Fed Falters Yellen’S Wavering
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Real-Time Price Discovery Via Verbal Communication: Method and Application to Fedspeak
Real-time Price Discovery via Verbal Communication: Method and Application to Fedspeak Roberto G´omezCram, and Marco Grotteria October 30, 2020 CEMLA XXV Meeting of the Central Bank Researchers Network Roberto G´omezCram, and Marco Grotteria Real-time Price Discovery via Verbal Communication: Method and Application to Fedspeak 1 Expectations and the Central Bank Previous literature Expectations play an important role for central banks Forward-guidance is a key tool used to shape expectations How do economic agents form expectations? Large macroeconomic literature on information rigidity (e.g., Mankiw and Reis, 2002; Reis, 2006; Coibion and Gorodnichenko, 2015) This paper Provides granular evidence on the agents' expectations formation process. Investors' fail to fully incorporate the Central Banks' messages This failure is economically large. Roberto G´omezCram, and Marco Grotteria Real-time Price Discovery via Verbal Communication: Method and Application to Fedspeak 2 Methodological contribution Identifying individual messages For the days in which the Federal Open Market Committee has a scheduled meeting, 1 we scrape the videos of the Fed Chairman's press conference 2 we split the video into smaller frames of around 3 seconds each 3 we use an end-to-end deep learning algorithm to convert the audio into interpretable text 4 we timestamp each word spoken in each moment 5 we align high-frequency financial data with these exact words =) link between specific messages sent and the signals received Roberto G´omezCram, and Marco Grotteria Real-time Price Discovery via Verbal Communication: Method and Application to Fedspeak 3 FOMC meeting on July 31 2019: Timestamped words Start time End time Text Fed Chairman/News outlet 14:35:36.286 14:35:39.946 Per your statement here, I guess the question is, New York Times . -
Nine Crises Fifty Years of Covering the British Economy from Devaluation to Brexit William Keegan
Nine Crises Fifty Years of Covering the British Economy from Devaluation to Brexit William Keegan London: Biteback Publishing, 2019, £20.00 (h/b) Bartholomew Steer Nine Crises is an attempt to encapsulate the UK’s economic crises of the last 50 years, and the way they were managed by the leading lights of the day, as they were reported in William Keegan’s newspaper columns over the period. Keegan was not to know that as soon as 2019 was out, the biggest economic crisis since WW2 would take place, with some suggesting it is likely to be the biggest for 100 years.1 That said, it lends a certain perspective to the events of the last 50 years and a new twist to the ‘Crisis, what crisis?’ comment (which was falsely attributed to ‘Sunny Jim’ Callaghan, Prime Minister in the late seventies). It turns out that, judged by the events of 2020, all previous crises were mere blips in times of steady economic growth and prosperity for the majority. It appears that far from being the Beast holding the UK back, the state is vital to propping-up not only the banks, as in 2008/9, but the entire shooting match. For all the denial of the role of modern monetary theory (MMT), as described by Stephanie Kelton in her book,2 when push came to shove MMT is the only thing preventing an even bigger crisis. William Keegan will need no introduction to readers of the Observer, where he has been a permanent fixture as a financial journalist commentating on economic affairs through five decades. -
Jerome H Powell: Opening Remarks
For release on delivery 9:55 a.m. EDT (8:55 a.m. CDT) June 4, 2019 Opening Remarks by Jerome H. Powell Chair Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System at “Conference on Monetary Policy Strategy, Tools, and Communications Practices” sponsored by the Federal Reserve Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Chicago, Illinois June 4, 2019 Good morning. I am very pleased to welcome you here today. This conference is part of a first-ever public review by the Federal Open Market Committee of our monetary policy strategy, tools, and communications. We have a distinguished group of experts from academics and other walks of life here to share perspectives on how monetary policy can best serve the public. I’d like first to say a word about recent developments involving trade negotiations and other matters. We do not know how or when these issues will be resolved. We are closely monitoring the implications of these developments for the U.S. economic outlook and, as always, we will act as appropriate to sustain the expansion, with a strong labor market and inflation near our symmetric 2 percent objective. My comments today, like this conference, will focus on longer-run issues that will remain even as the issues of the moment evolve. While central banks face a challenging environment today, those challenges are not entirely new. In fact, in 1999 the Federal Reserve System hosted a conference titled “Monetary Policy in a Low Inflation Environment.” Conference participants discussed new challenges that were emerging after the then-recent victory over the Great Inflation.1 They focused on many questions posed by low inflation and, in particular, on what unconventional tools a central bank might use to support the economy if interest rates fell to what we now call the effective lower bound (ELB). -
