The Politics of Economic Growth in Postwar America 1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Politics of Economic Growth in Postwar America 1 More The Politics of Economic Growth in Postwar America ROBERT M. COLLINS 1 2000 3 Oxford New York Athens Auckland Bangkok Bogotá Buenos Aires Calcutta Cape Town Chennai Dar es Salaam Delhi Florence Hong Kong Istanbul Karachi Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Mumbai Nairobi Paris São Paulo Singapore Taipei Tokyo Toronto Warsaw and associated companies in Berlin Ibadan Copyright © 2000 Published by Oxford All rights reserved. No by Robert M. University Press, Inc. part of this publication Collins 198 Madison Avenue, may be reproduced, New York, New York stored in a retrieval 10016. system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, Oxford is a registered mechanical, trademark of Oxford photocopying, recording, University Press. or otherwise, without the prior permission of Oxford University Press. Library of Congress Cataloging–in–Publication Data Collins, Robert M. More : the politics of economic growth in postwar America / Robert M. Collins. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0–19–504646–3 1. Wealth—United States—History—20th century. 2. United States—Economic policy. 3. United States—Economic conditions—1945–. 4. Liberalism—United States— History—20th Century. 5. National characteristics, American. I. Title. HC110.W4C65 2000 338.973—dc21 99–022524 Design by Adam B. Bohannon 987654321 Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper For My Parents Contents Preface ix Acknowledgments xiii Prologue: The Ambiguity of New Deal Economics 1 1 > The Emergence of Economic Growthmanship 17 2 > The Ascendancy of Growth Liberalism 40 3 > Growth Liberalism Comes a Cropper, 1968 68 4 > Richard Nixon’s Whig Growthmanship 98 5 > The Retreat from Growth in the 1970s 132 6 > The Reagan Revolution and Antistatist Growthmanship 166 7 > Slow Drilling in Hard Boards 214 Conclusion 233 Notes 241 Index 285 Preface bit of personal serendipity nearly three decades ago inspired this A book. In 1971 I visited Washington, D.C., and happened upon an arti- fact of the American Century that has stayed in my mind ever since. It was the so-called GNP clock, and the story behind it fascinated me. The GNP clock was an appropriately outsized toteboard full of lights and numbers that the Department of Commerce had constructed to keep track of the nation’s economic growth. The aim was to record and publicize the point at which the U.S. economy achieved a rate of growth that would, if continued for one year, yield a $1 trillion gross national product.1 At the appropriate moment, all the bells and whistles of the Nixon administra- tion’s public relations machinery would announce to the world yet another milestone in the progress of the world’s richest economy. By prearrangement, the numbers on the board were to flash the $1 tril- lion figure at noon on a winter’s day late in 1970, at which time President Richard Nixon would usher in the economic millennium with a few cele- bratory remarks. Alas, the president’s arrival was delayed. Mild panic set in as technicians scrambled madly to turn the machine back. But the board seemed to take on a life of its own, and despite their best efforts it flashed the $1 trillion figure at 12:02. By the time Nixon finally arrived at 12:07, $2.3 million more had been added as the machine began calculating the GNP at a wildly accelerating rate.2 Some Americans, less enamored of economic growth than the Republican president, saw this victory of machine over man and of matter over mind as ominously symbolic. In outline, the story of the GNP clock seemed to feed all of my prejudices. At the time, I felt a left liberal’s powerful antipathy toward Nixon, whom I and my friends called the Trickster even before Watergate; and reflecting my graduate student penury and the influence of counterculture values on x > Preface even an aspiring middle-class professional, I embraced a weak but excep- tionally smug antimaterialism that held in contempt not my own quite strong desire for acquisition but rather my culture’s somewhat more abstract (but still indisputably real) and surely less refined materialism. All in all, the GNP clock story struck me at the time as an apt metaphor for eco- nomic growth, materialism, and technology all run amok. It was only years later, when I read the full text of Richard Nixon’s remarks on that occasion, that I came to suspect that perhaps the GNP clock episode expressed something more complicated—and more interesting— than the rather arch morality play I had first envisioned. In the land where, John Kenneth Galbraith had sworn just a decade earlier, the cult of produc- tion held absolute sway, Nixon’s remarks sounded a strangely defensive note: “I think that rather than apologizing for our great, strong, private enterprise economy, we should recognize