Partisan Gerrymandering and the Efficiency Gap Nicholas Stephanopoulos

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Partisan Gerrymandering and the Efficiency Gap Nicholas Stephanopoulos University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Public Law and Legal Theory Working Papers Working Papers 2014 Partisan Gerrymandering and the Efficiency Gap Nicholas Stephanopoulos Eric McGhee Follow this and additional works at: https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/ public_law_and_legal_theory Part of the Law Commons Chicago Unbound includes both works in progress and final versions of articles. Please be aware that a more recent version of this article may be available on Chicago Unbound, SSRN or elsewhere. Recommended Citation Nicholas Stephanopoulos & Eric McGhee, "Partisan Gerrymandering and the Efficiency Gap" (Public Law and Legal Theory Working Paper No. 493, 2014) available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2457468.. This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Working Papers at Chicago Unbound. It has been accepted for inclusion in Public Law and Legal Theory Working Papers by an authorized administrator of Chicago Unbound. For more information, please contact [email protected]. CHICAGO PUBLIC LAW AND LEGAL THEORY WORKING PAPER NO. 493 PARTISAN GERRYMANDERING AND THE EFFICIENCY GAP Nicholas Stephanopoulos and Eric McGhee THE LAW SCHOOL THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO October 2014 This paper can be downloaded without charge at the Public Law and Legal Theory Working Paper Series: http://www.law.uchicago.edu/academics/publiclaw/index.html and The Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection. PARTISAN GERRYMANDERING AND THE EFFICIENCY GAP 82 U. CHI. L. REV. (forthcoming 2015) Nicholas O. Stephanopoulos* Eric M. McGhee** The usual legal story about partisan gerrymandering is relentlessly pessimistic. The courts did not even recognize the cause of action until the 1980s; they have never struck down a district plan on this basis; and four sitting Justices want to vacate the field altogether. The Supreme Court’s most recent gerrymandering decision, however, is the most encouraging development in this area in a generation. Several Justices expressed interest in the concept of partisan symmetry—the idea that a plan should treat the major parties symmetrically in terms of the conversion of votes to seats—and suggested that it could be shaped into a legal test. In this Article, we take the Justices at their word. First, we introduce a new measure of partisan symmetry: the efficiency gap. It represents the difference between the parties’ respective wasted votes in an election, divided by the total number of votes cast. It captures, in a single tidy number, all of the packing and cracking decisions that go into a district plan. It also is superior to the metric of gerrymandering, partisan bias, that litigants and scholars have used until now. Partisan bias can be calculated only by shifting votes to simulate a hypothetical tied election. The efficiency gap eliminates the need for such counterfactual analysis. Second, we compute the efficiency gap for congressional and state house plans between 1972 and 2012. Over this period as a whole, the typical plan was fairly balanced and neither party enjoyed a systematic advantage. But in recent years—and peaking in the 2012 election—plans have exhibited steadily larger and more pro-Republican gaps. In fact, the plans in effect today are the most extreme gerrymanders in modern history. And what is more, several likely will remain extreme for the remainder of the decade, as indicated by our sensitivity testing. Finally, we explain how the efficiency gap could be converted into doctrine. We propose setting thresholds above which plans would be presumptively unconstitutional: two seats for congressional plans and eight percent for state house plans, but only if the plans probably will stay unbalanced for the rest of the * Assistant Professor of Law, University of Chicago Law School. ** Research Fellow, Public Policy Institute of California. This Article builds on our earlier legal and political science work on redistricting. It is part of a larger project aimed at grasping the consequences—and improving the law—of this important and intricate activity. For helpful comments, we are grateful to Bruce Cain, Jowei Chen, Chris Elmendorf, Andrew Gelman, Michael Gilbert, Ruth Greenwood, Bernie Grofman, Rick Hasen, Benjamin Highton, Vlad Kogan, Justin Levitt, and Rick Pildes. We are pleased as well to acknowledge the support of the Robert Helman Law and Public Policy Fund at the University of Chicago. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2457468 1 Efficiency Gap cycle. Plans with gaps above these thresholds would be unlawful unless states could show that the gaps either resulted from the consistent application of legitimate policies, or were inevitable due to the states’ political geography. This approach would neatly slice the Gordian knot the Court has tied for itself, explicitly replying to the Court’s “unanswerable question” of “how much political . effect is too much.” TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION .............................................................................................1 I. THE DOCTRINAL OPPORTUNITY ...................................................................... 6 A. Pre-LULAC ................................................................................................ 6 B. LULAC ...................................................................................................... 8 C. Post-LULAC ............................................................................................ 