Speech Delivered at the Money Marketeers of New York University, New York, October 19
For release on delivery 4:30 p.m. EDT March 28, 2017 America’s Central Bank: The History and Structure of the Federal Reserve Remarks by Jerome H. Powell Member Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System at the West Virginia University College of Business and Economics Distinguished Speaker Series Morgantown, West Virginia March 28, 2017 I am delighted to have this opportunity to speak at West Virginia University. Thanks to Brian Cushing for inviting me here today.1 Gathered in this part of West Virginia, we are located in the Fifth Federal Reserve District, which stretches down from here to South Carolina and east to the Atlantic Ocean (figure 1). More than 100 years ago, the organizers of the Federal Reserve System divided the country into 12 of these Districts, each with its own Federal Reserve Bank. Together, the Board of Governors in Washington and the 12 Reserve Banks are the key elements of the Federal Reserve System. Today I will discuss how the Federal Reserve came to have this unique structure. The Fed’s organization reflects a long-standing desire in American history to ensure that power over our nation’s monetary policy and financial system is not concentrated in a few hands, whether in Washington or in high finance or in any single group or constituency. Rather, Americans have long desired that decisions about these matters be influenced by a diverse set of voices from all parts of the country and the economy. The structure of the Federal Reserve was designed to achieve this broad representation and promote a stronger financial system to build resiliency against the sort of periodic financial crises that had repeatedly damaged the country in the 19th and early 20th centuries. -
Purdah: on the Rationale for Central Bank Silence Around Policy Meetings” by M
WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 868/FEBRUARY2008 PURDAH ON THE RATIONALE FOR CENTRAL BANK SILENCE AROUND POLICY MEETINGS byMichael Ehrmann and Marcel Fratzscher WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 868 / FEBRUARY 2008 PURDAH ON THE RATIONALE FOR CENTRAL BANK SILENCE AROUND POLICY MEETINGS 1 Michael Ehrmann and Marcel Fratzscher 2 In 2008 all ECB publications This paper can be downloaded without charge from feature a motif taken from the http://www.ecb.europa.eu or from the Social Science Research Network 10 banknote. electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=1090543. 1 This paper is forthcoming in the Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. We would like to thank Terhi Jokipii and Björn Kraaz for excellent research assistance, Niels Bünemann for some information about the purdah practices of central banks and Magnus Andersson, Alan Blinder, Alex Cukierman and Bernhard Winkler as well as seminar participants at the ECB for comments. This paper presents the authors’ personal opinions and does not necessarily refl ect the views of the European Central Bank. 2 Both authors: European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany; e-mail: [email protected], [email protected] © European Central Bank, 2008 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Website http://www.ecb.europa.eu Fax +49 69 1344 6000 All rights reserved. Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, whether printed or produced electronically, in whole or in part, is permitted only with the explicit written authorisation of the ECB or the author(s). -
Real-Time Price Discovery Via Verbal Communication: Method and Application to Fedspeak