that we are very fortunate to have it.” “Don’t look at it,” he urged, “simply in terms of a great group of selfish people, money grubbing.” The real significance of the trillion-dollar achievement, he stressed, was not production for its own sake but rather what an economy of that size and strength made possible. Plans for improving the income, health, education, and housing of America’s poor and middle classes were fanciful unless backed by such productive capacity: “Unless we produce the wealth, all of those great dreams, those idealistic plans for doing things for people, aren’t going to mean anything at all.” Nixon stood for growth, defiantly but not mindlessly. Here, at what had appeared at first blush to be little more than a civic celebration of Mammon, Nixon gave thanks that “as a result of our moving forward on the economic side . we can now turn more to the qual- ity of life and not just to its quantity.”3 Reading Nixon’s speech after the fact, it occurred to me that perhaps America’s embrace of economic growth had been more complex, more nuanced, more ambiguous, and perhaps even more ambivalent, than either contemporaries or historians have generally recognized. The chapters that follow explore that possibility. This book, then, is about how the pursuit of economic growth came to become a central and defining feature of U.S. public policy in the half-cen- tury after the end of World War II. Commentators in the 1950s coined the term “growthmanship” to describe the seemingly single-minded pursuit of exuberant economic growth that was then appearing to dominate the polit- ical agenda and the public dialogue throughout the Western industrialized world, nowhere more dramatically than in that bastion of materialistic excess, the United States. I examine the origins of the postwar embrace of growth and trace how that initial growthmanship evolved over time. Preface > xi Over the last half of the twentieth century, American political leaders, policymakers, and intellectuals created a succession of growth regimes, all of which emphasized growth both as an end in itself and, more important, as a vehicle for achieving a striking variety of other, ideological goals as well. In one regard, I follow the lead of many observers in seeing the pursuit of growth as a time-honored way of avoiding hard questions and evading tough decisions about the distribution of wealth and power in America. At the same time, however, I depart from the view that Americans in the post- war era “substituted economic performance for political ideology.”4 Rather, I contend that growth did not suspend or supersede ideological conflict so much as embody and express it. The political economy of growth became an important arena for ideological expression and conflict in the postwar era; throughout, ideology shaped conceptions of growth, while, at the same time, growth itself influenced ideology. As a result of this interpene- tration, economic growth over time emerged as a much more complex and heavily freighted phenomenon than the rhetoric of many of its champions and most of its detractors allowed. It is my intention to make that complex- ity both more discernible and more comprehensible. Of course, I do not mean to suggest that it was only in the postwar era that growth came to be recognized or valued. Economists since Adam Smith have long recognized the importance of growth for a rising standard of living; Smith himself wrote in 1776 that “it is not the actual greatness of national wealth, but its continued increase, which occasions a rise in the wages of labor.”5 From the time of Alexander Hamilton’s Report on Manu- factures in 1791 and its gradual implementation in the early nineteenth cen- tury, the federal government used land and trade policies to encourage national development. Similarly, fears about the end of growth or about limits to growth, usually expressed as anxiety regarding the disappearance of the frontier, became a staple of American discourse as early as the 1880s.6 What made the postwar pursuit of growth distinctively modern was the availability of new state powers and means of macroeconomic management dedicated to achieving growth that was more exuberant, more continuous and constant, more aggregately quantifiable, and also more precisely mea- sured than ever before. Perhaps we can best appreciate what made postwar growthmanship distinctive by looking at the context from which it emerged, for it was the ambivalence of New Deal economic policy that made the sub- sequent emergence of growthmanship seem like a striking departure. Acknowledgments riting is a solitary exercise, but completing a book is a collective W achievement. This book has been a long time in coming, and my indebtedness to others has grown accordingly over the years. Many friends and colleagues read portions of the work in progress, and Colin Gordon and Michael Hogan read the penultimate draft in its entirety.