11 II. THE EFFICIENCY GAP ..................................................................................... 14 A. Definition and Computation .................................................................... 14 B. Key Properties ......................................................................................... 16 C. Comparison to Partisan Bias ................................................................... 18 D. Limitations .............................................................................................. 25 III. GERRYMANDERING OVER TIME AND SPACE .................................................. 28 A. Summary Statistics .................................................................................. 29 B. Individual Plans ....................................................................................... 34 C. Gerrymandering Litigation ...................................................................... 36 IV. A POTENTIAL TEST ........................................................................................ 39 A. Setting the Threshold............................................................................... 40 B. Presumptive Validity and Invalidity ........................................................ 44 C. Concerns and Responses ......................................................................... 48 CONCLUSION ........................................................................................................ 51 INTRODUCTION Cass Sunstein once quipped that the non-delegation doctrine (which purports to limit congressional delegations of authority to agencies) “has had one good year, and 211 bad ones.”1 According to the conventional wisdom, the cause of action for partisan gerrymandering2 has not had even this one good year. The claim was not recognized until 1986, when the Supreme Court ruled that gerrymandering is justiciable but still upheld a pair of Indiana district plans that used every trick in the book to disadvantage the state’s Democrats.3 Since 1986, not a single plaintiff has managed to persuade a court to strike down a plan on 1 Cass R. Sunstein, Nondelegation Canons, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 315, 322 (2000). 2 We note at the outset that, consistent with the metric we introduce in this Article, whenever we refer to “gerrymandering,” we mean district plans whose electoral consequences are asymmetric. We do not mean plans that were devised with partisan intent. Our conception of gerrymandering is strictly effects-based. 3 See Davis v. Bandemer, 478 U.S. 109, 118-43 (1986). Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2457468 Efficiency Gap 2 this basis.4 By our count, claimants’ record over this generation-long period is roughly zero wins and fifty losses.5 And adding insult to injury, a majority of the Court rejected almost every conceivable test for gerrymandering in 2004, and a plurality would have extricated the judiciary from this domain altogether.6 But the gloomy conventional wisdom is not quite right. In the Court’s most recent gerrymandering case, LULAC v. Perry,7 several Justices expressed surprising enthusiasm for the concept of partisan symmetry—the idea, that is, that a district plan should treat the major parties symmetrically with respect to the conversion of votes to seats. Justice Stevens raved that symmetry is “widely accepted by scholars as providing a measure of partisan fairness in electoral systems.”8 Justice Souter noted that “[i]nterest in exploring this notion is evident.”9 And, most remarkably of all, Justice Kennedy declared that he did not “discount[] its utility in redistricting planning and litigation.”10 These comments, overlooked by almost all scholars and litigants in the aftermath of LULAC,11 are the most promising development in this area in decades. They provide the motivation for our effort, in this Article, to introduce a new measure of partisan symmetry and to show how it could be fashioned into a workable judicial standard. We dub our new measure the efficiency gap.12 It represents the difference between
Recommended publications
  • H.Doc. 108-224 Black Americans in Congress 1870-2007
    “The Negroes’ Temporary Farewell” JIM CROW AND THE EXCLUSION OF AFRICAN AMERICANS FROM CONGRESS, 1887–1929 On December 5, 1887, for the first time in almost two decades, Congress convened without an African-American Member. “All the men who stood up in awkward squads to be sworn in on Monday had white faces,” noted a correspondent for the Philadelphia Record of the Members who took the oath of office on the House Floor. “The negro is not only out of Congress, he is practically out of politics.”1 Though three black men served in the next Congress (51st, 1889–1891), the number of African Americans serving on Capitol Hill diminished significantly as the congressional focus on racial equality faded. Only five African Americans were elected to the House in the next decade: Henry Cheatham and George White of North Carolina, Thomas Miller and George Murray of South Carolina, and John M. Langston of Virginia. But despite their isolation, these men sought to represent the interests of all African Americans. Like their predecessors, they confronted violent and contested elections, difficulty procuring desirable committee assignments, and an inability to pass their legislative initiatives. Moreover, these black Members faced further impediments in the form of legalized segregation and disfranchisement, general disinterest in progressive racial legislation, and the increasing power of southern conservatives in Congress. John M. Langston took his seat in Congress after contesting the election results in his district. One of the first African Americans in the nation elected to public office, he was clerk of the Brownhelm (Ohio) Townshipn i 1855.
