Sahotra Sarkar · Ben A. Minteer Editors a Sustainable Philosophy— the Work of Bryan Norton the International Library of Environmental, Agricultural and Food Ethics

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Sahotra Sarkar · Ben A. Minteer Editors a Sustainable Philosophy— the Work of Bryan Norton the International Library of Environmental, Agricultural and Food Ethics The International Library of Environmental, Agricultural and Food Ethics 26 Sahotra Sarkar · Ben A. Minteer Editors A Sustainable Philosophy— The Work of Bryan Norton The International Library of Environmental, Agricultural and Food Ethics Volume 26 Series editors Michiel Korthals, Wageningen, The Netherlands Paul B. Thompson, Michigan, USA The ethics of food and agriculture is confronted with enormous challenges. Scientific developments in the food sciences promise to be dramatic; the concept of life sciences, that comprises the integral connection between the biological sciences, the medical sciences and the agricultural sciences, got a broad start with the genetic revolution. In the mean time, society, i.e., consumers, producers, farmers, policymakers, etc, raised lots of intriguing questions about the implications and presuppositions of this revolution, taking into account not only scientific developments, but societal as well. If so many things with respect to food and our food diet will change, will our food still be safe? Will it be produced under animal friendly conditions of husbandry and what will our definition of animal welfare be under these conditions? Will food production be sustainable and environmentally healthy? Will production consider the interest of the worst off and the small farmers? How will globalisation and liberalization of markets influence local and regional food production and consumption patterns? How will all these develop- ments influence the rural areas and what values and policies are ethically sound? All these questions raise fundamental and broad ethical issues and require enormous ethical theorizing to be approached fruitfully. Ethical reflection on criteria of animal welfare, sustainability, liveability of the rural areas, biotechnol- ogy, policies and all the interconnections is inevitable. Library of Environmental, Agricultural and Food Ethics contributes to a sound, pluralistic and argumentative food and agricultural ethics. It brings together the most important and relevant voices in the field; by providing a platform for theoretical and practical contributors with respect to research and education on all levels. More information about this series at http://www.springer.com/series/6215 Sahotra Sarkar • Ben A. Minteer Editors A Sustainable Philosophy— The Work of Bryan Norton 123 Editors Sahotra Sarkar Ben A. Minteer Departments of Philosophy School of Life Sciences and Integrative Biology Arizona State University University of Texas Tempe, AZ Austin, TX USA USA ISSN 1570-3010 ISSN 2215-1737 (electronic) The International Library of Environmental, Agricultural and Food Ethics ISBN 978-3-319-92596-7 ISBN 978-3-319-92597-4 (eBook) https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-92597-4 Library of Congress Control Number: 2018942926 © Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature 2018 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed. The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. The publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. Printed on acid-free paper This Springer imprint is published by the registered company Springer International Publishing AG part of Springer Nature The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland Foreword Rudolf Carnap and External Questions: My Path to Sustainability I am sometimes asked: What philosopher has most affected your work? When I respond, “Rudolf Carnap,” those not associated with philosophy give me a blank look, while those inquirers who know the story of philosophy in the twentieth century are even more nonplussed: How could Carnap’s work, best known for its attack on the meaningfulness of metaphysics and most of traditional philosophy, support my efforts to use philosophy to address contemporary social problems, especially environmental problems? The key to this puzzle requires that we distinguish between two sometimes-clashing themes in Carnap’s work: his empiricist (verificationist) view, associated with the Vienna Circle, and his principle of tolerance (PT), associated with his conventional notion of language. In my dissertation and an early book, I showed that these two themes co-existed throughout Carnap’s career, with the former view being more dominant in the early decades, while the latter view emerged as more central in