Recommended publications
  • The Employment Act of 1946: a Half Century of Experience
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Washington University St. Louis: Open Scholarship Washington University in St. Louis Washington University Open Scholarship Weidenbaum Center on the Economy, Murray Weidenbaum Publications Government, and Public Policy Policy Brief 169 4-1-1996 The Employment Act of 1946: A Half Century of Experience Murray L. Weidenbaum Washington University in St Louis Follow this and additional works at: https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/mlw_papers Part of the Economics Commons, and the Public Policy Commons Recommended Citation Weidenbaum, Murray L., "The Employment Act of 1946: A Half Century of Experience", Policy Brief 169, 1996, doi:10.7936/K7571960. Murray Weidenbaum Publications, https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/mlw_papers/143. Weidenbaum Center on the Economy, Government, and Public Policy — Washington University in St. Louis Campus Box 1027, St. Louis, MO 63130. NOT FOR RELEASE BEFORE 2:00 E.S.T. APRIL 26, 1996 Center for the Study of The Employment Act of 1946: American A Half Century of Experience Business Murray_Weidenbaum C918 Policy Brief 169 April 1996 Contact: Robert Batterson Communications Director (314) 935-5676 Washington University Campus Box 120B One Brookings Drive St. Louis. Missouri 63130-4899 The Employment Act of 1946: A Half Century of Experience by Murray Weidenbaum The first half century of experience under the Employment Act of 1946 (originally the Full Employment Bill of 1945) likely has disappointed both the proponents and the opponents of that innovative law. The impact on national economic policy is neither as bad as the opposition feared nor as substantial as the sponsors had hoped.
    [Show full text]
  • The Kennedy and Johnson Years. SPONS AGENCY National Inst
    DOCUMENT RESUME ED 231 050 iA 015 ;711 AUTHOR Graham, Hugh Davis TITLE The Transformation of Federal Education,Policy: The Kennedy and Johnson Years. SPONS AGENCY National Inst. of Education (ED), Washington, DC. PUB DATE. Jan 83 , GRANT NIE-G-80-0139' .NOTE . 427p: PUB TYPE Historical Materials (060) -- Reports - General (140) Books (010) EDRS PRICE ME01/PC18 Plus Postage." DESCRIPTORS *Advisory Committees; Advocacy; Archives; De ision . Making; Educational Change; *Educational.His ory; : *Educational Legislation; Educational'Oualit Federal Government; Federal Legislation; Federal Programs4 Government School Relationship; Historiography; *PoliCy Formation;'Political Power;, Political Science; *Presidents; Social Change; Social SCience Research IDENTIFIERS Congress; *Great Society; Johnson (Lyndon Baines); Kennedy (John F); *Task Force Approach ABSTRACT Archive-based historical anaIysis brings a perspective to policy studies that is lackingn individual case° studies. The recently opened Kennedy and Johnson arChives facilitate an internal analysis of the evolution of education policyformulation in the 1960s from the petspective of the executive branch. The central thread of continuity for such an analysis is executive planning through presidential task forces, such as those coordinated in the mid-1960$ by Bill Moyers and Joseph Califano. While task . forcing was for Kennedy largely a one-shot ceampagn effort,of dubious efficacy, it was crucial for Johnson's construction of'the Great Sciciety's programmatic base. Task forces provide both
    [Show full text]
  • THE UNITED STATES and SOUTH AFRICA in the NIXON YEARS by Eric J. Morgan This Thesis Examines Relat
    ABSTRACT THE SIN OF OMISSION: THE UNITED STATES AND SOUTH AFRICA IN THE NIXON YEARS by Eric J. Morgan This thesis examines relations between the United States and South Africa during Richard Nixon’s first presidential administration. While South Africa was not crucial to Nixon’s foreign policy, the racially-divided nation offered the United States a stabile economic partner and ally against communism on the otherwise chaotic post-colonial African continent. Nixon strengthened relations with the white minority government by quietly lifting sanctions, increasing economic and cultural ties, and improving communications between Washington and Pretoria. However, while Nixon’s policy was shortsighted and hypocritical, the Afrikaner government remained suspicious, believing that the Nixon administration continued to interfere in South Africa’s domestic affairs