Power, Control and Resistance Within Worker Co-Operatives: an Ethnography of a Co-Operative Factory

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Power, Control and Resistance Within Worker Co-Operatives: an Ethnography of a Co-Operative Factory UNIVERSITE PARIS-DAUPHINE Dauphine Recherches en Management, DRM (UMR CNRS 7088) ECOLE DOCTORALE DE DAUPHINE Power, control and resistance within worker co-operatives: An ethnography of a co-operative factory Thèse pour l’obtention du titre de docteur en sciences de gestion Présentée et soutenue publiquement le 24 novembre 2015 par Stéphane Jaumier Jury : Mme Isabelle HUAULT, Professeure à l’Université Paris-Dauphine (Directrice de thèse) Mme Eve CHIAPELLO, Directrice d’études à l’E.H.E.S.S. (Rapporteur) Mr. Pierre-Yves GOMEZ, Professeur à l’EM-Lyon (Rapporteur) Mr. Nicolas BERLAND, Professeur à l’Université Paris-Dauphine (Suffragant) Mme Robyn THOMAS, Professeure à l’Université de Cardiff (Suffragant) Mr. Thibault DAUDIGEOS, Professeur Associé à GEM (Suffragant) 2 L’université n’entend donner aucune approbation ni improbation aux opinions émises dans cette thèse : ces opinions doivent être considérées comme propres à leur auteur. 3 4 ARTICLE 1 5 6 Stéphane Jaumier Grenoble Ecole de Management & Université Paris-Dauphine PSL, France Thibault Daudigeos Grenoble Ecole de Management, France Vassili Joannidès Grenoble Ecole de Management, France & Queensland University of Technology, Australia Co-operatives, compromises and critiques: What do French co-operators tell us about individual responses to pluralism? Abstract: The purpose of our paper is to contribute to the further understanding of how individuals deal with pluralism by studying the various instantiations they construct based on a shared set of diverse principles. Drawing on theoretical insights from the sociology of conventions, we look at the various modes of justification publicly advanced by French co- operators when substantiating their positions towards co-operative principles. Our analysis allows us to identify three main instantiations of co-operation: pragmatic, reformist and political. Our contribution to the understanding of pluralism and its instantiations by organizational members is threefold. First, and in contrast with studies drawing on an institutional logics perspective, our study shows that individual instantiations of pluralism do not rely on positive affirmations of logics only but also rest on critical mobilizations of competing logics. Second, our study shows that pluralism can be understood not only as having multiple logics, but also along different possible instantiations of the same logic, the ambiguity of which allows compromises to be settled with other logics. Third, drawing on the concept of instantiation, we suggest that organizational members’ responses to pluralism often involve more than two logics, which are combined into a complex set of interdependent positions. In addition, in relation to co-operatives studies, our proposed typology provides a mapping that usefully delineates the range of possibilities found in co-operators’ interpretations of co-operative principles, thus furthering our understanding of the diversity of the co-operative movement together with that of the links between co-operative principles. Keywords: Pluralism, sociology of conventions, compromise, critique, worker co-operatives 7 8 ‘What is wealth, what is worth? We speak about added value but without dealing with the question of wealth as such. And what is wealth today? To what do we grant wealth?’ Co-operative bank representative Introduction Pluralism may sound as if it is evidence for organizational members, most organizations being depicted as increasingly exposed to multiple, often conflicting, principles of evaluation (Kraatz and Block, 2008; Stark, 2009). This is true for private corporations, whose primary objective of profit has been challenged by demands for corporate social responsibility, as measured by triple bottom-line approaches (Gray, 2002). This is true as well for public administrations, whose traditionally dominant concern for citizens’ welfare has been challenged by the introduction of New Public Management, together with its concerns for efficiency and methods borrowed from the private sector (Diefenbach, 2009; Sinclair, 1995). However, this observation has only recently permeated new institutionalism (Greenwood et al., 2011; Pache and Santos, 2010). Indeed, although neo-institutionalist scholars have shown a growing interest in the question of pluralism, i.e. the possibility that distinct evaluative principles coexist, limited understanding of the way organizational members respond to such pluralism has actually been gained to date (Greenwood et al., 2011; Pache and Santos, 2010). The main reason for this paradoxical outcome is that, while acknowledging the presence of multiple evaluative principles at the societal level (Cloutier and Langley, 2013; Rojas, 2010), most research stances have tended, for a long time, to consider the field an intermediate level that operates as a filter between society and organizations/individuals, thus leaving the latter quite untouched by the question of pluralism. The institutional logics perspective provides the most salient example of such an approach (Thornton et al., 2012). Indeed, it primarily situates the stakes of pluralism at the interplay between society, which in its Western forms includes a plurality of value spheres or so-called ‘institutional orders’ (Friedland and Alford, 1991), and a given field, in which a single dominant institutional logic is usually said to govern (Thornton and Ocasio, 1999). When two logics concomitantly populate a field, it is then conceived of as a transitory