his more mature philosophy. In a University of Michigan seminar (1968) led by Prof. Jaegwon Kim, we read Carnap’s 1950 piece, “Empiricism, Semantics, and Ontology” (ESO); as I was struggling to understand how to separate “meaningless metaphysics” from what seemed to me to be valuable philosophical insights, I came to see that Carnap’s attitude toward traditional philosophy in 1950 embraced a shift away from his early emphasis on empiricism and the denigration of philosophical utterances as unver- ifiable (see Appendix). By the time he wrote “Empiricism, Semantics, and Ontology,” empiricism appears not as an essential criterion of meaningfulness but rather as posing problems for his ongoing work in semantics, in which he con- structed languages that formed sentences referring to entities, some of which were not observable and would, hence, be unverifiable and meaningless according to the strict empiricism of the Vienna Circle. In particular, he was stung by criticisms from empiricists who charged him with falling into metaphysics when he introduced v vi Foreword conventions that allowed reference to unverifiable (abstract) entities such as num- bers, classes, properties, and relations because he included such entities in the ontologies he introduced to provide semantic content for his constructed languages, which he fashioned to allow creative improvements on the language of science. To respond to these uncomfortable criticisms, Carnap returned in “Empiricism, Semantics, and Ontology” to the second theme, which had been formulated in his early masterwork, The Logical Syntax of Language (1937). There, Carnap rejected attempts of philosophers to exclude some linguistic forms based on “negative requirements” and instead proposed his Principal of Tolerance: It is not our business to set up prohibitions, but to arrive at conventions (Carnap 1937: 51). Elaborating on this point, he said: “In logic there are no morals. Everyone is at liberty to build up his own logic, i.e. his own form of language, as he wishes. All that is required of him is that, if he wishes to discuss it, he must state his methods clearly, and give syntactical rules instead of philosophical arguments” (Carnap 1937: 52). PT merely dramatizes the position more commonly referred to as “linguistic conventionalism,” which asserts that language forms are tools for communication and that choosing linguistic forms necessarily involves choices not fully dictated by the structure and content of reality; they are better understood as proposals to adopt specific languages in particular situations which, in turn, give shape to the reality humans experience. Whereas the strict empiricism of the Vienna Circle positivists aimed to destroy and put to rest philosophical problems, PT aims more at a reconstruction of tra- ditional philosophy. This reconstruction was accomplished by arguing that philo- sophical assertions such as “There are material objects” or “There are numbers” can be rehabilitated by restating them in the metalanguage as assertions about the usefulness, in particular situations, of languages that refer to material objects or to numbers, respectively. Without going into great detail here (see Norton 1977, 2005, 2015, Appendix for more detail), we can see that Carnap was advocating a new mode and purpose for philosophy. The mode was to use linguistic analysis in cooperation with active empirical scientists to improve communication of scientific findings and, in the process, to create “ontologies,” which represent useful interpretations of scientific observations. Chosen linguistic categories can thus reflect models of reality through semantic choices justified not by appeals to “essences” existing in the real world, but with a method of appealing to the practical usefulness of proposed language forms. This apparently innocuous viewpoint has deep and consequential implica- tions for philosophy because choices legitimized by PT can only be resolved or justified by appeal to human purposes and thus require appeals to human interests and values. The linguistic choices that Carnap defends in ESO—based on PT and a human interest in language reformation—are “pragmatic” decisions. In The Logical
Recommended publications
  • American Political Thought: Readings and Materials Keith E. Whittington
