<<

ISSUE BRIEF 11.30.17 Are Consumption Really Regressive?

Jorge Barro, Ph.D., Fellow, Center for Public Finance

In the , state and municipal rises, the portion of income allocated to governments rely heavily on consumption consumption declines, and the portion revenues to finance their expenditures. allocated to savings rises—concepts for According to the U.S. Census Bureau, which John Maynard Keynes coined the consumption taxation generated $544 billion terms “marginal propensity to consume” of revenue in 2015, amounting to 3% of gross and “marginal propensity to save.” This domestic product and financing roughly one- decline in consumption as a percentage of third of all sub-federal level expenditures. income is often used to substantiate claims Roughly two-thirds of consumption tax of consumption tax regressivity. Such a revenue was generated by sales taxes, while claim obfuscates the fact that savings is just the remaining one-third was generated by another term for future consumption, which and other consumption taxes. As of eventually faces similar tax exposure. 2017, 45 states and the District of Columbia, Because annual income fluctuates as well as municipal governments in 38 significantly over a lifetime, economist states, collect sales taxes,1 while every state James Poterba argued that annual and several municipal governments, as well consumption taxes paid as a fraction of as the U.S. federal government, levy some annual income is not a good measure of kind of excise tax.2 tax progressivity. Individuals use savings Given this extensive dependence to shift consumption throughout their on consumption taxation to finance lives, suggesting that lifetime consumption government expenditures, policymakers taxes paid as a fraction of lifetime income should carefully consider who bears the is a better measure of consumption tax Many argue that sales burden of the tax. progressivity. As a proxy for lifetime and excise taxes are On the surface, a consumption tax consumption tax progressivity, Poterba regressive based on seems simple: a tax that is proportional proposed studying consumption expenditure the strict relationship to the things that we consume. In composition as it relates to income. If reality, consumption tax bases are highly consumption composition shifts away between annual income partitioned into groups of expenditure from taxable items as income increases, and taxes paid. items that receive special treatment, either then the consumption tax burden falls through differential tax rates or through disproportionately onto households with tax exemptions. Housing, for example, is lower lifetime income, confirming claims of not taxed at the sales , but rather consumption tax regressivity. However, if at the rate. Most health care taxable consumption increases with income, expenditures, by contrast, are exempt from we have no reason to conclude that the tax taxation altogether. burden falls more heavily onto households Many argue that sales and excise with lower lifetime income. taxes are regressive based on the strict A particularly interesting feature of relationship between annual income sales and excise taxes is that individuals and taxes paid. As a household’s income can avoid them by not consuming the RICE UNIVERSITY’S BAKER INSTITUTE FOR PUBLIC POLICY // ISSUE BRIEF // 11.30.17

taxed items. For example, one could take step involves determining how taxable public transportation to avoid paying sales consumption in each tax base changes with tax on a vehicle and excise tax on fuel. household income. A negative relationship Because of this differential tax treatment would indicate that the tax burden falls across consumption goods, each household more heavily on low-income households, expenditure can be categorized according while a positive relationship would imply to whether or not it is included in the sales the opposite. The burden of an or excise tax bases. Following Poterba’s method, measuring the relationship between increase in the sales DESCRIPTION OF DATA tax rate may actually sales- and excise-taxable expenditures and income provides a better indication of how fall more heavily on This study analyzes data from the 2015 CEX, the respective tax burden corresponds to which documents an estimated 60-70% households with higher lifetime income. of all household expenditures at varying lifetime incomes. To test whether high-income earners granularity of consumption categories.3 substitute away from taxable goods, a Although the expenditure items in the typical tax base can be reconstructed using survey do not comprise an exhaustive the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX). budget, the CEX still provides the best data This data set contains detailed information available for studying taxable expenditure regarding household expenditures and patterns as they relate to income. income levels. The first step in analyzing Figure 1 shows how broad expenditure the data involves identifying which categories change with annual household consumption items are typically included income levels. The largest expenditure in sales or excise tax bases. The next share is housing, which makes up roughly one-third of all measured expenditures and declines as income rises. The next largest FIGURE 1 — EXPENDITURE COMPOSITION AND INCOME share is food, retail, and miscellaneous expenditures, which comprise nearly a 1 quarter of measured expenditures at every income level. Education and financial 0.9 expenditures, which include insurance payments and contributions to pensions, 0.8 tend to rise with income. Transportation 0.7 outlays, including vehicle payments and fuel, comprise around 10% of measured 0.6 expenditures and decline with income. Average health expenditures by households 0.5 are less than 10% of measured consumer 0.4 expenditures, and the expenditure share declines slightly with income. Finally, alcohol 0.3 and tobacco maintain a small but flat share

