacturing, processing, and construction lies within the secondary sector.

Activities associated with the secondary sector include metal working and smelting, automobile production, textile production, chemical and engineering industries, aerospace manufacturing, energy utilities, engineering, breweries and bottlers, construction, and shipbuilding. In Uttar Pradesh economic viability also goes in loss in secondary sector, but the loss of secondary sector is less than to primary sector.

Table 5.3: Loss of Secondary Activities

Categories Name of District's and their Percentage Point

Very High (- Kanpumagar (-22.29). 20.0 and above)

High (-10.0 — Meerut (-12.45), Ghaziabad (-19.4), Agra (-13.49), - - 20.0) Firozabad(-14. 53).

Medium (0.0 Shahranpur (-8.51), Muzaffamagar (-7.79), Bijnor (- -10.0) 7.9), Moradabad(-7.5), Rampur (-3.8), Bulandshar (-

4.36), Aligarh (-6.29), Mathura (-5.99), Etah (-0.62).

Mainpuri (-1.19), Budaun (-0.02), Bareilly (-3.29).

Pilibhit(-2.41), Shahjanpur(-].36), Unno (-1.31). 76

lucknow (-9.0), Raebareli (-L56), Etawah (-1.24),

Kanpurdehat (-1.31), Jalaun (-1.27), Jhansi (-5.3),

Lalitpur (-1.95), Hamirpur (-2.27), Banda (-0.74),

Fatehpur (-0.65), Faizabad(1.89), Bahraich (-0.86),

Gonda ( -0.04), Basti (-0.92), Gorakhpur(-2.08), Deoria

(-0.82), Jaunpur (-0.4), Varansi (-3.71), Mirzapur (-

7.43).

Low (+10.0 — Kheri (+1.08), Sitapur (+0.4), Hardoi (+1.75), 0.0) Farukhabad (+0.64), Paratapgarh(+0.57), Allahabad

(+0.59), Barabanki (+0.86), Siddharthanagar (+0.6).

Azamgarh (+0.31), Ballia (+1.02), Ghazipur (+0.87),

Sonbhadra(+5.77).

Very Low ( > Nil. —' +10.0)

Result: Again Negative or loss. 77

Uttar Pradesh- Loss of Secondary Activities,( 1991-2001)

Fig 2

Fig. 5.2 78

Table 5.3 & Figure 5.2 shows the moderate loss in secondary activities in Uttar Pradesh due to the shifting of workforce from secondary sector to tertiary sector. All districts of Uttar Pradesh are categorised in to five levels.

Name of the district that include in first level very high loss (- 20.0 and above)

Kanpumagar (-22.29), the district that include in second level high loss (-10.0 to -20.0) Meerut (-12.45), Ghaziabad (-19.4), Agra (-13.49), Firozabad (-14.

53), the district that include in third level medium loss (0.0 to -10.0)

Shahranpur(-8.51), Muzaffamagar(-7.79), Bijnor (-7.9), Moradabad(-7.5),

Rampur(-3.8), Bulandshar (-4.36), Aligarh (-6.29), Mathura (-5.99), Etah (-

0.62), Mainpuri (-1.19), Budaun (-0.02), Bareilly (-3.29), Pilibhit(-2.4I)

Shahranpur (-8.51), Muzaffamagar (-7.79), Bijnor (-7.9), Moradabad(-7.5),

Rampur (-3.8), Bulandshar (-4.36), Aligarh (-6.29), Mathura (-5.99). Etah (-

0.62), Mainpuri (-1.19), Budaun (-0.02), Bareilly (-3.29), Pilibhit(-2.41),

Shahjanpur(-1.36), Unno (-1.31), lucknow (-9.0), Raebareli (-1.56), Etawah (-

1.24), Kanpurdehat (-1.31), Jalaun (-1.27), Jhansi (-5.3), Lalitpur (-1.95),

Hamirpur (-2.27), Banda (-0.74), Fatehpur (-0.65), Faizabad(1.89), Bahraich (-

0.86), Gonda ( -0.04), Basti (-0.92), Gorakhpur(-2.08), Deoria (-0.82), Jaunpur

(-0.4), Varansi (-3.71), Mirzapur (-7.43), the district that include in forth level low loss (+10.0 to 0.0) Kheri (+1.08), Sitapur (+0.4), Hardoi (^1.75),

Farukhabad (+0.64), Paratapgarh(+0.57), Allahabad (+0.59), Barabanki

(+0.86), Siddharthanagar (+0.6), Azamgarh (+0.31), Ballia (+1.02), Ghazipur

(+0.87), Sonbhadra(+5.77) the district that include in fifth level very low loss

(> than +10.0) nil or no district has found. Finally, the result shows moderately 79 negative or loss that secondary sector workforce level goes in loss in Uttar

Pradesh due to the shifting of workforce level.

Trend of Employment Change in Tertiary Sector 1991-2001

Tertiary Sector:

The tertiary sector of the economy is the service industry. This sector provides services to the general population and to businesses Activities associated with this sector include retail and wholesale sales, transportation and distribution, entertainment, movies, television, radio, music, theater, etc , restaurants, clerical services, media, tourism, insurance, banking, Healthcaie, and law. In Uttar Pradesh economic viability goes m gain in tertiary sector, there are many new opportunities open in tertiary sector

Table 5.4: Gain in Tertiary Activities

Categories Name of District's and their Percentage Point

Very High Nil (+40.0 and above)

High (+30.0 — Meerut (+31.09), Ghaziabad (+34.28). +40.0)

Medium (+20.0 Shahranpur (+28 22), Moradabad (+20 01),Bulandshdr — +30.0) (+20 17), Agra (+20 87), Firozabad(+28 38), Varansi

(+23.96) 80

Low (+10.0 -- Muzaffamagar (+18.69), Moradabad (+20.01), Rampur +20.0) (+10.98), Aligarh (+18.94), Mathura (+13.71), Budaun

(+11.81), Bareilly (+12.77), Pilibhit (+11.63), Lucknow

(+17.47), Etawah (+12.05), Allahabad (12.26), Deoria

(+11.21), Mirzapur (+11.98), Sonbhadra (+11.77).

Very Lo>v( < — Etah (+7.81), Mainpuri (+4.12), Shahjahanpur (+9.02), +10.0) Kheri (+7.61), Sitapur (+6.13), Hardoi (+5.63), Unno

(+8.41), Raebareli (+5.71), Farukhabad (+8.62),

Kanpurdehat (+8.69), Kanpumagar (+9.48), Jalaun

(+5.64), Jhansi (+8.1), Lalitpur (+4.58), Hamirpur

(+8.65), Banda (+8.53), Fatehpur (+5.73), Pratapgarh

(+5.38), Barabanki (+4.93), Faizabad (+6.38), Sultanpur

(+8.18), Bahraich (+6.09), Gonda (-4.93),

Siddharthanagar (+3.29), Basti (+6.0), Maharajganj

(+3.72), Gorakhpur (+8.21), Azamgarh (+6.96), Mau

(+8.25), Ballia (+8.46), Jaunpur (+4.9), Ghazipur

(+6.95).