    [Show full text]
  • Gerrymandering Becomes a Problem
    VOLUME TWENTY FOUR • NUMBER TWO WINTER 2020 THE SPECIAL ELECTION EDITION A LEGAL NEWSPAPER FOR KIDS Gerrymandering Becomes a Problem Battling Over for the States to Resolve How to Elect by Phyllis Raybin Emert a President by Michael Barbella Gerrymandering on a partisan basis is not new to politics. The term gerrymander dates back to the 1800s when it was used to mock The debate on how the President Massachusetts Governor Elbridge Gerry, who manipulated congressional of the United States should be elected lines in the state until the map of one district looked like a salamander. is almost as old as the country itself. Redistricting, which is the redrawing of district maps, happens every Contrary to popular belief, voters 10 years after the U.S. Census takes place. Whatever political party is do not elect the president and vice in power at that time has the advantage since, in most states, they president directly; instead, they choose are in charge of drawing the maps. electors to form an Electoral College “Partisan gerrymandering refers to the practice of politicians where the official vote is cast. drawing voting districts for their own political advantage,” During the Constitutional Convention says Eugene D. Mazo, a professor at Rutgers Law School and of 1787, a an expert on election law and the voting process. few ways to Professor Mazo explains that politicians, with the use of advanced computer elect the chief technology, use methods of “packing” and “cracking” to move voters around to executive were different state districts, giving the edge to one political party.
    [Show full text]
  • OPENING PANDORA's BOX David Cameron's Referendum Gamble On
    OPENING PANDORA’S BOX David Cameron’s Referendum Gamble on EU Membership Credit: The Economist. By Christina Hull Yale University Department of Political Science Adviser: Jolyon Howorth April 21, 2014 Abstract This essay examines the driving factors behind UK Prime Minister David Cameron’s decision to call a referendum if the Conservative Party is re-elected in 2015. It addresses the persistence of Euroskepticism in the United Kingdom and the tendency of Euroskeptics to generate intra-party conflict that often has dire consequences for Prime Ministers. Through an analysis of the relative impact of political strategy, the power of the media, and British public opinion, the essay argues that addressing party management and electoral concerns has been the primary influence on David Cameron’s decision and contends that Cameron has unwittingly unleashed a Pandora’s box that could pave the way for a British exit from the European Union. Acknowledgments First, I would like to thank the Bates Summer Research Fellowship, without which I would not have had the opportunity to complete my research in London. To Professor Peter Swenson and the members of The Senior Colloquium, Gabe Botelho, Josh Kalla, Gabe Levine, Mary Shi, and Joel Sircus, who provided excellent advice and criticism. To Professor David Cameron, without whom I never would have discovered my interest in European politics. To David Fayngor, who flew halfway across the world to keep me company during my summer research. To my mom for her unwavering support and my dad for his careful proofreading. And finally, to my adviser Professor Jolyon Howorth, who worked with me on this project for over a year and a half.
    [Show full text]
  • Tennessee Mayors Growing Civic Engagement
    J A N U A R Y 2 0 2 0 tennessee mayors growing civic engagement H O W L O C A L L E A D E R S C A N L E V E R A G E T H E I R O F F I C E T O E N G A G E V O T E R S introduction For over a decade, Tennessee has consistently trailed most other states in voter registration and turnout. Participation in local elections is particularly low: Voter turnout fell below 25 percent in recent elections in our state's four largest cities. As a state with a proud civic history, Tennessee has an important opportunity to examine practices, from election administration to civic engagement, that may offer room for improvement. Systemic reforms, such as policies that modernize and secure election machines and voter- registration databases, are critical, but so too are efforts that better connect voters to their communities and elected representatives. Although state leaders, election officials, community groups and individual residents all have roles to play, city and county mayors are uniquely suited to promote civic engagement at the community level. This report highlights Tennessee Mayors Growing Civic Engagment (TMGCE), a new cohort of city and county mayors who collectively committed to making civic engagement a priority in their communities. Within these pages, readers will learn why mayors are well-placed to lead civic engagement efforts, be able to review specific examples from the participating Tennessee leaders and have access to tools and templates to build a civic-engagement action plan all their own.