despite its new policy relaxations. The Nixon administration concluded that change in South Africa could only be achieved through the Afrikaner government, and therefore ignored black South Africans. Nixon’s indifference strengthened apartheid and hindered liberation efforts, helping to delay black South African freedom for nearly two decades beyond his presidency. THE SIN OF OMMISSION: THE UNITED STATES AND SOUTH AFRICA IN THE NIXON YEARS A Thesis Submitted to the Faculty of Miami University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts Department of History by Eric J. Morgan Miami University Oxford, Ohio 2003 Advisor __________________________________ (Dr. Jeffrey P. Kimball) Reader ___________________________________ (Dr. Allan M. Winkler) Reader ___________________________________ (Dr. Osaak Olumwullah) TABLE OF CONTENTS Acknowledgements . iii Prologue The Wonderful Tar Baby Story . 1 Chapter One The Unmovable Monolith . 3 Chapter Two Foresight and Folly .
    [Show full text]
  • A Dinner Tribute to Joseph A. Pechman
    This document is from the collections at the Dole Archives, University of Kansas http://dolearchives.ku.edu A Dinner Tribute to Joseph A. Pechman "In his generation of Washington intellectuals - the people who make a difference not because of their offices or their connections, but because of the force of their writing and their argument- none had more influence than Mr. Pechman. None used it with greater generosity or a surer sense of the public interest" I The Washington Post Wednesday, August 23, 1989 The Brookings Institution 1775 Massachusetts Avenue, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20036-2188 202/797-6220 Page 1 of 29 This document is from the collections at the Dole Archives, University of Kansas http://dolearchives.ku.edu A Dinner Tribute to Joseph A. Pechman hosted by The Brookings Institution Tuesday, April 24, 1990 6:30 p.rn. The Hyatt Regency Hotel Capitol Hill 400 New Jersey Avenue, N.W. Washington District of Columbia Page 2 of 29 This document is from the collections at the Dole Archives, University of Kansas http://dolearchives.ku.edu Joseph A. Pechman, one of America's most influential economists and leading theoretician on tax policy, was Director of the Economic Studies Program at The Brookings lnstitution for more than 20 years. At his death, he was Senior Fellow Emeritus in Economic Studies. Joe Pechman came to Brookings in 1960 after serving on the staff of the Council of Economic Advisers, the Committee for Economic Development, and the Office of Price Administration. As Director of Economic Studies from 1962 to 1983, he managed programs in the study of government finance and supervised research in social economics and regulatory policy.
    [Show full text]
  • “Mcconnell Majorities” in Supreme Court Decision-Making
    PRESIDENT-SHOPPING FOR A NEW SCALIA: THE ILLEGITIMACY OF “MCCONNELL MAJORITIES” IN SUPREME COURT DECISION-MAKING J. Stephen Clark* WASHINGTON, June 29—By the slimmest of margins, the Supreme Court today ended its decades of protecting abortion rights and overruled Roe v. Wade,1 the 1973 decision that established abortion as a constitutional right.2 The breaking news one day in June 2019 is the demise of Roe v. Wade. By a vote of 5-4, the Supreme Court has overruled the precedent and left the protection of abortion rights to the sole discretion of lawmakers. There had been no majority for such a decision until President Trump had the chance to make two appointments to the Court. One of those appointees wrote the majority opinion. Perhaps fittingly, the author of the opinion was the successor to the late Justice Antonin Scalia, who strove for this goal more vigorously than any member of the Court since 1973. Of course, every supporter of abortion rights realizes that the Trump appointee now sits on the High Court only because President Obama’s nominee for the same seat was ignored by the Senate for eleven months. The overruling of Roe is directly traceable to that stonewalling and its mastermind—the majority leader, Senator Mitch McConnell of Kentucky. Why should supporters of abortion rights accept the legitimacy of a Court decision handed down by a bare majority that owes its fifth vote to Mitch McConnell’s Supreme Court Justice? The answer is that they would not, nor should they. Contrary to McConnell’s repeated claims, his posture of determined inaction * Professor of Law, Albany Law School.