period of conflict, the formerly dominant logic being progressively displaced by a newly dominant one, for 9 instance as reported in the editing industry, with the shift from a professional to a market logic (Thornton and Ocasio, 1999), and in French cuisine, with Nouvelle Cuisine taking over from Cuisine Traditionnelle (Rao et al., 2003). And when, by accident, two logics come to coexist over a long period of time, geographic segregation contributes then to letting organizations and individuals be unaffected by pluralism (Lounsbury, 2007). Within the institutional logics perspective, a growing number of studies, though, have come to progressively challenge this prevalent consensus by showing that: (1) two logics were sometimes able to inhabit a field over long periods of time (Reay and Hinings, 2009), for example the care and scientific logics in medical education (Dunn and Jones, 2010), and the aesthetic and efficiency ones in architecture (Thornton et al., 2005); (2) a field could be populated by more than two logics at the same time (Greenwood et al., 2010), thus prompting the reference to constellations (Goodrick and Reay, 2011) or pools of these – Goodrick and Reay (2011), for instance, notice within the field of pharmacy a concomitant influence of professional, corporate, market and state logics –; and (3) modes of interaction between field logics other than conflict and competition were also possible, featuring complementarity and mutual support as a possible outcome of field pluralism (Greenwood et al., 2010). These findings have had strong implications for organizations and organizational members, which, under these circumstances, no longer appeared shielded from the effects of pluralism, thus paving the way for studying the kinds of responses they articulate when confronting it (Almandoz, 2014; Besharov and Smith, 2014; Greenwood et al., 2011; Pache and Santos, 2010). The nascent literature on individual instantiations of pluralism that resulted from this move has so far offered contrasted results, endowing organizational members with more or less agency to leverage institutional logics strategically or to actualize logics on the ground (Bullinger et al., 2015; McPherson and Sauder, 2013; Pache and Santos, 2013a; Smets et al., 2015). As a consequence, it is still unclear how individuals practically deal with pluralism. With the aim of further unleashing the avenue opened by these recent contributions, we choose to turn to a different theoretical stance, which, because of its extended conception of pluralism, may bring promising insights in our understanding of this phenomenon. The sociology of conventions has developed a vision of pluralism based on the empirical observation of the argumentative resources that actors mobilize when they engage in public justifications (Boltanski and Thévenot, 1999, 2006). In such situations, actors actually rely, when articulating their claims, on a limited number of so-called ‘orders of worth’, each 10 featuring a singular definition of the common good. All orders of worth being simultaneously available to actors, pluralism is no longer conceived of as a transitional issue to be eventually solved but rather as inherent to any social situation (Cloutier and Langley, 2013; Daudigeos and Valiorgue, 2010). It is because actors are equipped with critical capacities that they are able to deal with the social inherence of pluralism and the ever-present ambiguity this entails. They do this by deciding on the order of worth that should prevail in a given situation, articulating critiques and justifications accordingly and, when needed, settling compromises (Boltanski and Thévenot, 1999, 2006). We here contend that such premises offer a strong avenue for furthering our understanding of how individuals construct situated instantiations of pluralism. More specifically, drawing on the premises of the sociology of conventions, we will pay attention to the role of critiques and compromises in these instantiations. Although pluralism can in this sense be understood as a
Recommended publications
  • Parliamentary Debates (Hansard)
    Thursday Volume 513 15 July 2010 No. 33 HOUSE OF COMMONS OFFICIAL REPORT PARLIAMENTARY DEBATES (HANSARD) Thursday 15 July 2010 £5·00 © Parliamentary Copyright House of Commons 2010 This publication may be reproduced under the terms of the Parliamentary Click-Use Licence, available online through the Office of Public Sector Information website at www.opsi.gov.uk/click-use/ Enquiries to the Office of Public Sector Information, Kew, Richmond, Surrey TW9 4DU; e-mail: [email protected] 1069 15 JULY 2010 1070 what can be done to speed up transactions. I know that House of Commons my right hon. Friend the Minister for Housing is looking at ways to speed up the introduction of e-conveyancing. Thursday 15 July 2010 Dr Alan Whitehead (Southampton, Test) (Lab): Why has the Secretary of State decided, alongside the abolition The House met at half-past Ten o’clock of HIPs, that energy performance certificates should no longer be required at the point when a house is initially viewed for purchase? Does he intend to downgrade the PRAYERS importance of those as well? [MR SPEAKER in the Chair] Mr Pickles: Gracious, no—indeed, under our green deal, energy certificates will perform a much more important role. They will be about bringing the price of energy down and ensuring that somebody with a house Oral Answers to Questions that has a good energy certificate does well, because we want to get houses on to the market. We will insist that the energy certificate be commissioned and in place before the sale takes place. It is about speeding things COMMUNITIES AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT up—the hon.