    [Show full text]
  • FIGHTING VOTER SUPPRESSION PRESENTED by ELLEN PRICE -MALOY APRIL 26, 2021 VIDEOS to WATCH Stacey Abrams on 3 Ways Votes Are Suppressed – Youtube
    FIGHTING VOTER SUPPRESSION PRESENTED BY ELLEN PRICE -MALOY APRIL 26, 2021 VIDEOS TO WATCH Stacey Abrams on 3 ways votes are suppressed – YouTube Stacey Abrams discussed with Jelani Cobb the three ways that voter suppression occurs in America: registration access restrictions, ballot access restriction... The History of U.S. Voting Rights | Things Explained Who can vote today looked a lot different from those who could vote when the United States was first founded. This video covers the history of voting rights, including women's suffrage, Black disenfranchisement, the Voting Rights Act of 1965, and the various methods American voters can cast their ballots today. For more episodes, specials, and ... 2020 election: What is voter suppression? Tactics used against communities of color throughout history, in Trump-Biden race - ABC7 San Francisco NEW YORK -- As Election Day draws close, some American citizens have experienced barriers to voting, particularly in communities of color. While stories about voter suppression across the nation ... SUPPORT DEMOCRACY H.R.1/S.1 The legislation contains several provisions to fight voter suppression, including national automatic voter registration, prohibitions on voter roll purging and federal partisan gerrymandering, and improved election security measures. It also strengthens ethics providing a strong enforcement of Congress’ Ethics Code – leading to prosecution of those who break the Ethics code and standards and for all three branches of government, e.g. by requiring presidential candidates to disclose 10 years of tax returns and prohibiting members of Congress from using taxpayer dollars to settle sexual harassment cases. The bill aims to curb corporate influence in politics by forcing Super PACs to disclose their donors, requiring government contractors to disclose political spending, and prohibiting coordination between candidates and Super PACs, among other reforms.
    [Show full text]
  • In the United States Court of Appeals for the Eighth Circuit
    No. 14-1382 In the United States Court of Appeals for the Eighth Circuit TRINITY LUTHERAN CHURCH OF COLUMBIA, INC., Plaintiff–Appellant, v. SARA PARKER PAULEY, in her official capacity as Director of the Missouri Department of Natural Resources Solid Waste Management Program, Defendant–Appellant. On Appeal from the United States District Court for the Western District of Missouri Civil Case No. 2:13-CV-04022-NKL – Judge Nanette K. Laughrey Brief Amicus Curiae of the Becket Fund for Religious Liberty in Support of Appellant Eric S. Baxter Asma T. Uddin Diana M. Verm The Becket Fund for Religious Liberty 3000 K St. NW, Suite 220 Washington, DC 20007 (202) 349-7221 [email protected] Attorneys for Amicus Curiae RULE 26.1 DISCLOSURE STATEMENT The Becket Fund for Religious Liberty has no parent corporations and issues no shares of stock. s/ Eric S. Baxter Eric S. Baxter The Becket Fund for Religious Liberty 3000 K Street, NW, Ste. 220 Washington, DC 20036 (202) 349-7221 [email protected] i TABLE OF CONTENTS RULE 26.1 DISCLOSURE STATEMENT ............................................ i TABLE OF AUTHORITIES ................................................................ iv INTEREST OF AMICUS CURIAE ...................................................... 1 INTRODUCTION ................................................................................. 3 ARGUMENT ......................................................................................... 5 I. The State’s interpretation of its “no aid” provisions raises federal constitutional
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral Systems Used Around the World
    Chapter 4 Electoral Systems Used around the World Siamak F. Shahandashti Newcastle University, UK CONTENTS 4.1 Introduction ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 78 4.2 Some Solutions to Electing a Single Winner :::::::::::::::::::::::: 79 4.3 Some Solutions to Electing Multiple Winners ::::::::::::::::::::::: 82 4.4 Blending Systems Together :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 87 4.5 Other Solutions :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 88 4.6 Which Systems Are Good? ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 90 4.6.1 A Theorist’s Point of View ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 90 4.6.1.1 Majority Rules ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 90 4.6.1.2 Bad News Begins :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 91 4.6.1.3 Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem ::::::::::::::::: 93 4.6.1.4 Gibbard–Satterthwaite Impossibility Theorem ::: 94 4.6.1.5 Systems with Respect to Criteria :::::::::::::::: 95 4.6.2 A Practitioner’s Point of View ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 97 Acknowledgment ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 101 77 78 Real-World Electronic Voting: Design, Analysis and Deployment 4.1 Introduction An electoral system, or simply a voting method, defines the rules by which the choices or preferences of voters are collected, tallied, aggregated and collectively interpreted to obtain the results of an election [249, 489]. There are many electoral systems. A voter may be allowed to vote for one or multiple candidates, one or multiple predefined lists of candidates, or state their pref- erence among candidates or predefined lists of candidates. Accordingly, tallying may involve a simple count of the number of votes for each candidate or list, or a relatively more complex procedure of multiple rounds of counting and transferring ballots be- tween candidates or lists. Eventually, the outcome of the tallying and aggregation procedures is interpreted to determine which candidate wins which seat. Designing end-to-end verifiable e-voting schemes is challenging.