Result: Positive or gain. 81

Uttar Pradesh - Gain in Tertiary Activities, (1991-2001)

Figl

Very Low (<

Fig. 5.3 82

Table 5.4 & Figure 5.3 shows the gain in tertiary activities in Uttar

Pradesh due to the shifting of workforce from other sector to tertiary sector. All districts of Uttar Pradesh are categoried in to five levels. Name of the district that include in first level very high gain (+40.0 and above) nil or no district has found, the district that include in second level high gain (+30.0 to +40.0)

Meerut (+31.09), Ghaziabad (+34.28), the district that include in third level medium gain (+20.0 to +30.0) Shahranpur (+28.22), Moradabad

(+20.01),Bulandshar (+20.17), Agra (+20.87), Firozabad(+28.38), Varansi

(+23.96), the district that include in forth level low gain (+10.0 to +20.0)

Muzaffamagar (+18.69), Moradabad (+20.01), Rampur (+10.98), Aligarh

(+18.94), Mathura (+13.71), Budaun (+11.81), Bareilly (+12.77), Pilibhit

(+11.63), Lucknow (+17.47), Etawah (+12.05), Allahabad (12.26), Deoria

(+11.21), Mirzapur (+11.98), Sonbhadra (+11.77). the district that include in fifth level very low gain (< than +10.0) Etah (+7.81), Mainpuri (-^4.12).

Shahjahanpur (+9.02), Kheri (+7.61), Sitapur (+6.13), Hardoi (+5.63), Unno

(+8.41), Raebareli (+5.71), Farukhabad (+8.62), Kanpurdehat (+8.69),

Kanpumagar (+9.48), Jalaun (+5.64), Jhansi (+8.1), Lalitpur (+4.58), Hamirpur

(+8.65), Banda (+8.53), Fatehpur (+5.73), Pratapgarh (+5.38), Barabanki

(+4.93), Faizabad (+6.38), Sultanpur (+8.18), Bahraich (+6.09), Gonda (+4.93),

Siddharthanagar (+3.29), Basti (+6.0), Maharajganj (+3.72), Gorakhpur

(+8.21), Azamgarh (+6.96), Mau (+8.25), Ballia (+8.46), Jaunpur (+4.9),

Ghazipur (+6.95). Finally, the result shows positive or gain that tertiary sector 83 workforce level goes in gain in Uttar Pradesh due to the shifting of workforce level. Per Capita Income of India and Uttar Pradesh

Income levels are an important determinant of the economic well being

and social development. In terms of per capita income, Uttar Pradesh is among the 'low income category' states along with Bihar, Madhya Pradesh and Orissa.

Moreover, due to sluggish economic growth in Uttar Pradesh, the gap in per

capita income of the state and that of the country has been increasing. The state

economy is also characterised by sharp differences in per capita income levels

across different regions and districts of the state.

Table 5.5: Per Capita Income of India and Uttar Pradesh (Rs.)

State 1993-94 1996-97 2000-01 2003-04

Uttar 5066 7476 9162 10817 Pradesh India 7690 11564 16555 20989

Source: sampark.chd.nic. 84

Table 5.6: District wise Per Capita Income of Uttar Pradesh,

1997-98 (Rs.)

S.No. Districts All S.No. Districts All Sectors Sectors 1 Shahranpur 11256 12 Aligarh 9467

2 Muzaffarnagar 11064 13 Hathras

3 Bijnor 10832 14 Mathura 9064

4 Moradabad 8568 15 Agra 10053

5 Rampur 8725 16 Firozabad 7173

6 J. P. Nagar 17 Etah 8500

7 Meerut 13200 18 Mainpuri 7003

8 Baghpat 19 Budaun 6801

9 Ghaziabad 18064 20 Bareilly 9145

10 G. B. Nagar 21 Pilibhit 9403

11 Bulandshar 10601 22 Shahjahanpur 8811

23 Kheri 8642 42 Fatehpur 7216

24 Sitapur 6961 43 Pratapgarh 4961

25 Hardoi 5997 44 Kaushambi 13202

26 Unno 6358 45 Allahabad 7245

27 Lucknow 11232 46 Barabanki 6267

28 Raebareli 5906 47 Faizabad 6059

29 Farukhabad 7353 48 A. Nagar

30 Kannauj 49 Sultanpur 8061 85

31 Etawah 6177 50 Bahraich 4301

32 Auraiya 51 Sharwasti

33 Kanpurdehat 5993 52 Balrampur

34 Kanpurnagar 5993 53 Gonda 7081

35 Jaiaun 6847 54 Siddharthanagar 4250

36 Jhansi 10424 55 Basti 5099

37 Lalitpur 8700 56 Sant K. Nagar

38 Hamirpur 8353 57 Maharajganj 5957

39 Mahoba 6577 58 Gorakhpur 5693

40 Banda 6517 59 Kushinagar 5411

41 Chitrakot 60 Deoria 4316

61 Azamgarh 5132 66 Chandauli

62 Mau 6575 67 Varanasi 10651

63 Baliia 4426 68 Sant Ravidas 5802

64 Jaunpur 5142 69 Mirzapur 6688

65 Ghazipur 4797 70 Sonbhadra 15310

Source: Human Development Report (2003)

Table 5.7: Distribution of Per Capita Income

Categories Name of District's and tlieir Percentage Point

Very High Ghaziabad (18064). (18064 and above) 86

High (15000 Sonbhadra (15310). — 18064)

Medium Meerut (13200), Agra (10053), Bijnor (10832), (10000 15000) Buladshar (10601), Lucknow (11232), Muzaffamagar

(11064), Shahranpur (11256), Faizabad (6059), varansi

(10651), Jhansi (10424).

Low Firozabad (7173), Mainpuri (7003), Mathra (9064), (5000 10000) Moradabad (8568), Aligarh (9467), Bareilley (9145),

Badaun (6801), Etah (8500), Etawah (6177),

Farukhabad (7353), Unno (6358), Raebareli (5906).

Sitapur (6961), Pilibhit (9403), Rampur (8725),

Shahjahanpur (8811), Barabanki (6267), Fatehpur

(7216), Hardoi (5997), Kanpur (5993), Khaeri (8642),

Mirzapur (6688), Sultanpur (8061), Allahabad (7245),

Azamgarh (5132), Basti (5099),Faizabad (6059),

Gorakhpur (5693), Gonda (7081), Kaushambi (13202),

Maharajganj (5957), Mau (6575), S.R.Nagar (5802).

Banda (6517), Hamirpur (8353), Jalaun (6847), Mahoba

(6577), Lalitpur (8700). Jaunpur(5142), Kaushinagar

(5411).