    [Show full text]
  • Activity 6 [COOPERATIVES in the SCHOOLS]
    Day 1 – Activity 6 [COOPERATIVES IN THE SCHOOLS] Activity 6 - Cooperative Facts Time: 20 minutes Objective: Students will learn some basic history and facts about cooperatives. Step 1: Instruct students to take out their handouts called “Cooperative Fact Sheets.” Give them 3-5 minutes to read them silently to themselves. Step 2: Tell students that they will play, “Find the Fact”. Have each material handler come up and get a white board for each cooperative. If the teacher does not have white boards, then have the reporter take out a notebook and a marker. Tell students that each group will get 30 seconds to find the answer to a fact question and write it on their whiteboard or notebook. At the end of the 30 seconds, each team will hold up their answers and accumulate points for each correct fact found. Team will use their “Cooperative Fact Sheet” to help them with this game. Step 3: Give an example so that students understand the game. “Who is the founding father that organized the first successful US cooperative in 1752?” After 30 seconds, call time and have students hold up their answers. For the teams who wrote, “Benjamin Franklin” say, these teams would have gotten one point. Write the team names on the board to keep track of points. Step 4: When teams understand the rules, begin the game. Below are sample questions/answers: 1. What year was the first cooperative in Wisconsin formed? A: 1841 2. What is the word that means, “The money left over after you pay all your expenses?” A: profit 3.
    [Show full text]
  • Mapping: Key Figures National Report: United Kingdom Ica-Eu Partnership
    MAPPING: KEY FIGURES NATIONAL REPORT: UNITED KINGDOM ICA-EU PARTNERSHIP TABLE OF CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION AND CONTEXT ........................................................................... 2 i. Historical background ........................................................................................... 2 ii. Public national statistics ....................................................................................... 4 iii. Research methodology......................................................................................... 5 II. KEY FIGURES ......................................................................................................... 6 iv. ICA member data ................................................................................................. 7 v. General overview .................................................................................................. 7 vi. Sector overview .................................................................................................... 8 III. GRAPHS................................................................................................................. 11 vii. Number of cooperatives by type of cooperative: ............................................... 11 viii. Number of memberships by type of cooperative: .............................................. 12 ix. Number of employees by type of cooperative: .................................................. 13 x. Turnover by type of cooperative in EUR: ..........................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Principles and Practices in the 21St Century
    A1457 Cooperatives: Principles and practices in the 21st century Kimberly A. Zeuli and Robert Cropp ABOUT THE COVER IMAGE: The “twin pines” is a familiar symbol for cooperatives in the United States.The Cooperative League of the USA, which eventually became the National Cooperative Business Association (NCBA), adopted it as their logo in 1922.The pine tree is an ancient symbol of endurance and immor- tality.The two pines represent mutual cooperation—people helping people. C OOPERATIVES: q Publication notes ii C ont Chapter 1 1 An introduction to cooperatives Chapter 2 5 ents Historical development of cooperatives throughout the world Chapter 3 15 Cooperative history, trends, and laws in the United States Chapter 4 27 Cooperative classification Chapter 5 39 Alternative business models in the United States Chapter 6 49 Cooperative roles, responsibilities, and communication Chapter 7 59 Cooperative financial management Chapter 8 69 Procedures for organizing a cooperative Chapter 9 77 A summary of cooperative benefits and limitations Notes 81 Glossary 85 Cooperative resources 89 PRINCIPLES & PRACTICES IN THE 21ST CENTURY i Kimberly Zeuli and Robert Cropp, Assistant Publication notes Professor and Professor Emeritus in the This publication is the fourth and most extensive Department of Agricultural and Applied revision of the Marvin A. Schaars’ text, Cooperatives, Economics, University of Wisconsin—Madison, Principles and Practices, University of Wisconsin are responsible for all of the editing and most Extension—Madison, Publication A1457, July 1980. of the revised text. The following individuals What has come to be known simply as “the also contributed to various chapters: Schaars book,” was originally written in 1936 by David Erickson, Director of Member Relations, Chris L.