    [Show full text]
  • Justice Sandra Day O'connor: the World's Most Powerful Jurist?
    JUSTICE SANDRA DAY O'CONNOR: THE WORLD'S MOST POWERFUL JURIST? DIANE LOWENTHAL AND BARBARA PALMER* I. INTRODUCTION Justice Sandra Day O'Connor has been called a "major force on [the] Supreme Court,"' the "real" Chief Justice, 2 and "America's most powerful jurist."' 3 Others have referred to her as "the most 5 powerful woman in America" 4 and even of "the world.", Even compared to women like Eleanor Roosevelt and Hillary Clinton, there is no one "who has had a more profound effect on society than any other American woman... If someone else had been appointed to her position on the court, our nation might now be living under different rules for abortion, affirmative action, race, religion in school and civil rights. We might well have a different president." 6 Former Acting Solicitor General Walter Dellinger noted, "What is most striking is the assurance with which this formerly obscure state court judge effectively decides many hugely important questions for a country of 275 million people.",7 As one journalist put it, "We are all living in * Diane Lowenthal, Ph.D. in Social and Decision Sciences, Carnegie Mellon University and Barbara Palmer, Ph.D. in Political Science, University of Minnesota, are assistant professors in American University's Washington Semester Program. The authors would like to thank their undergraduate research assistants, Amy Bauman, Nick Chapman-Hushek, and Amanda White. This paper was presented at October 28, 2004 Town Hall The Sway of the Swing Vote: Justice Sandra Day O'Connor and Her Influence on Issues of Race, Religion, Gender and Class sponsored by the University of Maryland Law Journal of Race, Religion, Gender and Class and the Women, Leadership and Equality Program.
    [Show full text]
  • Partisan Gerrymandering and the Construction of American Democracy
    0/-*/&4637&: *ODPMMBCPSBUJPOXJUI6OHMVFJU XFIBWFTFUVQBTVSWFZ POMZUFORVFTUJPOT UP MFBSONPSFBCPVUIPXPQFOBDDFTTFCPPLTBSFEJTDPWFSFEBOEVTFE 8FSFBMMZWBMVFZPVSQBSUJDJQBUJPOQMFBTFUBLFQBSU $-*$,)&3& "OFMFDUSPOJDWFSTJPOPGUIJTCPPLJTGSFFMZBWBJMBCMF UIBOLTUP UIFTVQQPSUPGMJCSBSJFTXPSLJOHXJUI,OPXMFEHF6OMBUDIFE ,6JTBDPMMBCPSBUJWFJOJUJBUJWFEFTJHOFEUPNBLFIJHIRVBMJUZ CPPLT0QFO"DDFTTGPSUIFQVCMJDHPPE Partisan Gerrymandering and the Construction of American Democracy In Partisan Gerrymandering and the Construction of American Democracy, Erik J. Engstrom offers an important, historically grounded perspective on the stakes of congressional redistricting by evaluating the impact of gerrymandering on elections and on party control of the U.S. national government from 1789 through the reapportionment revolution of the 1960s. In this era before the courts supervised redistricting, state parties enjoyed wide discretion with regard to the timing and structure of their districting choices. Although Congress occasionally added language to federal- apportionment acts requiring equally populous districts, there is little evidence this legislation was enforced. Essentially, states could redistrict largely whenever and however they wanted, and so, not surpris- ingly, political considerations dominated the process. Engstrom employs the abundant cross- sectional and temporal varia- tion in redistricting plans and their electoral results from all the states— throughout U.S. history— in order to investigate the causes and con- sequences of partisan redistricting. His analysis
    [Show full text]
  • Successful Citizens' Initiatives
    Successful Citizens’ Initiatives A Guide to Winning Local Land-Use Ballot Measure Campaigns 2002 Edition 631 Howard St., Ste. 510, San Francisco, CA 94105 www.greenbelt.org Table of Contents Executive Summary………………………………………………………………4 Introduction ..................................................................................................... 7 Getting Started Deciding to Pursue a Ballot Strategy ....................................................... 7 First Steps................................................................................................. 9 Establishing Timelines ............................................................................. 9 Community Outreach & Building the Leadership Group ...................... 