Very Low ( Praptapgarh (4961), Bahraich (4301), Ballia (4426), 4797 — 5000) Deorai (4316) Ghazipur (4797), Sidhartha Nagar

(4250), Ghazipur (4797). 87

Uttar Pradesh -Per Capita Income, (1997-98)

Fig 4

Voy Low (4797 — 5000)

Fig. 5.4 88

Table 5.7 & Figure 5.4 shows that growth of per capita income in Uttar

Pradesh. The relationship shows growth level of per capita income between three sectors of the economy, primary, secondary, and tertiary sector. All

districts of Uttar Pradesh are categorised in to five levels. Name of the district

that include in first level very high (18064 and above) Ghaziabad (18064), the

district that include in second level high (15000 to 18064) Sonbhadra (15310),

the district that include in third level medium (10000 to 15000) Meerut

(13200), Agra (10053), Bijnor (10832), Buladshar (10601), Lucknow (11232),

Muzaffamagar (11064), Shahranpur (11256), Faizabad (6059), varansi

(10651), Jhansi (10424), the district that include in forth level low (5000 to

10000) Firozabad (7173), Mainpuri (7003), Mathra (9064), Moradabad (8568).

Aligarh (9467), Bareilley (9145), Badaun (6801), Etah (8500), Etawah (6177),

Farukhabad (7353), Unno (6358), Raebareli (5906), Sitapur (6961), Pilibhit

(9403), Rampur (8725), Shahjahanpur (8811), Barabanki (6267), Fatehpur

(7216), Hardoi (5997), Kanpur (5993), Khaeri (8642), Mirzapur (6688).

Sultanpur (8061), Allahabad (7245), Azamgarh (5132), Basti (5099),Faizabad

(6059), Gorakhpur (5693), Gonda (7081), Kaushambi (13202), Maharajganj

(5957), Mau (6575), S.R.Nagar (5802). Banda (6517), Hamirpur (8353), Jalaun

(6847), Mahoba (6577), Lalitpur (8700). Jaunpur(5142), Kaushinagar (5411),

the district that include in fifth level very low (4797 to 5000) Praptapgarh

(4961), Bahraich (4301), Ballia (4426), Deorai (4316) Ghazipur (4797),

Sidhartha Nagar (4250), Ghazipur (4797). 89

Finally, the relationship shows the growth level of per capita income and workforce level of three sectors of the economy.

An Analysis of Per Capita Income in Primary Sector among various

Districts of Uttar Pradesli:

The districts which include high per capita income level, those districts had loss in workforce level and the districts which include a low per capita income those districts had gain in workforce level in primary sector.

An Analysis of Per Capita Income in Secondary Sector among various

Districts of Uttar Pradesh:

The districts which include high per capita income level, those districts had moderately loss in workforce level and the districts which include a low per capita income those districts had moderately gain in workforce level in secondary sector.

An Analysis of Per Capita Income in Tertiary Sector among various

Districts of Uttar Pradesh:

The districts which include high per capita income level, those districts had gain in workforce level and the districts which include a low per capita income level those districts had loss in workforce level in tertiary sector. 90

Table 5.8: Sectoral Distribution of Workforce in Primary Sector

S.No. Districts Primary Sector Change( Percentage Points) 1981 1991 2001 1991-1981 2001-1991

1 Shahranpur 64.40 64.83 52.61 +0.43 -12.22 1

2 Muzaffarnagar 70.90 68.96 58.5 -1.94 -10.46

3 Bijnor 67.72 67.36 57.4 -0.36 +9.96

4 Moradabad 70.10 67.92 55.4 -2.18 -12.52

5 Rampur 75.03 73.18 66.0 -1.85 -7.18

6 J. P. Nagar 63.5

7 Meerut 57.12 55.24 36.5 -1.88 -18.74

8 Baghpat 59.3

9 Ghaziabad 46.98 40.09 24.5 -6.89 -15.59

10 G. B. Nagar 35.0

11 Bulandshar 70.48 68.30 52.5 -2.18 -15.8

12 Aligarh 67.63 65.05 32.4 -2.58 -32.65

13 Hathras 57.8

14 Mathura 68.13 65.03 57.3 -3.1 -7.73

15 Agra 49.55 48.08 40.7 -1.47 -8.01

16 Firozabad 59.34 45.5 -13.84

17 Etah 82.28 79.70 72.4 -2.58 -7.3

18 Mainpuri 81.66 80.03 77.1 -1.63 -2.93

Contd. 91

19 Budaun 86.89 85.28 77.5 -1.61 -7.78

20 Bareilly 71.08 68.18 58.7 -2.9 -9.48

21 Pilibhit 81.28 80.12 70.9 -1.08 -9.22

22 Shahjahanpur 81.44 79.86 72.2 -1.58 -7.66

23 Kheri 89.44 87.59 79.0 -1.85 -8.59

24 Sitapur 86.39 84.40 77.8 -1.99 -6.6

25 Hardoi 88.01 85.78 78.4 -2.23 -7.38

26 Unno 84.90 82.34 75.1 -2.56 -7.24

27 Lucknow 45.40 40.02 31.6 -5.38 -8.42

28 Raebareli 85.15 81.65 77.5 -3.5 -4., 5

29 Farukhabad 78.63 76.36 67.1 -2.27 -9.26

30 Kannauj 69.9

31 Etawah 79.07 77.11 66.3 -1.96 -10.81

32 Auraiya 73.8

33 Kanpurdehat 76.3

34 Kanpurnagar 50.95 17.63 30.3 -33.32 -12.67

35 Jalaun 79.29 78.97 74.6 -0.32 -4.37

36 Jhansi 61.75 63.40 60.7 -1.65 -2.7

37 Lalitpur 81.84 83.23 80.3 + 1.39 -2.93

38 Hamirpur 32.92 83.18 76.8 +50.26 -6.38

39 Mahoba 77.4

Contd. 92

40 Banda 86.19 86.59 48.7 +0.4 -37.89

41 Chitrakot 81.3

42 Fatehpur 84.21 81.83 76.7 -2.38 -5.13

43 Pratapgarh 86.66 83.24 77.2 -3.42 -6.04

44 Kaushambi 78.5

45 Allahabad 69.71 70.04 57.2 +0.33 -12.84

46 Barabanki 86.71 84.02 78.2 -2.69 -5.82

47 Faizabad 81.07 79.59 75.1 -1.58 -4.49

48 A. Nagar 75.3

49 Sultanpur 86.99 84.54 74.4 -2.45 -10.14

50 Bahraich 90.57 88.53 83.2 -2.04 -5.33

51 Shanvasti 88.7

52 Balrampur 86.9

53 Gonda 89.83 88.49 83.6 -1.34 -4.89

54 Siddharthanagar 90.90 87.0 3.9

55 Basti 87.88 85.88 80.7 -2 -5.18

56 Sant K. Nagar 82.1

57 Maharajganj 89.10 84.3 -4.8

58 Gorakhpur 81.56 71.72 65.6 -9.84 -6.12

59 Kushinagar 82.5

Contd. 93

60 Deoria 84.48 83.22 72.5 -1.26 -10.72

61 Azamgarh 78.96 80.07 72.8 + 1.11 -7.27

62 Mau 68.94 60.4 -8.54

63 Ballia 81.41 79.68 70.2 -1.73 -9.48

64 Jaunpur 79.62 76.90 72.3 -2.72 -4.6

65 Ghazipur 46.98 40.09 71.7 -6.89 -7.82

66 Chandauli 64.4

67 Varanasi 52.77 51.85 31.5 -0.92 -20.35

68 Sant Ravidas 40.9

69 Mirzapur 73.29 67.75 63.2 -5.54 -4.55

70 Sonbhadra 78.90 73.1 -5.8 94

Table 5.8 shows the sectoral distribution of workforce in primary sector in Uttar Pradesh. There are 70 districts in Uttar Pradesh according to