Measurable Expenditure Share of expenditures. 0.2

0.1 DESCRIPTION OF TAXABLE ITEMS 0 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Base Annual Household Income (in hundred thousands) While each state levies its sales tax on a unique set of consumption goods, several Food, Retail, Misc. Transportation Housing states have many of the same items in Financial and Education Health Alcohol and Tobacco their tax bases. Of the large expenditure categories, education, financial services,

and health are generally excluded from sales

2 ARE CONSUMPTION TAXES REALLY REGRESSIVE?

taxation. Within the housing expenditures FIGURE 2 — SALES-TAXABLE CONSUMPTION SHARE AND INCOME category, property payments, such as rent or mortgage, are generally excluded from 0.3 the sales tax base, but home furnishings and appliances are usually not excluded. This leaves transportation, food, retail, and miscellaneous expenditures to comprise the remaining sales tax base. Groceries are usually exempt from sales taxation, while 0.25 restaurant dining is often not exempt. Public transportation is generally excluded from sales taxation, but vehicle payments are included in the sales tax base. Retail and miscellaneous items, such as personal care products, are generally taxed as sales, but 0.2 most services are not taxed. For the purpose of constructing a realistic sales tax base,

entertainment services, such as sporting Sales-taxable Consumption Percentage event tickets, are included in the sales tax base, but other services are excluded. 0.15 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 Excise Tax Base Annual Household Income (in hundred thousands) Consumption items are categorized as excise-taxable based on whether they are generally treated by the tax system uniquely. Motor vehicle fuel, alcohol, tobacco, lodging (e.g., hotel stays), and home utilities, such as electricity and water, each satisfy the FIGURE 3 — EXCISE-TAXABLE CONSUMPTION SHARE AND INCOME definition of an excise tax and collectively comprise the excise tax base. 0.25

MEASURING PROGRESSIVITY

After carefully evaluating the CEX data set 0.2 and constructing a typical tax base, the next step is to estimate the percentage of taxable expenditures across income levels.4 Figure 2 shows that the share of expenditures 0.15 included in the sales tax base increases steadily by roughly five percentage points— from 18% to 23%—for households earning up to $100,000 per year. However, the 0.1 base declines around one percentage point beyond $130,000 and stabilizes at around Sales-taxable Consumption Percentage 22% of consumption for households earning above $200,000. This graph suggests that sales taxation 0.05 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 may actually be progressive for most Annual Household Income (in hundred thousands) households. Data from the 2015 Current Population Survey shows that 73.6% of U.S. households had an annual income less than $100,000, and 87.7% of households had an 3 RICE UNIVERSITY’S BAKER INSTITUTE FOR PUBLIC POLICY // ISSUE BRIEF // 11.30.17

income below $150,000. Further breakdown of this relationship across different age ENDNOTES groups results in a similar pattern, suggesting 1. See at https:// that lifetime consumption patterns do not taxfoundation.org/state-and-local-sales- show evidence of differential age-dependent tax-rates-in-2017/. after accounting for income. 2. Ibid. This suggests that a shift in taxation toward 3. See Bureau of Labor Statistics at sales taxation may actually increase a state https://www.bls.gov/opub/hom/cex/data. or municipal tax structure’s progressivity. htm. Figure 3 shows that the excise tax 4. In Figures 2 and 3, a non-parametric burden falls more heavily on lower- locally weighted regression is used to income households. As household income estimate the percentage of taxable increases up to $100,000, the fraction of consumption as it relates to income. excise-taxable expenditures falls about six percentage points and declines another four percentage points as household REFERENCES income rises to $300,000. As opposed to sales taxation, a shift toward excise Keynes, John M. 1936. The General Theory of taxation reduces the progressivity of a Employment, Interest and Money. New state or municipal tax structure. York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Poterba, James M. 1989. “Lifetime incidence and the distributional burden of excise CONCLUSION taxes.” Working paper no. 2833, Although sales taxation often faces National Bureau of Economic Research. opposition based on the assumption of a strict relationship between income and taxes AUTHOR paid, this analysis shows that sales-taxable

See more issue briefs at: consumption actually rises with income. This Jorge Barro, Ph.D., is a fellow in public www.bakerinstitute.org/issue-briefs implies that the burden of an increase in the finance at the Baker Institute Center for sales tax rate may actually fall more heavily Public Finance. His area of research involves This publication was written by a on households with higher lifetime incomes. the development of dynamic macroeconomic researcher (or researchers) who By contrast, excise-taxable consumption models for evaluation. He was participated in a Baker Institute project. falls as income rises, suggesting that previously an economist at the University Wherever feasible, this research is reviewed by outside experts before it is increases in excise taxes unambiguously of Pennsylvania’s Wharton Public Policy released. However, the views expressed affect lower-income households more than Initiative, where he led the development of herein are those of the individual higher-income households. their dynamic macroeconomic model and author(s), and do not necessarily While this study can serve as a quick helped launch the nonpartisan Penn Wharton represent the views of Rice University’s reference for policymakers considering Budget Model. Baker Institute for Public Policy. the effects of changing the sales or excise © 2017 Rice University’s Baker Institute tax rate, a tax jurisdiction’s actual tax for Public Policy progressivity depends on the unique composition of its tax base. Choosing to This material may be quoted or restructure the sales or excise tax base reproduced without prior permission, through exemptions and inclusions almost provided appropriate credit is given to the author and Rice University’s Baker certainly changes the tax structure’s Institute for Public Policy. progressivity. To that extent, policymakers wishing to study the progressivity of Cite as: taxing particular consumption bundles Barro, Jorge. 2017. Are Consumption can reconstruct elements of their specific Taxes Really Regressive? Issue brief no. 11.30.17. Rice University’s Baker Institute tax base using the CEX to measure the for Public Policy, Houston, Texas. relationship between taxable consumption share and income. 4