11 Steering Committee................................................................... 11 Coalition.................................................................................... 12 Campaign Structure................................................................................ 12 Campaign Manager ................................................................... 12 Treasurer ................................................................................... 12 Fundraising Chair...................................................................... 13 Outreach Coordinator................................................................ 13 Spokesperson............................................................................. 13 Other Roles...............................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Constitutional Intolerance to Religious Gerrymandering.Pdf
    Constitutional Intolerance to Religious Gerrymandering Jonathan J. Kim and Eugene Temchenko Can the government pass a law criminalizing consumption of alcohol everywhere except at bars, hotels, clubs, restaurants and private homes? In practice, the law would ban sacramental consumption of alcohol. Yet surprisingly, in many circuits this law would not offend the First Amendment. There is a four-way circuit split on how to treat explicit and implicit secular exemptions under Employment Division v. Smith and Church of the Lukumi Babalu Aye, Inc. v. Hialeah. Some circuits disregard all exemptions so long as there is no evidence of discriminatory intent. Other circuits apply strict scrutiny to every law that contains a single secular exemption. But application of strict scrutiny in free exercise context rarely results in a victory for the religious group. A series of cases significantly watered down strict scrutiny in the free exercise clause context, leaving religious individuals without a constitutional right to free exercise of religion. The purpose of this Article is to address these two related issues: first, when do exemptions warrant scrutiny; and second, when do laws fail scrutiny? The Article argues that a law warrants scrutiny when it exempts secular conduct that undermines the objective of the law to the same extent as a religious exemption would. A law fails scrutiny, in turn, when the compelling government interest and the harm to third-parties does not outweigh the harm the law causes to a religious individual. The right to Free Exercise deserves greater protection. It is a right by which people express a core part of their identities.
    [Show full text]
  • Labour's Next Majority Means Winning Over Conservative Voters but They Are Not Likely to Be the Dominant Source of The
    LABOUR’S NEXT MAJORITY THE 40% STRATEGY Marcus Roberts LABOUR’S The 40% There will be voters who go to the polls on 6th May 2015 who weren’t alive strategy when Tony and Cherie Blair posed outside 10 Downing Street on 1st May NEXT 1997. They will have no memory of an event which is a moment of history as distant from them as Margaret Thatcher’s 1979 election victory was for the voters of 1997. If Ed Miliband seeks to emulate what Blair did in 1997, he too must build his own political majority for the era in which he seeks to govern. MAJORITY This report sets out a plausible strategy for Labour’s next majority, one that is secured through winning 40 per cent of the popular vote in May 2015, despite the challenges of a fragmenting electorate. It also challenges the Marcus Roberts party at all levels to recognise that the 40 per cent strategy for a clear majority in 2015 will require a different winning formula to that which served New Labour so well a generation ago, but which is past its sell-by date in a different political and economic era. A FABIAN REPORT ISBN 978 0 7163 7004 8 ABOUT THE FABIAN SOCIETY The Fabian Society is Britain’s oldest political think tank. Since 1884 the society has played a central role in developing political ideas and public policy on the left. It aims to promote greater equality of wealth, power and opportunity; the value of collective public action; a vibrant, tolerant and accountable democracy; citizenship, liberty and human rights; sustainable development; and multilateral international cooperation.
    [Show full text]