    [Show full text]
  • Recessions and Recoveries
    Mark A. Wynne Nathan S. Balke Senior Economist Assistant Professor of Economics Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Southern Methodist University and Research Associate Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Recessions and Recoveries he U.S. economy entered recession in July the behavior of groups of leading, coincident, and T 1990 and began to recover, many analysts lagging indicators in the first seven months of six believe, in April or May 1991. Since then, the recoveries (the earliest being that following the economy has grown at a pace so sluggish as to be trough in July 1924, the latest being that following indistinguishable, in some ways, from continued the trough in August 1954, since revised to May recession. However, as early as spring 1991, several 1954) and tentatively concluded that “recoveries observers were expressing the opinion that the in output, employment, and profits have usually recovery from the 1990–91 recession would not been faster after severe depressions than after be particularly robust because the recession itself mild contractions” (p. 88). Moore (1965) contains was not particularly severe. For example, in Busi- a restatement of the finding that severe contractions ness Week in June 1991, Alan Blinder argued, tend to be followed by strong expansions, and “Shallow recessions are followed by weak recov- Bry and Boschan (1971) present further evidence eries for a simple reason: An economy that has on this proposition, focusing on growth in non- not fallen far has little catching up to do. And agricultural employment. catch-up
    [Show full text]
  • The National Data Center Proposal of 1965 and Its Descendants
    Statistical Déjà Vu: The National Data Center Proposal of 1965 and Its Descendants by Rebecca S. Kraus, Ph.D. History Staff U.S. Census Bureau For presentation at the Joint Statistical Meetings Miami Beach, FL, August 1, 2011 This paper is to inform interested parties of ongoing research and to encourage discussion. Any views expressed on historical issues are those of the author and not necessarily those of the U.S. Census Bureau. Abstract Issues concerning sharing of statistical information, linking data sets, and storing and preserving data collected by the federal statistical agencies have long sparked debate. This paper focuses on the National Data Center proposal of 1965, ensuing public concern over its privacy implications, and the response of the Bureau of the Budget and the U.S. Census Bureau. The purpose of this study is to identify the issues leading to the development of the proposal, as well as the consequences of the proposal, in order to inform current policy decisions, particularly in regard to the U.S. Census Bureau. Examples of subsequent efforts at statistical consolidation and data sharing highlight the persistent theme of statistical déjà vu. The author would like to thank the following staff of the U.S. Census Bureau for their review and comment on the contents of this paper: Francis Grailand Hall, Division Chief, Administrative and Customer Services Division (ACSD); Claudette Bennett, Assistant Division Chief, Product Development and Publications Services, ACSD; Bill Maury, Chief, History Staff, ACSD; Nick Birnbaum, History Staff, ACSD; Nancy Gordon, Associate Director for Strategic Planning and Innovation; Mary Frazier, Privacy Office; and Kathleen Styles, formerly of the Policy Office.