2001 census. Table shows distribution of workforce 1981, 1991, 2001 and their change (percentage point) between 1991 to 1981 and 2001 to 1991. After liberalisation period the change (percentage point) between 2001 to 1991 that almost all districts shows negative growth, the districts include their names,

Aligarh (-32.65), Banda (-37.89), Varansi (-20.35), Shaharanpur (-12.22),

Muzaffamagar (-10.46), Moradabad (-12.52), Meerut (-18.74), Ghaziabad (-

15.59), Bulandshar (-15.8), Firozabad (-13.84), Etawah (-10.81), Kanpumagar

(-12.67), Allahabad (12.84), Sultanpur (-10.14), Deoria (-10.72), Mathura (-

7.73), Agra (-8.01), Etah (-7.3), Mainpuri (-2.93), Budaun (-7.78), Bareilly(-

9.48), Pilibhit (-9.22), Shahjanpur (-7.66), Kheri(-8.59), Sitapur (-6.6), Hardoi

(-7.38), Unno (-7.24), Lucknow (-8.42), Raebareli(-4.15), Farukhabad (-9.26),

Jalaun (-4.37), Jhansi (-2.7), Lalitpur (-2.93), Hamirpur(-6.38), Fatehpur (-

5.13), Pratapgarh (-6.04), Barabanki (-5.82), Faizabad( -4.49), Bahraich (-

5.33), Gonda (-4.89), Basti (-5.18), Maharajganj (-4.8), Gorakhpur (-6.12),

Azamgarh (-7.27), Mau (-8.54), Ballia (-9.48), Jaunpur(-4.6), Ghazipur(-7.82),

Mirzapur (-4.55), Sonbhadra (-5.8). There is no positive growth being noticed of workforce in primary sector. It means, after liberalisation period workforce level goes negative or loss in primary sector in Uttar Pradesh. 95

Table 5.9: Sectoral Distribution of Workforce in Secondary Sector

S.No. Districts Secondary Change (Percentage Sector Point)

1981 1991 2001 1991-1981 2001-1991

1 Sliahranpur 13.19 12.61 4.1 -1.3 -8.51

2 Muzaffarnagar 12.54 11.93 3.6 -0.61 -7.79

3 Bijnor 17.07 14.10 6.2 -2.97 -7.9

4 Moradabad 14.07 13.00 5.5 -1.07 -7.5

5 Rampur 10.67 10.40 6.6 -0.27 -3.8

6 J. P. Nagar 8.0

7 Meerut 17.53 17.35 4.9 -0.18 -12.45

8 Baghpat 4.2

9 Ghaziabad 23.96 24.10 4.7 0.14 -19.4

10 G. B. Nagar 4.0

11 Bulandshar 11.48 10.16 5.8 -1.32 -4.36

12 Allgarli 12.55 12.89 6.6 0.34 -6.29

13 Hathras 6.8

14 Matiiura 11.82 10.39 4.4 -1.43 -5.99

15 Agra 21.71 20.09 6.6 -1.62 -13.49

16 Firozabad 20.93 6.4 -14.53

17 Etah 6.45 5.42 4.8 -1.03 -0.62

Contd. 96

18 Mainpuri 6.40 3.89 2.7 -2.51 -1.19

19 Budaun 5.02 3.84 2.9 -1.18 -0.02

20 Bareilly 11.40 8.09 4.8 -3.31 -3.29

21 Pilibhit 7.07 6.11 3.7 -0.96 -2.41

22 Shahjahanpur 6.91 5.06 3.7 -1.85 -1.36

23 Kheri 3.99 2.32 3.4 -1.67 1.08

24 Sitapur 5.30 4.40 4.8 -0.9 +0.4

25 Hardoi 4.36 2.95 4.7 -1.41 + 1.75

26 Unno 5.76 5.47 4.3 -0.29 -1.31

27 Lucknow 13.29 14.00 5.0 +0.71 -9

28 Raebareli 5.60 5.66 4.1 +0.06 -1.56

29 Farukhabad 9.61 7.66 8.3 -1.95 +0.64

30 Kannauj 13.3

31 Etawah 6.79 5.34 4.1 -1.45 -1.24

32 Auraiya 3.3

33 Kanpurdehat 3.2 -1.31

34 Kanpurnagar 19.43 26.19 3.9 +6.76 -22.29

35 Jalaun 6.77 4.87 3.6 -1.9 -1.27

36 Jhansi 12.08 11.20 5.9 -0.88 -5.3

37 Lalitpur 7.03 4.95 3.0 -2.08 -1.95

38 Hamirpur 6.35 5.17 2.9 -1.18 -2.27

Contd. 97

39 Mahoba 3.0

40 Banda 4.78 3.84 3.1 -0.94 -0.74

41 Chitrakot 3.0

42 Fatehpur 6.08 4.25 3.6 -1.83 -0.65

43 Pratapgarh 5.01 4.63 5.2 -0.38 +0.57

44 Kaushambi 5.5

45 Allahabad 12.12 9.11 9.7 -3.01 +0.59

46 Barabanki 6.55 5.44 6.3 -1.11 +0.86

47 Faizabad 7.80 5.79 3.9 -2.01 -1.89

48 A. Nagar 6.2

49 Sultanpur 5.22 4.54 6.6 -0.68 +2.06

50 Bahraich 3.12 3.06 2.2 + 1.42 -0.86

51 Sharwasti 2.6

52 Balrampur 2.3

53 Gonda 3.57 2.74 2.7 -0.83 -0.04

54 S. Nagar 1.70 2.3 +0.6

55 Basti 4.68 4.52 3.6 -0.16 -0.92

56 Sant K. Nagar 3.5

57 Maharajganj 1.72 2.8 + 1.08

58 Gorakhpur 5.40 5.98 3.9 +0.58 -2.08

59 Kushinagar 3.6

Contd. 98

60 Deoria 5.84 4.92 4.1 -0.92 -0.82

61 Azamgarh 11.58 7.59 7.9 -3.99 0.31

62 Mau 17.21 17.5

63 Ballia 5.86 4.38 5.4 -1.48 1.02

64 Jaunpur 9.79 8.00 7.6 -1.79 -0.4

65 Ghazipur 8.43 5.33 6.2 -3.1 +0.87

66 Chandauli 8.0

67 Varanasi 26.04 26.31 22.6 +0.27 -3.71

68 Sant Ravidas 26.0

69 Mirzapur 14.69 18.03 10.6 ^3.34 -7.43

70 Sonbhadra 8.47 2.5 +5.77 99

Table 5.9 shows the sectoral distribution of workforce in secondary sector in Uttar Pradesh. There are 70 districts in Uttar Pradesh according to