    American Political Thought: Readings and Materials Keith E. Whittington Index of Materials for Companion Website 2. The Colonial Era, Before 1776 II. Democracy and Liberty John Adams, Letter to James Sullivan (1776) John Cotton, The Bloudy Tenent Washed and Made White (1647) John Cotton, Letter to Lord Say and Seal (1636) Jacob Duche, The Duty of Standing Fast in Our Spiritual and Temporal Liberties (1775) Massachusetts Body of Liberties (1641) James Otis, Rights of the British Colony Asserted and Proved (1764) Elisha Williams, The Essential Rights and Liberties of Protestants (1744) Roger Williams, The Bloudy Tenent Yet More Bloudy (1652) John Winthrop, Arbitrary Government Described (1644) John Winthrop, A Defense of an Order of Court (1637) John Winthrop, Defense of the Negative Vote (1643) III. Citizenship and Community Agreement among the Settlers of Exeter, New Hampshire (1639) Combination of the Inhabitants of the Piscataqua River for Government (1641) Robert Cushman, The Sin and Danger of Self-Love (1621) Fundamental Agreement, or Original Constitution of the Colony of New Haven (1639) Fundamental Orders of Connecticut (1639) Patrick Henry, Give Me Liberty Speech (1775) William Livingston, “The Vanity of Birth and Titles” (1753) Oath of a Freeman in Massachusetts Bay (1632) Thomas Tryon, The Planter’s Speech to His Neighbors and Countrymen (1684) IV. Equality and Status Address of the Mechanics of New York City (1776) Jonathan Boucher, Sermon on the Peace (1763) Charles Inglis, The True Interest of America (1776) William Knox, Three Tracts Respecting the Conversion (1768) William Byrd, Letter to Lord Egmont (1736) Samuel Sewall, The Selling of Joseph (1700) John Saffin, A Brief and Candid Answer (1701) John Woolman Some Considerations on Keeping Negroes (1762) V.
    [Show full text]
  • Amos Yong Complete Curriculum Vitae
    Y o n g C V | 1 AMOS YONG COMPLETE CURRICULUM VITAE Table of Contents PERSONAL & PROFESSIONAL DATA ..................................................................................... 2 Education ................................................................................................................................................... 2 Academic & Administrative Positions & Other Employment .................................................................... 3 Visiting Professorships & Fellowships ....................................................................................................... 3 Memberships & Certifications ................................................................................................................... 3 PUBLICATIONS ............................................................................................................................ 4 Monographs/Books – and Reviews Thereof.............................................................................................. 4 Edited Volumes – and Reviews Thereof .................................................................................................. 11 Co-edited Book Series .............................................................................................................................. 16 Missiological Engagements: Church, Theology and Culture in Global Contexts (IVP Academic) – with Scott W. Sunquist and John R. Franke ................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955 Herbert Hovenkamp
    University of Minnesota Law School Scholarship Repository Minnesota Law Review 2009 United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955 Herbert Hovenkamp Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mlr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Hovenkamp, Herbert, "United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955" (2009). Minnesota Law Review. 483. https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mlr/483 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the University of Minnesota Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in Minnesota Law Review collection by an authorized administrator of the Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Article United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955 Herbert Hovenkampt INTRODUCTION: HISTORICAL EXPLANATION AND THE MARGINALIST REVOLUTION The history of legal policy toward the economy in the United States has emphasized interest group clashes that led to regula- tory legislation.' This is also true of the history of competition policy. 2 Many historians see regulatory history as little more than a political process in which well-organized, dominant interest groups obtain political advantage and protect their particular in- dustry from competition, typically at the expense of consumers.3 t Ben V. & Dorothy Willie Professor, University of Iowa College of Law. Thanks to Christina Bohannan for commenting on a draft. Copyright 0 2009 by Herbert Hovenkamp. 1. See, e.g., WILLIAM J. NOVAK, THE PEOPLE'S WELFARE: LAW AND REGULA- TION IN NINETEENTH-CENTURY AMERICA 83-84 (1996); THE REGULATED ECONO- MY: A HISTORICAL APPROACH TO POLITICAL ECONOMY 12-22 (Claudia Goldin & Gary D.