    [Show full text]
  • John Mitchell and the Crimes of Watergate Reconsidered Gerald Caplan Pacific Cgem Orge School of Law
    University of the Pacific Scholarly Commons McGeorge School of Law Scholarly Articles McGeorge School of Law Faculty Scholarship 2010 The akM ing of the Attorney General: John Mitchell and the Crimes of Watergate Reconsidered Gerald Caplan Pacific cGeM orge School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarlycommons.pacific.edu/facultyarticles Part of the Legal Biography Commons, and the President/Executive Department Commons Recommended Citation 41 McGeorge L. Rev. 311 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the McGeorge School of Law Faculty Scholarship at Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in McGeorge School of Law Scholarly Articles by an authorized administrator of Scholarly Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Book Review Essay The Making of the Attorney General: John Mitchell and the Crimes of Watergate Reconsidered Gerald Caplan* I. INTRODUCTION Shortly after I resigned my position as General Counsel of the District of Columbia Metropolitan Police Department in 1971, I was startled to receive a two-page letter from Attorney General John Mitchell. I was not a Department of Justice employee, and Mitchell's acquaintance with me was largely second-hand. The contents were surprising. Mitchell generously lauded my rather modest role "in developing an effective and professional law enforcement program for the District of Columbia." Beyond this, he added, "Your thoughtful suggestions have been of considerable help to me and my colleagues at the Department of Justice." The salutation was, "Dear Jerry," and the signature, "John." I was elated. I framed the letter and hung it in my office.
    [Show full text]
  • Xerox University Microfilms
    INFORMATION TO USERS This material was produced from a microfilm copy of the original document. While the most advanced technological means to photograph and reproduce this document have been used, the quality is heavily dependent upon the quality of the original submitted. The following explanation of techniques is provided to help you understand markings or patterns which may appear on this reproduction. 1.The sign or "target" for pages apparently lacking from the document photographed is "Missing Page(s)". If it was possible to obtain the missing page(s) or section, they are spliced into the film along with adjacent pages. This may have necessitated cutting thru an image and duplicating adjacent pages to insure you complete continuity. 2. When an image on the film is obliterated with a large round black mark, it is an indication that the photographer suspected that the copy may have moved during exposure and thus cause a blurred image. You will find a good image of the page in die adjacent frame. 3. When a map, drawing or chart, etc., was part of the material being photographed the photographer followed a definite method in "sectioning" the material. It is customary to begin photoing at die upper left hand corner of a large sheet and to continue photoing from left to right in equal sections with a small overlap. If necessary, sectioning is continued again — beginning below the first row and continuing on until complete. 4. The majority of users indicate that the textual content is of greatest value, however, a somewhat higher quality reproduction could be made from "photographs" if essential to the understanding of the dissertation.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter One: Postwar Resentment and the Invention of Middle America 10
    MIAMI UNIVERSITY The Graduate School Certificate for Approving the Dissertation We hereby approve the Dissertation of Jeffrey Christopher Bickerstaff Doctor of Philosophy ________________________________________ Timothy Melley, Director ________________________________________ C. Barry Chabot, Reader ________________________________________ Whitney Womack Smith, Reader ________________________________________ Marguerite S. Shaffer, Graduate School Representative ABSTRACT TALES FROM THE SILENT MAJORITY: CONSERVATIVE POPULISM AND THE INVENTION OF MIDDLE AMERICA by Jeffrey Christopher Bickerstaff In this dissertation I show how the conservative movement lured the white working class out of the Democratic New Deal Coalition and into the Republican Majority. I argue that this political transformation was accomplished in part by what I call the "invention" of Middle America. Using such cultural representations as mainstream print media, literature, and film, conservatives successfully exploited what came to be known as the Social Issue and constructed "Liberalism" as effeminate, impractical, and