2001 census. Table shows distribution of workforce 1981, 1991, 2001 and their change (percentage point) between 1991 to 1981 and 2001 to 1991. After liberalisation period the change (percentage point) between 2001 to 1991 that some of district shows negative growth, the districts include their names,

Kanpumagar (-22.29), Meerut (-12.45), Ghaziabad (-19.4), Agra (-13.49),

Firozabad (-14. 53), Shahranpur (-8.51), Muzaffamagar (-7.79), Bijnor (-7.9),

Moradabad(-7.5), Rampur (-3.8), Bulandshar (-4.36), Aligarh (-6.29), .Mathura

(-5.99), Etah (-0.62), Mainpuri (-1.19), Budaun (-0.02), Bareilly (-3.29),

Pi]ibhit(-2.41), Shahjanpur(-1.36), Unno(-1.31), lucknow (-9.0), Raebareli (-

1.56), Etawah (-1.24), Kanpurdehat (-1.31), Jalaun (-1.27), Jhansi (-5.3).

Lalitpur (-1.95), Hamirpur (-2.27), Banda (-0.74), Fatehpur (-0.65),

Faizabad(1.89), Bahraich (-0.86), Gonda ( -0.04), Basti (-0.92), Gorakhpur(-

2.08), Deoria (-0.82), Jaunpur (-0.4), Varansi (-3.71), Mirzapur (-7.43). The some of districts shows positive growth, these districts include there names

Kheri (+1.08), Sitapur (+0.4), Hardoi (+1.75), Farukhabad (+0.64),

Paratapgarh(+0.57), Allahabad (+0.59), Barabanki (+0.86), Siddharthanagar

(+0.6), Azamgarh (+0.31), Ballia (+1.02), Ghazipur (+0.87), Sonbhadra(+5.77).

It means, after liberalisation period workforce level moderately goes negative or loss in secondary sector in Uttar Pradesh. iOO

Table 5.10: Sectoral Distribution of Workforce in Tertiary Sector

S.No. Districts Tertiary Sector Change (Percentage Point) 1981 1991 2001 1991-2001 2001-1991

1 Sliahranpur 22.41 15.08 43.3 -7.33 +28.22

2 Muzaffarnagar 16.56 19.11 37.8 +2.55 + 18.69

3 Bijnor 15.21 18.55 36.5- +3.34 + 17.95

4 Moradabad 15.83 19.09 39.1 +3.26 +20.01

5 Rampur 14.31 16.42 27.4 +2.11 + 10.98

6 J. P. Nagar 28.6

7 Meerut 25.34 27.41 58.5 +2.07 +31.09

8 Baghpat 37.5

9 Ghaziabad 29.06 35.80 70.08 +6.74 -34.28

10 G. B. Nagar 61.0

11 Bulandshar 18.04 21.53 41.7 +3.49 +20.17

12 Aligarh 19.82 22.06 41.0 +2.24 + 18.94

13 Hathras 35.4

14 Mathura 20.04 24.59 38.3 + 13.09 + 13.71

15 Agra 28.74 31.83 52.7 +3.09 +20.87

16 Firozabad 19.72 48.1 +28.38

17 Etah 11.27 14.89 22.7 +3.62 + 7.81

18 Mainpuri 11.94 16.08 20.2 +4.14 +4.12

Contd. 101

19 Budaun 8.09 11.81 19.5 +3.72 + 11.81

20 Bareilly 17.53 23.73 36.5 +6.2 + 12.77

21 Pilibhit 11.65 13.77 25.4 +2.12 + 11.63

22 Shahjahanpur 11.66 15.08 24.1 +3.42 +9.02

23 Kheri 6.57 10.09 17.7 +3.52 +7.61

24 Sitapur 8.31 11.27 17.4 +2.96 +6.13

25 Hardoi 7.63 11.27 16.9 +3.64 -t-5.63

26 Unno 9.34 12.19 20.6 +2.85 +8.41

27 Lucknow 41.31 46.03 63.5 +4.72 + 17.47

28 Raebareli 9.24 12.69 18.4 +3.45 +5.71

29 Farukhabad 11.76 15.98 24.6 +4.22 +8.62

30 Kannauj 16.8

31 Etawali 14.14 17.55 29.6 +3.41 -12.05

32 Auraiya 23.0

33 Kanpurdehat 11.88 20.5 +26.7 +8.69

34 Kanpurnagar 29.62 56.32 65.8 +26.7 +9.48

35 Jalaun 13.93 16.16 21.8 +2.23 +5.64

36 Jhansi 26.17 25.40 33.5 +0.77 +8.1

37 Lalitpur 11.14 11.82 16.7 +0.68 +4.58

38 Hamirpur 10.73 11.65 20.3 +0.92 +8.65

39 Malioba 19.6 . Contd. 102

40 Banda 9.02 9.57 18.1 +0.55 +8.53

41 Chitrakot 15.7

42 Fatehpur 9.71 13.87 19.6 +4.16 +5.73

43 Pratapgarh 8.32 12.12 17.5 +3.8 +5.38

44 Kaushambi 16.0

45 Allahabad 18.17 20.84 33.1 +2.67 + 12.26

46 Barabanki 6.74 10.47 15.4 +3.73 +4.93

47 Faizabad 11.14 14.62 21.0 +3.48 +6.38

48 A. Nagar 18.5

49 Sultanpur 7.79 10.92 19.1 +3.13 +8.18

50 Bahraich 6.31 8.41 14.5 +2.1 +6.09

51 Sharwasti 8.7

52 Balrampur 10.9

53 Gonda 6.60 8.77 13.7 +2.17 -4.93

54 Siddharthanagar 7.41 10.7 ^3.29

55 Basti 7.44 9.60 15.6 +2.16 +6

56 Sant K. Nagar 14.3

57 Maharajganj 9.18 12.9 +3.72

58 Gorakhpur 13.04 22.29 30.5 +9.25 -8.21

59 Kushinagar 13.9

60 Deoria 9.68 12.19 23.4 +2.51 -11.21

Contd. 103

61 Azamgarh 9.46 12.34 19.3 +2.88 +6.96

62 Mau 13.85 22.1 +8.25

63 Ballia 12.73 15.94 24.4 +3.21 +8.46

64 Jaunpur 10.59 15.10 20.0 +4.51 +4.9

65 Ghazipur 12.88 15.15 22.1 +2.27 +6.95

66 Chandauli ' 27.5

67 Varanasi 21.19 21.84 45.8 +0.64 +23.96

68 Sant Ravidas 33.1

69 Mirzapur 12.03 14.22 26.2 +2.19 -11.98

70 Sonbhadra 12.63 24.4 + 11.77

Source: Census of India 1981, Table B-2(S), Census of India 1991, Table B-2(S) 104