    [Show full text]
  • Cooperative Banks: International Evidence Part of Nef's Stakeholder
    Cooperative banks: International evidence Part of nef’s Stakeholder Banks series nef is an independent think-and-do tank that inspires and demonstrates real economic well-being. We aim to improve quality of life by promoting innovative solutions that challenge mainstream thinking on economic, environmental and social issues. We work in partnership and put people and the planet first. nef (the new economics foundation) is a registered charity founded in 1986 by the leaders of The Other Economic Summit (TOES), which forced issues such as international debt onto the agenda of the G8 summit meetings. It has taken a lead in helping establish new coalitions and organisations such as the Jubilee 2000 debt campaign; the Ethical Trading Initiative; the UK Social Investment Forum; and new ways to measure social and economic well-being. Contents Executive Summary 2 1. What are Cooperative Banks? 4 2. The case for Cooperative Banks 7 2.1 The impact of cooperative ownership 7 2.2 A greater focus on high-street banking and branch services 8 2.3 Inclusive banking for SMEs and individuals 9 2.4 Long-term thinking and stable profits 11 2.5 Stability in a crisis: consistent lending and prudent management 12 3. What criticisms are typically made of the sector? 15 3.1 Cooperatives cannot quickly raise large amounts of capital 15 3.2 They are not as democratic as they claim to be 15 3.3 They act like commercial banks, but less successfully 16 3.4 They struggle to remove ineffective or opportunistic managers 17 3.5 Cooperatives are inefficient 17 4.
    [Show full text]
  • CRD 101: Principles and Practice of Co-Operation Is a First Semester Year One, Two Credit Diploma Core Course of Any Student of Entrepreneurship
    COURSE GUIDE CRD 101 PRINCIPLES AND PRACTICE OF CO-OPERATION Course Team: Dr Emejulu Gerald A. Department of Cooperative Economics and Management, Nnamdi Azikiwe University Awka, Anambra state Taiwo Olabisi Abdulahi Department of Cooperative Economics and Management, Nnamdi Azikiwe University Awka, Anambra State Dr. Tessy Anigbogu (Course Editor) – Department of Cooperative Economics and Management, Nnamdi Azikiwe University Awka, Anambra State Lawal, Kamaldeen A. A. Ph.D – (HoD) Faculty of Management Science, Department of Entrepreneurship – NOUN Dr. Ishola, Timothy O. (Dean) Faculty of Management Science – NOUN NATIONAL OPEN UNIVERSITY OF NIGERIA CRD 101 PRINCIPLES AND PRACTICE OF COOPERATION National Open University of Nigeria Headquarters University Village Plot 91 Cadastral Zone Nnamdi Azikiwe Expressway Jabi, Abuja. Lagos Office 14/16 Ahmadu Bello Way Victoria Island, Lagos e-mail: [email protected] URL: www.noun.edu.ng Published by: National Open University of Nigeria ISBN: Printed: 2017 All Rights Reserved ii CRD 101 MODULES CONTENTS PAGE Introduction……………………………………….…. iv Course Aims……………………………………….… iv Course Objectives………………………………….... iv What you will Learn in this Course………………..... iv Working through this Course…………………….….. iv Course Materials………………………………….…. v Study Units……………………………………….….. v Textbooks and References……………………….….. v Assessment………………………………………..….. vi Tutor-Marked Assignment………………………..….. vi Final Examination and Grading…………………..….. vii Course Overview/Presentation…………………….… vii How to Get the Most from this Course…………….… viii Facilitators, Tutors and Tutorials………………….…. ix Summary……………………………………………… x iii CRD 101 PRINCIPLES AND PRACTICE OF COOPERATION INTRODUCTION CRD 101: Principles and practice of co-operation is a first semester year one, two credit diploma core course of any student of entrepreneurship. The course introduces you to some basic concepts that will help you to understand the course.