elitist. Chapter One charts the rise of conservative populism and Middle America against the backdrop of 1960s social upheaval. I stress the importance of backlash and resentment to Richard Nixon's ascendancy to the Presidency, describe strategies employed by the conservative movement to win majority status for the GOP, and explore the conflict between this goal and the will to ideological purity. In Chapter Two I read Rabbit Redux as John Updike's attempt to model the racial education of a conservative Middle American, Harry "Rabbit" Angstrom, in "teach-in" scenes that reflect the conflict between the social conservative and Eastern Liberal within the author's psyche. I conclude that this conflict undermines the project and, despite laudable intentions, Updike perpetuates caricatures of the Left and hastens Middle America's rejection of Liberalism.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Report of the President.” ______
    REFERENCES Chapter 1 American Civil Liberties Union. 2013. “The War on Marijuana in Black and White.” Accessed January 31, 2016. Aizer, Anna, Shari Eli, Joseph P. Ferrie, and Adriana Lleras-Muney. 2014. “The Long Term Impact of Cash Transfers to Poor Families.” NBER Working Paper 20103. Autor, David. 2010. “The Polarization of Job Opportunities in the U.S. Labor Market.” Center for American Progress, the Hamilton Project. Bakija, Jon, Adam Cole and Bradley T. Heim. 2010. “Jobs and Income Growth of Top Earners and the Causes of Changing Income Inequality: Evidence from U.S. Tax Return Data.” Department of Economics Working Paper 2010–24. Williams College. Boskin, Michael J. 1972. “Unions and Relative Real Wages.” The American Economic Review 62(3): 466-472. Bricker, Jesse, Lisa J. Dettling, Alice Henriques, Joanne W. Hsu, Kevin B. Moore, John Sabelhaus, Jeffrey Thompson, and Richard A. Windle. 2014. “Changes in U.S. Family Finances from 2010 to 2013: Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances.” Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 100, No. 4. Brown, David W., Amanda E. Kowalski, and Ithai Z. Lurie. 2015. “Medicaid as an Investment in Children: What is the Long-term Impact on Tax Receipts?” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 20835. Card, David, Thomas Lemieux, and W. Craig Riddell. 2004. “Unions and Wage Inequality.” Journal of Labor Research, 25(4): 519-559. 331 Carson, Ann. 2015. “Prisoners in 2014.” Bureau of Justice Statistics, Depart- ment of Justice. Chetty, Raj, Nathaniel Hendren, Patrick Kline, Emmanuel Saez, and Nich- olas Turner. 2014. “Is the United States Still a Land of Opportunity? Recent Trends in Intergenerational Mobility.” NBER Working Paper 19844.
    [Show full text]
  • Nixon's Caribbean Milieu, 1950–1968
    Dark Quadrant: Organized Crime, Big Business, and the Corruption of American Democracy Online Appendix: Nixon’s Caribbean Milieu, 1950–1968 By Jonathan Marshall “Though his working life has been passed chiefly on the far shores of the continent, close by the Pacific and the Atlantic, some emotion always brings Richard Nixon back to the Caribbean waters off Key Biscayne and Florida.”—T. H. White, The Making of the President, 19681 Richard Nixon, like millions of other Americans, enjoyed Florida and the nearby islands of Cuba and the Bahamas as refuges where he could leave behind his many cares and inhibitions. But he also returned again and again to the region as an important ongoing source of political and financial support. In the process, the lax ethics of its shadier operators left its mark on his career. This Sunbelt frontier had long attracted more than its share of sleazy businessmen, promoters, and politicians who shared a get-rich-quick spirit. In Florida, hustlers made quick fortunes selling worthless land to gullible northerners and fleecing vacationers at illegal but wide-open gambling joints. Sheriffs and governors protected bookmakers and casino operators in return for campaign contributions and bribes. In nearby island nations, as described in chapter 4, dictators forged alliances with US mobsters to create havens for offshore gambling and to wield political influence in Washington. Nixon’s Caribbean milieu had roots in the mobster-infested Florida of the 1940s. He was introduced to that circle through banker and real estate investor Bebe Rebozo, lawyer Richard Danner, and Rep. George Smathers. Later this chapter will explore some of the diverse connections of this group by following the activities of Danner during the 1968 presidential campaign, as they touched on Nixon’s financial and political ties to Howard Hughes, the South Florida crime organization of Santo Trafficante, and mobbed-up hotels and casinos in Las Vegas and Miami.
    [Show full text]