    [Show full text]
  • <[email protected]> 15 January 2021 Department of Philosophy
    Sahotra Sarkar University of Texas at Austin E-mail: <[email protected]> 15 January 2021 Department of Philosophy, Department of Integrative Biology, 2210 Speedway, C3500, 205 West 24th St., C0930, Austin, TX 78712 -1180. Austin, TX 78712 -0253. Office: (512) 232 -7122. Office: (512) 232 -3800. FAX: (512) 471 -4806. FAX: (512) 471 -3878. Research Areas: Philosophy and History of Science; Biomedical Humanities; Environmental Philosophy; Formal Epistemology; History of Philosophy of Science; Conservation Biology; Disease Ecology and Epidemiology. Education 1981 -89: University of Chicago: M.A. 1984 (Conceptual Foundations of Science); Ph.D. 1989 (Philosophy). 1977 -81: Columbia University: B.A. 1981 (Mathematics, Philosophy, Physics). Professional Experience Fall 2003 –present: Professor, Department of Philosophy, Department of Integrative Biology, and Center for Computational Biology and Bioinformatics, University of Texas at Austin. Spring 2017 –Spring 2019: Distinguished University Fellow, Presidency University, Kolkata. Fall 2006 –Spring 2007: Graduate Faculty, Institute of Biology, Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México, Mexico City. Fall 2002 –Spring 2003: Visiting Scholar, Max-Planck-Institut für Wissenschaftsgeschichte in Berlin. 1 Fall 2001 –Spring 2010: Co-Director, Environmental Sciences Center, Hornsby Bend, Austin. Fall 1998 –Spring 2002: Associate Professor, Department of Philosophy, and Director, Program in the History and Philosophy of Science, University of Texas at Austin. Fall 1997 –Spring 2000: Research Associate, Redpath Museum, McGill University. Fall 1997 –Spring 1998: Visiting Professor, Departments of Biology and Philosophy, McGill University. Fall 1997 –Spring 1998: Visiting Scholar, Max-Planck-Institut für Wissenschaftsgeschichte in Berlin. Fall 1996 –Spring 1997: Fellow, Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin. Fall 1994 –Spring 1996: Visiting Associate Professor, Department of Philosophy, McGill University.
    [Show full text]
  • Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution
    Florida Law Review Volume 71 Issue 2 Article 4 Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution Herbert Hovenkamp Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/flr Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons Recommended Citation Herbert Hovenkamp, Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution, 71 Fla. L. Rev. 455 (). Available at: https://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/flr/vol71/iss2/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by UF Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Florida Law Review by an authorized editor of UF Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Hovenkamp: Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution REGULATION AND THE MARGINALIST REVOLUTION Herbert Hovenkamp* Abstract The marginalist revolution in economics became the foundation for the modern regulatory State with its “mixed” economy. For the classical political economists, value was a function of past averages. Marginalism substituted forward looking theories based on expectations about firm and market performance. Marginalism swept through university economics, and by 1920 or so virtually every academic economist was a marginalist. This Article considers the historical influence of marginalism on regulatory policy in the United States. My view is at odds with those who argue that marginalism saved capitalism by rationalizing it as a more defensible buttress against incipient socialism. While marginalism did permit economists and policy makers to strike a middle ground between laissez faire and socialism, the “middle ground” tilted very strongly toward public control. Ironically, regulation plus private ownership was able to go much further in the United States than socialism ever could because it preserved the rhetoric of capital as privately owned, even as it deprived firms of many of the most important indicia of ownership.