    [Show full text]
  • People-Centred Businesses Also by Johnston Birchall
    People-Centred Businesses Also by Johnston Birchall BUILDING COMMUNITIES, THE CO-OPERATIVE WAY CO-OP: The People’s Business CO-OPERATIVES AND THE MILLENNIUM DEVELOPMENT GOALS DECENTRALISING PUBLIC SERVICE MANAGEMENT (with C Pollitt) REDISCOVERING THE COOPERATIVE ADVANTAGE: Poverty Reduction Through Self-help THE INTERNATIONAL CO-OPERATIVE MOVEMENT Also edited by Johnston Birchall HOUSING POLICY IN THE 1990s THE NEW MUTUALISM IN PUBLIC POLICY People-Centred Businesses Co-operatives, Mutuals and the Idea of Membership Johnston Birchall Professor of Social Policy, Stirling University © Johnston Birchall 2011 All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of this publication may be made without written permission. No portion of this publication may be reproduced, copied or transmitted save with written permission or in accordance with the provisions of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under the terms of any licence permitting limited copying issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency, Saffron House, 6–10 Kirby Street, London EC1N 8TS. Any person who does any unauthorized act in relation to this publication may be liable to criminal prosecution and civil claims for damages. The author has asserted his right to be identified as the author of this work in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. First published 2011 by PALGRAVE MACMILLAN Palgrave Macmillan in the UK is an imprint of Macmillan Publishers Limited, registered in England, company number 785998, of Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS. Palgrave Macmillan in the US is a division of St Martin’s Press LLC, 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, NY 10010. Palgrave Macmillan is the global academic imprint of the above companies and has companies and representatives throughout the world.
    [Show full text]
  • 07 Chapter 2.Pdf
    CHAPTER II PRINCIPLES OF CONSUMERS1 COOPERATIVE MOVEMENT 2.1 Historical Background 2.2 Rochdale Pioneers 1#44 2.3 The Rochdale Principles 1&44 2.4 Committee of International Cooperative Alliance 1937 2.5 I.C.A. Commission on Cooperative Principles 1966 CHAPTER II Pr i n c i p l e s of c o n s u m e r s * cooperative MOVEMENT The term 'consumers' cooperation' is an economic concept. It is one of the important activities which has occupied significant place in every sphere of economic life in different countries. The wor cooperative movement started in England through consumers' cooperation and later on it spread all over the world. 2-1 Plgtprical BaskgKPunti The Industrial Revolution in England changed the entire socio-economic life of the people of England. The domestic system of production was replaced by the factory system of production. Rural population started shifting from villages to towns and cities for employment in the coming up industries. To some this change was a boon while to othersit was a great source of insecurity and poverty. The factory system of production created socio-economic problems such as low wages, unemployment, exploitation of the working class and labour disputes, exploitation of child labour. The economists, political thinkers, social reformers all started to apply their minds to find out 15 16 solutions to these problems. The trade union movement could not provide better solution due to the lack of idealism. The cooperative philosophy based on some idealism could provide solutions to form the ideal society. The cooperators had something positive to do, their task was something immediate, practical and something in which every one could share.
    [Show full text]
  • Annual Report 2013
    Cooperative Center FEDERAL CREDIT UNION Annual Report 2013 - 2014 Cooperative Center Federal Credit Union was founded, and continues to be guided by, The Seven Cooperative Economic Principles (Rochdale Principles) Voluntary and Open Membership Cooperative Center FCU is open for membership to all who qualify under our Federal Charter, No. 04900, without discrimination based on gender, sexual orientation, race, ethnicity, religion, or disability. (For a full list, see the About Us page at www.coopfcu.org) Member Economic Participation We encourage our members to make Cooperative Center FCU their primary fnancial institution. When members participate in the cooperative fnancial model, the entire credit union membership, individually and collectively, benefts through competitive loan and share rates and lower fees for services. Democratic Member Control Cooperative Center FCU members participate in the democratic election of a Board of Directors whose function is to create policies and make decisions for the good of the entire membership. Men and women serving as elected Board members are accountable to the membership. Autonomy and Independence Cooperative Center FCU is an autonomous, self-help fnancial institution, controlled by and operated for the beneft of the members, not for outside shareholders. Education, Training and Information Cooperative Center FCU provides education and training for its members, elected and appointed ofcials, management team, and employees. Cooperation Among Cooperatives Cooperative Center FCU supports full cooperation among cooperative fnancial institutions. We serve our members most efectively and strengthen the cooperative movement by working together through local, national, regional, and international structures. Credit unions are more than just fnancial institutions. We are a movement.