Table 5.10 shows the sectoral distribution of workforce in tertiary sector in Uttar Pradesh. There are 70 districts in Uttar Pradesh according to

2001 census. Table shows distribution of workforce 1981, 1991, 2001 and their change (percentage point) between 1991 to 1981 and 2001 to 1991. After liberalisation period the change (percentage point) between 2001 to 1991 that almost all districts shows positive growth, the districts include their names,

Meerut (+31.09), Ghaziabad (+34.28), Shahranpur (+28.22), Moradabad

(+20.01), Bulandshar (+20.17), Agra (+20.87), Firozabad (+28.38), Varansi

(+23.96), Muzaffamagar (+18.69), Moradabad (+20.01), Rampur (+10.98)

Aligarh (+18.94), Mathura (+13.71), Budaun (+11.81), Bareilly (-rl2.77)

Pilibhit (+11.63), Lucknow (+17.47), Etawah (+12.05), Allahabad (12.26)

Deoria (+11.21), Mirzapur (+11.98), Sonbhadra (+11.77), Etah (r7.81)

Mainpuri (+4.12), Shahjahanpur (+9.02), Kheri (+7.61), Sitapur (r6.13)

Hardoi (+5.63), Unno (+8.41), Raebareli (+5.71), Farukhabad (r8.62j

Kanpurdehat (+8.69), Kanpumagar (+9.48), Jalaun (+5.64), Jhansi (+8.1)

Lalitpur (+4.58), Hamirpur (+8.65), Banda (+8.53), Fatehpur (+5.73)

Pratapgarh (+5.38), Barabanki (+4.93), Faizabad (+6.38), Sultanpur (^8.18)

Bahraich (+6.09), Gonda (+4.93), Siddharthanagar (+3.29), Basti (+6.0)

Maharajganj (+3.72), Gorakhpur (+8.21), Azamgarh (+6.96), Mau (+8.25)

Ballia (+8.46), Jaunpur (+4.9), Ghazipur (+6.95). There is no negative growth being noticed of workforce in tertiary sector. It means, after liberalisation period workforce level goes positive or gain in tertiary sector in Uttar Pradesh. 105

Correlation Coefficient Technique

A correlation coefficient (r): Is "a decimal number between 0.00 and + or -

1.00 that indicates the degree to which two quantitative variables are related".

Formula Correlation Co-efficient:

Correlation(r) =[ NEXY - (2:X)(I:Y) / SqrtdNEX^ - (2:X)^1[NI:Y^ - (L\f\)] where,

N = Number of values or elements

X = First Score

Y = Second Score

SXY = Sum of the product of first and Second Scores

SX = Sum of First Scores

ZY = Sum of Second Scores

SX = Sum of square First Scores

lY' = Sum of square Second Scores 106

Table 5.11: Showing Correlations between District Wise Per Capita Income with Primary, Secondary, Tertiary Sectors

S.No. Correlation Between Number of Values of Variables Variables Correlation

District wise Per Capita 4 -0.320 1 Income -Primary Sector

2 District wise Per Capita 4 -0.526 Income - Secondary Sector

3 District wise Per Capita 4 +0.651 Income - Tertiary Sector

The above table 5.11 shows the correlation coefficient between per capita income of primary, secondary, and tertiary sectors of Uttar Pradesh. Per capita income of districts exhibited highest value of correlation coefficient with tertiary results (+0.651) followed by secondary results (-0.526) and than with primary results (-0.320). The result is obtained at significance levels of 0.01 level in tertiary sector, 0.01 level in secondary sector, 0.05 level in primary sector. It means moderately strong correlation ship between per capita income with tertiary sector. It shows positive correlation ship with rise of income there is increase workforce in tertiary sector. Moderate correlation ship between per capita income with secondary sector. It shows moderately negative correlation ship with rise of per capita income there is moderate decline in workforce in 107 secondary sector. Weak correlation ship between per capita income with primary sector. It shows negative correlation ship with rise in per capita income there is decline in workforce in primary sector. 108

Conclusion

The analysis clearly has established a link between the process of economic liberalisation and change in the nature of employment structure.

There is a clear cut evidence of shifting of employment from primary to secondary and tertiary sector of the economy. Thus, with the liberalisation process there is a marked change in the employment structure with prevalence of tertiary sector, economic activity with urban bias. Over all conclusion shows of all chapters that; first chapter concludes implement of economic liberalisation, origin of the concept, impact of economic liberalisation on employment and economy and how to deal with organised and unorganised sectors. Second chapter concluded the beginning and consequences of economic liberalisation in India. In third chapter literature review conclude earlier work done by scholars. Fourth chapter concluded simply describe the geographical outline of Uttar Pradesh. In fifth chapter conclusion is being made with the helps of tables & graphs that after liberalisation period employment structure in Uttar Pradesh shifted from primary sector to secondary and tertiary sector, the level of workforce shows negative or loss in primary sector, level of workforce shows moderately negative or loss in secondary sector, and level of workforce shows positive or gain in tertiary sector of economy. It means that employment structure shift from agricultural to industry and service sector of the economy. Workforce level shows increase in industry and service sector and decrease in agriculture sector. 109

Following the implementation of liberalisation in Uttar Pradesh, the government faces many new challenges, the level of competition rise in the market, industry produced goods and services are in better quality, so they can challenge the global market and their demands increase in international market, standard of living increases, people are living in better condition and enjoy their higher status, their economic, social, and cultural life has improved, various new opportunities are now open for the people to reach the international and global level. The dynamic information technology (IT) sector has under gone major changes through liberalisation and modernisation, while many employment opportunities rise in this new IT sector. There is a continued emphasis on technological progress in agriculture specially in the backward districts in Uttar Pradesh. Through, liberalisation many new doors opened in economic sectors to raise the over all economy, to raise employment and to reduce poverty, and the sustainable development of the state and better employment opportunities provided for our future generation. So, they can live in a better condition and make efforts to put the economy on the path of economic development and catch the growth pattern of developed nations. 110

Reference

Census of India: Various Census Report.

Human Development Report (2003): Uttar Pradesh. Ill

Proposed Plan for Ph.D. Work

The proposed plan for doctoral research on "The Impact of Economic

Liberalisation on Employment Structure in Uttar Pradesh" would designate basically impact of liberalisation at district level on three sectors of the economy. The proposal plan mainly deal with the level of growth of development of the economy and with level of workforce of primary, secondary, and tertiary sectors. The study will be undertaken by collecting published and unpublished data. The data includes the information on different aspects of distribution of workforce of primary, secondary, and tertiary sectors, and also include the main, marginal and non-workers. All the information has to be collected on the basis of primary and secondary data collection. Fresh information is necessary in order to measure the impact of economic liberalisation on employment structure in Uttar Pradesh.