    [Show full text]
  • Doctoraat FINAAL .Pdf
    Here be dragons Here Exploring the hinterland of science Maarten Boudry Here be dragons Exploring the hinterland of science Maarten Boudry ISBN978-90-7083-018-2 Proefschrift voorgedragen tot het bekomen van de graad van Doctor in de Wijsbegeerte Promotor: Prof. dr. Johan Braeckman Supervisor Prof. dr. Johan Braeckman Wijsbegeerte en moraalwetenschap Dean Prof. dr. Freddy Mortier Rector Prof. dr. Paul Van Cauwenberghe Nederlandse vertaling: Hic sunt dracones. Een filosofische verkenning van pseudowetenschap en randwetenschap Cover: The image on the front cover is an excerpt of a map by the Flemish cartographer Abraham Ortelius, originally published in Theatrum Orbis Terrarum (1570). ISBN: 978-90-7083-018-2 The author and the promoter give the authorisation to consult and to copy parts of this work for personal use only. Every other use is subject to the copyright laws. Permission to reproduce any material contained in this work should be obtained from the author. Faculty of Arts & Humanities Maarten Boudry Here be Dragons Exploring the Hinterland of Science Proefschrift voorgedragen tot het bekomen van de graad van Doctor in de Wijsbegeerte 2011 Acknowledgements This dissertation could not have been written without the invaluable help of a number of people (a philosopher cannot help but thinking of them as a set of individually necessary and jointly sufficient conditions). Different parts of this work have greatly benefited from stimulating discussions with many colleagues and friends, among whom Barbara Forrest, John Teehan, Herman Philipse, Helen De Cruz, Taner Edis, Nicholas Humphrey, Geerdt Magiels, Bart Klink, Glenn Branch, Larry Moran, Jerry Coyne, Michael Ruse, Steve Zara, Amber Griffioen, Johan De Smedt, Lien Van Speybroeck, and Evan Fales.
    [Show full text]
  • Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution
    University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law 5-29-2018 Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution Herbert J. Hovenkamp University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Courts Commons, Economic History Commons, Growth and Development Commons, Industrial Organization Commons, Inequality and Stratification Commons, Intellectual Property Law Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Public History Commons, and the Technology and Innovation Commons Repository Citation Hovenkamp, Herbert J., "Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution" (2018). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law. 1984. https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/1984 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law by an authorized administrator of Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Hovenkamp Marginalism and Regulation June 2018, Page 1 REGULATION AND THE MARGINALIST REVOLUTION Herbert Hovenkamp* PRELIMINARY DRAFT: PLEASE CONSULT AUTHOR BEFORE CITING Abstract The marginalist revolution in economics became the foundation for the modern regulatory State with its “mixed” economy. Marginalism, whose development defines the boundary between classical political economy and neoclassical economics, completely overturned economists’ theory of value. It developed in the late nineteenth century in England, the Continent and the United States. For the classical political economists, value was a function of past averages. One good example is the wage-fund theory, which saw the optimal rate of wages as a function of the firm’s ability to save from previous profits.
    [Show full text]
  • Facilities for Study and Research in the Offices of the United States Government at Washington. Bulletin
    I UNITED STATES BUREAU OFEDUCATION BULLETIN, 1909: NO. 1 . WHOLE NUMBER 398 FACILITIES FOR STUDYAND RESEARCH IN THE OFFICES OF THE UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT AT WASH INGTON By ARTHUR TWINING HADLEY PRESIDENT OF YALE UNIVERSITY I.:- II . 1 4 9 3 3 5 JAN 1 2 1911 a 14' CONTENTS. Pe" LATTER OF TRANSMITTAL Brief history 7 Administration versus education 9 Existing facilities for study and research 11 . Facilities available for the general public 11 Arrangements for the training of CIMSSeS 14, 'Opportunities for individual research 15 Obstacles to student research S ' 17 1. The space difficulty 17 2. The administrative difficulty 18 3. The educational difficulty 19 Conclusions 21 APPENDIX. ,Form of inquiry by the Bureau of Education. 22 Letter of the Secretary of the Interior 23 Replies received: library of Congress 25 Departmen't of State Sureairof Indexvi and Archives Bureau of Rolls and Library 29 Treasury Departanent Public Health and litarine-Ilospital Service 30 Department of Justice - Library ,32 War Deriartment Library of the Surgeon-General's Office 32 Museum of the Surgeon-General's %Ace .33 Office of the Chief of Staff 34 Bureau of Insular Affairs 34 Navy Department Hydrographic Office 36 Naval Observatory.-, ' 35 Naval Medical School 36 Library and Naval War RToriaN. 38 Department of the Interior' General Lana Office 37 .Patent Office 1 37 Bureau of Education 38 Geological survey 40 Reclamation Service 4, 40 Government Hoepital for the Insane 41 3 4 CONTENTS. Replies receivedContinued. 'Page. Department of A griculture Weather Bureau 42 Bureau of Animal Industry 42 Bureau of Plant Industry 42 Forest Service 44 Bbreau of Chemistry 44 Bureau of Soils 45 Bureau of Entomology 46 Biological Survey 47 Office of Experiment Stations 48 Office of Public Roads 49 Library Department of Commerce and Labor.