    [Show full text]
  • Planning and Community Development: Case Studies
    PLANNING AND COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT: CASE STUDIES UC Berkeley – Technical University of Madrid Copyright © 2012 By Adolfo Cazorla & James Midgley Published by Grupo GESPLAN-UPM ETSI Agrónomos, Ciudad Universitaria s/n, 28040 Madrid (Spain) ISBN: 978-84-616-2381-5 Printed by Graficas Ulzama SL. Editors Migdely, James Cazorla, Adolfo Authors Afonso, Ana Balente , Obeimar Barrantes, Christian Cazorla, Adolfo De Nicolás, Víctor Luis De los Ríos, Ignacio Díaz-Puente, José María Fontana, Alejandro Fernández, María José Fetterman, David Fitzgerald, Charity Samantha Gómez, Francisca Hernández, Daniel Migdely, James Parra, Manuel R. Sastre, Susana Vidueira, Pablo Yagüe, José Luis INDEX FOREWORD ...................................................................................1 James Midgley Harry and Riva Specht Professor, University of California, Berkeley PART I THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK PLANNING THEORY IN POSTMODERNITY ................................. 9 CONCEPTUALIZING GOVERNANCE IN LATIN AMERICA ........ 33 SOCIAL CAPITAL MEASUREMENTS FOR COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT IN RURAL AREAS ............................................ 69 NOT FOR MEMBERS ONLY: COOPERATIVES AND COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT .................................................... 93 PART II CASE STUDIES A PROPOSAL FOR POLICY MANAGEMENT IN INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENT COOPERATION................ 117 FROM BLUE PRINT MODEL TO WORKING WITH PEOPLE (WWP): AYMARAS COMMUNITIES CASE STUDY IN PERÚ ... 153 i EMPOWERMENT EVALUATION CROSS-CULTURALLY: GUIDING THEORIES, PRINCIPLES, AND CONCEPTS IN SPAIN AND
    [Show full text]
  • A Nation Divided
    A Nation Divided: Building a United Kingdom A NATION DIVIDED BUILDING A UNITED KINGDOM A NATION Set in the context of the underlying divisions behind Britain’s decision to leave the European Union, A Nation Divided: Building a United Kingdom explores the extent DIVIDED to which the UK is divided along social, economic, cultural, regional and intergenerational lines. Forewords from leading academics and public fi gures BUILDING A UNITED KINGDOM are presented alongside chapters written by a team of eighteen Young Fabian members, each considering the impact of these divisions on community cohesion and Edited by Ria Bernard social integration across the UK. YOUNG FABIANS Published by the Young Fabians £7.00 2018 November Edited by Ria Bernard November 2018 © 2018 Young Fabians Edited by Ria Bernard A Nation Divided: Building a United Kingdom All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, distributed, or transmitted in any form or by any means, including photocopying, recording, or other electronic or mechanical methods, without the prior written permission of the publisher, except in the case of brief quotations embodied in critical reviews and certain other noncommercial uses permitted by copyright law. For permission requests, write to the publisher, addressed “Attention: Permissions Coordinator,” at the address below. Like all publications of the Fabian Society, this report represents not the collective views of the society, but only the views of the individual writers. The responsibility of the society is limited
    [Show full text]
  • History of Cooperatives in the United States: an Overview
    HISTORY OF COOPERATIVES IN THE UNITED STATES: AN OVERVIEW By Lynn Pitman, UW Center for Cooperatives Revised December 2018 Cooperative organizations have been organized 1858) and Charles Fourier (1772-1837), throughout history to meet many different needs, searching for paths to a more harmonious, often in response to economic and social stress. In utopian society, articulated arguments that the United States, cooperative organizations provided a broader rationale for cooperative appeared very early, reflecting both the European organizations. heritage of early settlers and the basic need for cooperative solutions to rural conditions. The more pragmatic William King (1786-1865) EUROPEAN INFLUENCES advocated the development of consumer cooperatives to address working class issues. His self-published magazine, "The Cooperator", The development of U.S. cooperative provided information on cooperative practice as organizations are rooted in the upheavals that well as theory. King emphasized small characterized the Industrial Revolution in England cooperatives that could be started with capital during 1750-1850. During this period many small, supplied by members. He stressed the use of home-based enterprises disappeared, forcing democratic principles of governance, and the workers to move to cities where they faced harsh education of the public about cooperatives. working conditions and low wages. In rural areas, the enclosure movement and changes in land The wave of consumer cooperatives that tenure patterns drove many small farmers off followed were part of a broader vision in which their lands into towns and cities looking for work. social needs could be met through cooperative action. The Rochdale Society of Equitable Building on trade and social guild traditions, Pioneers, considered the prototype for the mutual aid and "friendly society" organizations modern cooperative association, was organized sprang up to address the conditions of the times, in 1844.
    [Show full text]