Proposed tentative plan for doctoral research is given below:

The study will be accomplished in following broad categories.

1. The collection of literature and related work and its analysis.

2. Empirical observation.

3. Collection, computation, interpretation and result of the work related

data.

It is hoped that the proposed study, when completed would add a new chapter of research to the existing knowledge of employment structure and will provide a further base to enhance the scope of economic liberalisation and employment structure of Uttar Pradesh. I

I Bibliography 112

Bibliography

Agarwal, R.N. and Goldar, B. (1995): Economic Reforms and Employment in

India Projections for the year 2001-02: Indian Journal of Labour Economics,

Delhi, Indian Society of Labour Economics, Vol.38, No.4, pp.577-95.

Aggarwal, A. (1991): Estimates of Fixed Capital Stock in the Registered

Manufacturing Sector in India: Working Paper No. 937, Ahmedabad, Indian

Institute of Management.

Ahluwalia, I.J. (1991): Productivity and Growth in Indian Manufacturing:

Delhi, Oxford University Press.

Banerjee, B. (1983): The Role of the Informal Sector in the Migration Process:

A Test of Probabilistic Migration Models and Labour Market Segmentation in

India, Oxford Economic Papers, Oxford, Oxford University Press, pp. 399-422.

Banerjee, B. (1986): Rural to Urban Migration and the Urban Labour Market:

A Case Study of Delhi, Bombay, Himalaya Publishing House.

Bhalotra, Sonia R. (1996): The Spatial Unemployment-Wage Relation

Revisited: An Investigation of Interstate Urban Unemployment Differentials

India University, of Bristol, DP No. 96/409, Mar. 1996.

Chatterji R. (1989): The Behavior of Industrial Prices in India, New Delhi:

Oxford University Press. 113

Chenery, H., Robinson, S. and Syrquin, M. (1986): Industrialization and

Growth: A Comparative Study, New York, Oxford University Press.

Dev, S. Mahendra (2000): Economic Liberalization and Employment in South

Asia-I: Economic and political Weekly, Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 8 Jan., pp.

40-51.

Dutta, R., S. (1998): Lags in employment adjustment and inter-industry differentials: An analysis using dynamic inter-related factor demand functions:

Discussion Paper No. 149, Mumbai, Indira Gandhi Institute of Development

Research.

Fallon, P. and Lucas, R.E.B. (1993): Job Security Regulations and the Dynamic

Demand for Industrial Labour in India and Zimbabwe: Journal of Development

Economics, Amsterdam, Elsevier North Holland, 40.

Ghose, A.K. (1994): Employment in organized manufacturing m India, Indian

Journal of Labour Economics, Delhi, Indian Society of Labour Economics, vol.37(2), April-June, pp.141-62.

Ghose, A.K. (1995): Labour Market Flexibility and the Indian Economy:

Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Delhi, Indian Society of Labour

Economics, vol.38(l), April-June, pp.55-62. 114

Goldar, B. (2000): Employment Growth in Organised Manufacturing in India:

Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 1 Apr., pp. 1191-

1195.

Krueger, A. (1974): The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society:

American Economic Review, Nashville, American Economic Association.

Krueger, A. and Summers, L. (1987): Reflections on the Inter-Industry Wage

Structure, in K. Lang and J. Leonard (eds.): Unemployment and the structure of labour markets, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.

Krueger, A. and Summers, L. (1988): Efficiency Wages and the Inter-Industry

Wage Structure, Econometrica, Evanston, The Econometric Society, 56, pp.

259-293.

Kundu, A. (1997): Trends and Structure of Employment in the 1990s:

Implications for Urban Growth: Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai,

Sameeksha Trust, 14 June.

Marston, S. (1985): Two Views of the Geographic Distribution of

Unemployment: Quarterly Journal of Economics, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press,

79:57-79.

Mathur, A.N. (1989): The Effects of Legal and Contractual Regulations on

Employment in Indian industry, in G. Edgren (ed.): Restructuring, Employment and Industrial Relations, New Delhi, ILO-ARTEP. 115

Minhas, B., et al. (1987): The Cost of Living in Urban India, in Sankhya: The

Journal of the Indian Statistical Association, Poona, Indian Statistical

Association, University of Poona.

Minhas, B., et al. (1990): The Urban Cost of Living in Indian States, in Indian:

Journal of Political Economy, Pune, Indian School of Political Economy.

Minhas, B.S. and Majumdar, G. (1987): Unemployment and Casual Labour in

India: An Analysis of Recent NSS data: Indian Journal of Industrial Relations,

Pune, Indian School of Political Economy, 32(3).

Mitra, A. (1993): Urban Employment, Migrant Labour and Structural Adjustment: Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Delhi, Indian Society of Labour Economics, Vol. 37, No.3.

Mundle, S. (1992): The Employment Effect of Stabilization and Related Policy

Changes in India: 1991-92 to 1993-94: Indian Journal of Labour Economics,

Delhi, Indian Society of Labour Economics, Vol. 35, No.2, July-Sep., pp. 227-

37.

Mundle, S. (1993): Unemployment and Financing of Relief Employment in

Period of Stabilization in India, 1992-1994, Economic and Political Weekly,

Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 30 Jan.

Nagaraj, R. (1984): Subcontracting in Indian Manufacturing Industries:

Analysis, Evidence and Issues, Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai,

Sameeksha Trust, Aug. 116

Nagaraj, R. (1985): Trends in Factory Size in Indian industry: 1950-1980:

Economic and Political Weekly, Review of Management, Mumbai, Sameeksha

Trust, Feb.

Nagaraj, R. (1990): Industrial Growth: Further Evidence and Towards an

Explanation and Issues, Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai, Sameeksha

Trust, 13 Oct., pp.2313-2332.

Nagaraj, R. (1994): Employment and Wages in Manufacturing Industries:

Trends, Hypotheses and Evidence: Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai,

Sameeksha Trust, 22 Jan.

Nagaraj, R. (2000): Organised Manufacturing Employment, Discussion in

Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 16 Sep., pp.3445-

3448.

Nickell, S. (1993): Competition and Corporate Performance, Institute of

Economics and Statistics Applied Economics Discussion Paper No. 155.

University of Oxford.

Nickell, S. and Wadhwani, S. (1990): Insider Forces and Wage Determination:

Economic Journal, Oxford: Blackwell Publishers, on behalf of the Royal

Economic Society, 100, pp. 496-509. 117

Papola, T.S. (1994): Structural Adjustment, Labour Market Flexibility and

Employment: Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Delhi, Indian Society of

Labour Economics, Vol.37, No.l, Jan.-Mar., pp.3-16.

Planning Commission (1990): Employment: Past Trends and Prospects for the

1990s: Working paper. New Delhi, Government of India, May.

Planning Commission (1992): Eighth Five-Year Plan, 1992-97: New Delhi,

Government of India, Vol. 1.