    [Show full text]
  • The Yale Tradition in Macroeconomics
    The Yale Tradition in Macroeconomics Robert J. Shiller Arthur Okun Professor of Economics Economic Alumni Conference New Haven, April 8, 2011 Early History of Economics at Yale • 1813 Yale under President Timothy Dwight had only three professors: Jeremiah Day, Prof. of Mathematics and Natural Philosoppy,hy, Benjamin Silliman, Prof. of Chemistry and Mineralogy, James L. Kingsley, Prof. of Language and Eccl. History, and six tutors, no economics at all • “Political Economy” first appears in Yale Catalog 1824‐5 • Still no economics professors Economics Text Used 1828‐37: Jean Baptiste Say (1767‐1832) • Probably not Traité d'économie politique 1803 • More likely: Cours complet d'economie politique pratique 1828 Say’ s Cours PREMIÈRE DIVISION. De la nature des richesses. CHAP. Ier.De nos besoins et de nos biens CHAP. II. De la valeur qu' ont les choses CHAP. III. Du fondement de la valeur ou de l'utilité Des opérations productives. CHAP. IV. De ce qu'il faut entendre par la production des richesses CHAP. VI. De quoi se composent les travaux de l'industrie Say’ s Cours CHAP. VII. Classification des industries CHAP. VIII. Des instruments gééénéraux de l'in dustrie et des fonds productifs Il y a un tbltableau synoptique à la suite de ce chithapitre. CHAP. IX. De l'échange des frais de production contre des produits, et de ce qui constitue les progrès industriels CHAP. X. De la nature et de llemploi'emploi des capitaux CHAP. XI. Classification des capitaux CHAP. XII. Des capitaux improductifs CHAP. XIII. De la formation des capitaux CHAP. XIV. De la dissipation des capitaux CHAP.
    [Show full text]
  • List of Skull and Bones Members - Wikipedia
    12/30/2019 List of Skull and Bones members - Wikipedia List of Skull and Bones members Skull and Bones, a secret society at Yale University, was founded in 1832. Until 1971, the organization published annual membership rosters, which were kept at Yale's library. In this list of notable Bonesmen, the number in parentheses represents the cohort year of Skull and Bones, as well as their graduation year. There are no official rosters published after 1982 and membership for later years is speculative. Some news organizations refer to them as a power elite.[1] Contents Founding members (1832–33 academic year) 19th century 1830s 1840s 1850s 1860s 1870s 1880s 1890s Skull and Bones entry from the 20th century 1948 Yale Banner. Former 1900s United States President George 1910s Herbert Walker Bush is listed 1920s fourth down. 1930s 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s to present References Further reading Founding members (1832–33 academic year) https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_Skull_and_Bones_members 1/21 12/30/2019 List of Skull and Bones members - Wikipedia Frederick Ellsworth Mather (1833), Democratic member of the New York State Assembly (1854–1857)[2] Phineas Timothy Miller (1833), American physician[2] William Huntington Russell (1833), Connecticut State Legislator, Major General[3]:82 Alphonso Taft (1833), U.S. Attorney General (1876–1877), Secretary of War (1876), Ambassador to Austria-Hungary (1882) and Russia (1884–1885), father of William Howard Taft[3]:82 George Ingersoll Wood (1833), American clergyman[2] 19th century 1830s Asahel Hooker Lewis (1833), newspaper editor and member William Huntington Russell, founder of the Ohio General Assembly[2] of Skull and Bones and the namesake of the society's corporate John Wallace Houston (1834), Secretary of State of Delaware body, the Russell Trust Association (1841–1844), associate judge Delaware Superior Court (1855–1893)[2] John Hubbard Tweedy (1834), delegate to the United States Congress from Wisconsin Territory (1847–1848)[2] William Henry Washington (1834), Whig U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics CV