Real-time Price Discovery via Verbal Communication: Method and Application to Fedspeak Roberto G´omez-Cram Marco Grotteria∗ November 2, 2020 Abstract We advance the hypothesis and establish empirically that investors' expectations adjust slowly to Central Banks' messages. From the videos of post-FOMC-meeting press conferences, we extract the words, and timestamp them at the millisecond. We align the transcripts with high-frequency data for several financial assets to provide granular evidence on the investors' expectations formation process. When the Chairman discusses the changes between current and previous policy statement, price volatility and trading volume spike dramatically, and prices move in the same direction as they did around the statement release. Our approach allows us to quantify in monetary terms the value of information rigidity. ∗We thank Jules van Binsbergen, Anna Cieslak, Jo~aoCocco, Kent Daniel, James Dow, Itamar Drechsler, Francisco Gomes, Jo~aoGomes, Christopher Hennessy, Ralph Koijen, Matteo Leombroni, Emanuel Moench, Michael McMahon, Stefan Nagel, Stephen Schaepher, Jessica Wachter, and Amir Yaron for helpful discussions and/or comments. We thank the AQR Asset Management Institute for generous financial support. Yutong Hu, Oksana Smirnova, and Tianhao Yin provided excellent research assistantship. The authors are both assistant professors of finance at the London Business School, and can be reached at [email protected] and [email protected]. 1 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3613702 1 Introduction When policy analysis ignores the role of expectations, and their evolution, policy conclu- sions are misleading (Lucas, 1972, 1973, 1976). Because of that, central bankers today give high priority to communication with financial markets in an attempt of manag- ing the public's expectations. -
X Marks the Box: How to Make Politics Work for You by Daniel Blythe
Thank you for downloading the free ebook edition of X Marks the Box: How to Make Politics Work for You by Daniel Blythe. This edition is complete and unabridged. Please feel free to pass it on to anyone else you think would be interested. Follow Daniel on his blog at www.xmarksthebox.co.uk. The book is all about debate, of course – so get involved and tell Daniel and the world what you think there! The printed edition of X Marks the Box (ISBN 9781848310513), priced £7.99, is published on Thursday 4 March by Icon Books and will be available in all good bookstores – online and otherwise. And don’t forget to vote! www.xmarksthebox.co.uk I C O N B O O K S Published in the UK in 2010 by Icon Books Ltd, Omnibus Business Centre, 39–41 North Road, London N7 9DP email: [email protected] www.iconbooks.co.uk This electronic edition published in 2010 by Icon Books ISBN: 978-1-84831-180-0 (ePub format) ISBN: 978-1-84831-191-6 (Adobe ebook format) Printed edition (ISBN: 978-1-84831-051-3) sold in the UK, Europe, South Africa and Asia by Faber & Faber Ltd, Bloomsbury House, 74–77 Great Russell Street, London WC1B 3DA or their agents Printed edition distributed in the UK, Europe, South Africa and Asia by TBS Ltd, TBS Distribution Centre, Colchester Road, Frating Green, Colchester CO7 7DW Printed edition published in Australia in 2010 by Allen & Unwin Pty Ltd, PO Box 8500, 83 Alexander Street, Crows Nest, NSW 2065 Printed edition distributed in Canada by Penguin Books Canada, 90 Eglinton Avenue East, Suite 700, Toronto, Ontario M4P 2YE Text copyright © 2010 Daniel Blythe The author has asserted his moral rights. -
The FOMC: Transparency Achieved?
Economic SYNOPSES short essays and reports on the economic issues of the day 2012 ■ Number 9 The FOMC: Transparency Achieved? Richard G. Anderson, Vice President and Economist uring the past two decades, central banks have decisions were announced at the conclusion of each meet- D increasingly adopted inflation targeting because ing if the target federal funds rate had been changed. In theoretical and empirical analyses suggest that its addition, minutes of each meeting were released after the use promises improved economic performance.1 Simul ta - subsequent meeting. Beginning with the July 6, 1995, ne ously, central banks have sought to improve the transpar - meeting, a numerical target for the federal funds rate was ency of their policymaking because macroeconomists argue announced at the end of each meeting. In 2000, the FOMC that the full potential gains of inflation targeting will be began issuing a statement at the end of every meeting realized only when such greater transparency is achieved.2 (regardless of whether the target federal funds rate had The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) formally been changed) accompanied by a “balance of risks” proviso. adopted inflation targeting at its January 24-25, 2012, meet- In 2005, expanded FOMC minutes began to be released ing, setting as its goal a medium-term increase of 2 percent three weeks after each meeting. annually in the chain-price index for personal consump- tion expenditures. With this action, the Federal Reserve (specifically, the FOMC) became the only inflation target- Greater transparency is a means ing central bank among the G-7 countries that does not to better synchronize the public with release in a timely fashion the staff analyses, models, and projections that underlie its policy actions.3 These FOMC policymakers and minimize the risks staff materials, compiled in the Greenbook and the Blue - of undesirable economic outcomes. -
What Does Jerome Powell Know That William Mcchesney Martin Didn’T—And What Role Did Academic Research Play in That?