Planning Commission (2001): Report of the Task Force on Employment

Opportunities: New Delhi, Government of India, June.

Rodrik, D. 1992. .The Limits of Trade Policy Reform in Developing Countries:

The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Nashville, American Economic

Association, Vol.6, Issue 1, pp. 87-105.

Rosen, H.S. and Quandt, R.E. (1978): Estimation of a Disequilibrium

Aggregate Labour Market. In Review of Economics and Statistics, Cambridge,

MA, MIT Press, 60:371-379.

Sarvekshana. (1990): Employment and Unemployment: Journal of the National

Sample Survey Organisation, New Delhi, Central Statistical Office,

Government of India. 118

Sen, A. (1996): Economic Reforms, Employment and Poverty: Trends and options: Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, Vol. 31,

Nos. 35-37.

Sengupta, A. (1995): Financial Sector and Economic Reforms in India, Special

Article: Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 7 Jan.

Srivastava, V. (1996): Liberalisation, Productivity and Competition: A Panel

Study of Indian Manufacturing, Delhi, Oxford University Press.

Sundaram, K. (2001): Employment-Unemployment Situation in the Nineties:

Some Results from NSS 55th Round Survey: Economic and Political Weekly

Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 17 Mar., pp.931-940.

Tulpule, B. and Dutta, R. 1988. .Real wages in Indian Industry, in Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 29 Oct.

Unni, J., Lalitha, N. and Rani, U. (2001): Economic Refonns and Productivity

Trends in Indian Manufacturing, Special Article: Economic and Political

Weekly, Mumbai, Sameeksha Trust, 13 Oct., pp. 3914-3922.

Vaidyanathan, A. (1994): Employment Situation: Some Emerging

Perspectives: Special Article: Economic and Political Weekly, Mumbai,

Sameeksha Trust, 10 Dec. 119

Wadhwani, S. and Wall, M. (1991): A Direct Test of the Efficiency Wage

Model: in Oxford Economic Papers, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 529-

547.

Westphal, L. (1981): Empirical justification for infant industry protection:

World Bank Staff working paper No. 455, Washington D.C., World Bank. Annexure .20

Annexure-1

Sectors Workers (in lakh) Decadal Annual Increase Growth Rate 1981* 1991* 1991** 1981-91 1981-91 Total workers 323.97 413.61 388.81 89.64 2.47 1. Cultivators 189.58 220.31 206.86 30.73 1.51 2.Agricultural labourers 51.77 78.33 76.09 26.56 4.23 3.Plantation/Forestry/Fisheries/ 1.77 2.96 2.41 1.19 5.24 Livestock and hunting 4. Mining/ quarrying 0.20 0.35 0.30 0.15 5.69 5. Manufacturing including 29.22 32.05 30.57 2.83 0.93 house hold industry 6. Construction 3.30 5.11 4.35 1.81 4.45 7. Trade/ Commerce 14.69 25.51 23.97 10.82 5.68 8. Transport Storage/ 6.65 7.71 7.15 1.06 1.49 Communication 9. Other Services 26.79 41.28 37.11 14.49 4.42 Source: Distribution of Workers by Industry (Census 1981, 199 1) * Including Uttaranchal ** Excluding Uttaranchal 121

Annexure-2 Distribution of Persons on the Basis of Usual Status (Ps+ss) by Industry in Uttar Pradesh s. Industry Number of Persons (in lakh) Annual Growth Rate N. 32nd 43^" 50th 61st 1977 1993- 1999- roun round roun roun roun -78 94 to 2000 to d d* d* d* to 1999- 2004- (197 (1987- (1993 (1999 (200 1987 2000 05 7-78) 88) -94) 4- -88 2000) 05) 1 Agriculture 262 336 355 351 403 2.52 -0.19 2.80 2 Mining & - - 1 - 1 - - - Quarrying 3 Manufactur 35 42 48 61 84 1.84 4.07 6.61 ing 4 Electricity, - 1 1 1 2 - - 14.87 water etc. 5 Constructio 6 11 12 21 37 6.25 9.77 11.99 n 6 Whole sale 22 30 37 54 66 3.15 6.50 4.10 and retail trades, restaurant and hotels Transport 8 10 13 17 22 2.26 4.57 5,29 7 storage & communicat ion 8 Other 26 41 47 44 46 4.66 -1.09 0.9 & Services 9. Total 359 471 514 549 661 2.75 1.10 3.78 S()urce : Document of Resp active Roiind s of h[SS . 122

Annexure-3 State-wise current daily status of unemployment rates (50th, 55th and 61st round of NSS)

S.N. State 50th round 55th round 61st round Rural Urba Rural Urb Rural Urba n an n 1 Andhra Pradesh 6.3 8 8.1 7.6 10.9 7.9 2 Assam 7.8 9.4 7.4 11.9 6.5 9.0 3 Bihar 6 8.7 7 9.3 6.8 10.0 4 Gujarat 5.6 6 4.8 4.2 4.1 4.7 5 Haryana 6.6 6.6 4.7 4.5 6.2 6.9 6 Karnataka 4.4 6.3 4.3 5.4 6.7 6.0 7 Kerala 14.7 17.7 21.7 19.1 25.6 25.2 8 Madhya Pradesh 2.6 6.8 3.8 7 5.6 6.4 9 Maharashtra 4.3 6.3 6.5 8.1 9.3 8.8 10 Orissa 6.9 9.8 7.1 9.5 10.2 15.0 11 Punjab 2.7 4.1 3.7 4.9 9.7 7.5 12 Rajasthan 1.1 2.4 2.8 4.5 4.4 6.1 13 Tamil Nadu 12.2 9.7 13.5 8.9 15.1 8.6 14 Uttar Pradesh 3.1 4.8 3.6 6.2 3.7 6.3 15 West Bengal 9.1 12.1 17 10.6 11.2 10.5 All India 5.6 7.4 7.1 7.7 8.2 8.3 Source: Document of Respective Rounds of NSS. 123

Annexure-4 Sector Wise Assessment of Employment Potential in Uttar Pradesh during Eleventh Five Year Plan S.N. Sector Potential Employment (in lakh) 1. Health 4.00 2. Education 6.63 3. Information Kiosks(css) 2.00 4: Urban self employment 1.00 5. Agri-clinics 1.04 6. Tourism 6.30 7. Social sector 6.25 8. IT 3.00 9. Bio-Technology 0.23 10. SUDA Seva Centre 0.35 11. Auto industry 2.25 12. Agro industry 1.00 13. Animal Husbandry 0.20 14. Transport 0.50 15. Electronics 0.07 16. Labour 0.05 17. Social Forestry 0.04 18. Textiles 2.50 19. Handloom 1.50 20. Building Construction 0.50 21. Bio-Diesel 22.00 22. Khadi 5.30 23. Dairy 3.00 24. Silk 2.51 25. Land Reclamation 2.00 Total 74.22 Source: www.planning.up.nic.in/annualplan_0809/vol-l.