    CURRICULUM VITA (2019) ROBERT B. EKELUND, JR. OFFICE ADDRESS: Department of Economics College of Liberal Arts Auburn University Auburn, Alabama 36849 HOME ADDRESS: 404 Blake Street Auburn, Alabama 36830 (334) 821-1404; cell (334) 703-6872 e-mail: [email protected] http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Robert_Ekelund http://ideas.repec.org/e/pek2.html EDUCATION: B.B.A. (Economics; Minors, General Business, Art History) St. Mary's University, San Antonio, Texas (1962) M.A. (Economics; Minor, Ancient and Medieval History) St. Mary's University, San Antonio, Texas (1963). Thesis: Contributions of Francis Amasa Walker to Economic Thought: L. H. Mai, Director. Ph.D. (Economics; Minor, Political Theory) Louisiana State University (1967). Dissertation: A Critical Evaluation of Jules Dupuit's Contributions to Economic Theory and Policy: James P. Payne, Jr., Director. EMPLOYMENT (ACADEMIC) 2003 (October) – Present Edward K. and Catherine L. Eminent Scholar in Economics (Emeritus) Auburn University 2006 (March) – 2007 (March) Acting Co-Director, Jule Collins Smith Museum of Fine Art at Auburn University 1 1988 (October) – 2003 (October) Edward K. and Catherine L. Lowder Eminent Scholar Auburn University 2003 (January-May) Vernon F. Taylor Distinguished Professor (Visiting) Trinity University (San Antonio) 1992 (July) Visiting Scholar Hoover Institute, Stanford University 1987 - 1988 Liberty National Professor of Economics, Auburn University 1983 - 1987 Lowder Professor of Economics Auburn University Jan. 1979 – October 2003 Professor of Economics Auburn University 1977-1978 Visiting Professor of Economics Auburn University 1967 - 1979 From Assistant Professor (1967-1970) to Associate Professor (1970-1974) to Professor (1974- 1979) of Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station, Texas. 1966-1967 Instructor of Economics, Louisiana State University 1963-1966 Graduate Teaching Assistant in Economics, Louisiana State University 1962-1963 Instructor of Economics, St.
    [Show full text]
  • Patents and Productive Inefficiency William Hubbard University of Baltimore School of Law, [email protected]
    University of Baltimore Law ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 9-2014 The eD bilitating Effect of Exclusive Rights: Patents and Productive Inefficiency William Hubbard University of Baltimore School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarworks.law.ubalt.edu/all_fac Part of the Intellectual Property Law Commons Recommended Citation The eD bilitating Effect of Exclusive Rights: Patents and Productive Inefficiency, 66 Fla. L. Rev. 2045 (2014) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE DEBILITATING EFFECT OF EXCLUSIVE RIGHTS: PATENTS AND PRODUCTIVE INEFFICIENCY William Hubbard· Abstract Are we underestimating the costs of patent protection? Scholars have long recognized that patent law is a double-edged sword. While patents promote innovation, they also limit the number of people who can benefit from new inventions. In the past, policy makers striving to balance the costs and benefits of patents have analyzed patent law through the lens of traditional, neoclassical economics. This Article argues that this approach is fundamentally flawed because traditional economics rely on an inaccurate oversimplification: that individuals and firms always maximize profits. In actuality, so-called "productive inefficiencies" often prevent profit maximization. For example, cognitive biases, bounded rationality, habituation, and opportunism all contribute to productive inefficienci.es that harm individuals, firms, and ultimately society.
    [Show full text]