What does Jerome Powell know that William McChesney Martin didn’t—and what role did academic research play in that? by Alan S. Blinder, Princeton University Griswold Center for Economic Policy Studies Working Paper No. 259, September 2019 Keynote lecture at the Money Macro and Finance Research Group’s 50th Anniversary Conference, London School of Economics, September 4-6, 2019. Forthcoming in The Manchester School. I thank Roger Ferguson, Chris Sims, and Janet Yellen for helpful conversations, but none of them is implicated in the opinions expressed here. It is indeed a pleasure for an old LSE alumnus like me (M.Sc., 1968) to return to help mark the 50th anniversary of the Money Macro and Finance Research Group. I actually have on my bookshelf a copy of Harry Johnson’s 1972 book, Macroeconomics and Monetary Theory (Johnson, 1972), which was based on his lectures at LSE during the 1969-1970 academic year. I presumably heard some of these lectures as a student two years earlier. But fifty years is a long time and memory fails. The world changes in 50 years. In 1969, the New York Jets won the Superbowl of American football and the New York Mets won the World Series of baseball—two huge upsets in the same year! The former has never reoccurred; the latter has been repeated only once. The year 1969 is perhaps most famous for astronaut Neil Armstrong’s walk on the moon—a remarkable feat that was accomplished five more times, but not since 1972. However, some aspects of the world don’t change much in a half-century. -
Understanding the Greenspan Standard by Alan S. Blinder And
Understanding the Greenspan Standard by Alan S. Blinder and Ricardo Reis Princeton University September 12, 2005 Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City symposium, The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the Future, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 25-27, 2005. The authors are grateful for helpful discussions with Donald Kohn, Gregory Mankiw, Allan Meltzer, Christopher Sims, Lars Svensson, John Taylor, and other participants at the Jackson Hole conference—none of whom are implicated in our conclusions. We also thank Princeton’s Center for Economic Policy Studies for financial support. I. Introduction Alan Greenspan was sworn in as Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System almost exactly 18 years ago. At the time, the Reagan administration was being rocked by the Iran-contra scandal. The Berlin Wall was standing tall while, in the Soviet Union, Mikhail Gorbachev had just presented proposals for perestroika. The stock market had not crashed since 1929 and, probably by coincidence, Prozac had just been released on the market. The New York Mets, having won the 1986 World Series, were the reigning champions of major league baseball. A lot can change in 18 years. Turning to the narrower world of monetary policy, central banks in 1987 still doted on money growth rates and spoke in tongues—when indeed they spoke at all, which was not often. Inflation targeting had yet to be invented in New Zealand, and the Taylor rule was not even a gleam in John Taylor’s eye. European monetary union seemed like a far-off dream. And the world-famous Jackson Hole conference was not yet world-famous. -
In January 2000 the Federal Open Market
statement of the bias that the FOMC adopted at one The FOMC’s Balance-of- meeting was not made public until after the next meeting. In May 1999, the FOMC changed its practice Risks Statement and and began announcing the symmetry of its policy directive at the conclusion of each meeting. This Market Expectations of announcement attracted considerable attention. While the FOMC had never offered a formal inter- Policy Actions pretation of the symmetry clause of its policy direc- tive, the market interpreted the bias in one direction Robert H. Rasche and Daniel L. Thornton or another as an indication of the likelihood that the FOMC would change the intended funds rate in 1 n January 2000 the Federal Open Market that direction. This interpretation was reasonable Committee (FOMC) instituted the practice of given that the bias was stated in terms of the need issuing a “balance of risks” statement along with to change the degree of pressure in reserve markets, I i.e., the intended funds rate, during the intermeeting its policy decision at the close of each FOMC meet- ing. The balance-of-risks statement was intended period. Nevertheless, Thornton and Wheelock (2000) to indicate the Committee’s assessment of the bal- found that the bias had essentially no predictive ance of risks for heightened inflation pressures or content for changes in the funds rate target at or economic weakness over the foreseeable future. before the next meeting. Specifically, they found that, In announcing the procedural change, the FOMC while any action taken was nearly always in the explicitly noted that “this time frame in the new direction of the bias at the previous meeting, they language is intended to cover an interval extending could not reject the hypothesis that policy actions beyond the next FOMC meeting,” suggesting that taken were independent of the asymmetric language the balance-of-risks statement should not be inter- adopted at the previous meeting. -
Speech by Vice Chairman Fischer on the Process of Monetary Policy
For release on delivery 6:30 a.m. EST (11:30 a.m. GMT) February 11, 2017 “I’d Rather Have Bob Solow Than an Econometric Model, But . .” Remarks by Stanley Fischer Vice Chairman Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System at the Warwick Economics Summit Coventry, England February 11, 2017 Introduction: Econometric Models and a Eureka Moment. Eureka moments are rare in all fields, not least in economics.1 One such moment came to me when I was an undergraduate at the London School of Economics in the 1960s. I was talking to a friend who was telling me about econometric models. He explained that it would soon be possible to build a mathematical model that would accurately predict the future course of the economy. It was but a step from there to realize that the problems of policymaking would soon be over. All it would take was a bit of algebra to solve for the policies that would produce the desired values of the target variables. It was a wonderful prospect, and it remains a wonderful idea. But it has not yet happened. I want to talk about why not and about some of the consequences for policymaking. How the Fed Makes Monetary Policy Let me begin with how we make monetary policy at the Fed. The Federal Reserve System has both centralized and regional characteristics. The System comprises the Board of Governors, located in Washington, D.C., and 12 regional Reserve Banks in cities across the United States (figure 1). The members of the Board of Governors are appointed by the President, subject to confirmation by the U.S.