Which Was the “Real” Kondratiev: 1925 Or 1928?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Which Was the “Real” Kondratiev: 1925 Or 1928? Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Volume 24, Number 4, 2002 WHICH WAS THE ``REAL’’ KONDRATIEV: 1925 OR 1928? BY VINCENT BARNETT It is to be regretted that Nikolai Kondratiev’s 1928 paper on long cyclesÐ ``The price dynamics of industrial and agricultural commodities: the theory of relative dynamics and conjuncture’’Ð was omitted from the Pickering and Chatto English language edition of his works published in 1998.1 This is one of the two most important papers excluded from this edition, the other being the full text of his plan for agriculture and forestry, 1924± 28.2 In response, this note discusses some modi® cations that occurred in Kondratiev’s explanation of long cycles between 1925 and 1928, and puts to rest the suggestion that these changes might have taken place as the result of political factors rather than a genuine change of mind. I also counter some of my critics who have taken issue with my presentation of Kondratiev’s conception of long cycles (most notably Jan Reijnders (2001) in this journal), and link this with a more general discussion of some of the methodological issues involved. In his introductory essay to the collected works, Andrew Tylecote suggested that Kondratiev might have changed his mind on the explanation question between 1925 and 1928Ð ``retreating to a purely economic dynamic theory’’ to explain long cycles, as Tylecote put it (Tylecote 1998, p. lxxxiii)Ð because it would ``look safer’’ to the Soviet authorities. According to Tylecote, in 1925 Kondratiev oVered a tentative endogenous theory of long cycles which integrated extra-economic circumstances and events into the explanation, namely changes in technique, wars and revolutions, new country assimilation, and changes to gold production. In 1928 Kondratiev ``retreated’’ to explaining the endogeneity of the long cycle simply by over-investment. In one of my introductory essays for the collected works, I agreed with Tylecote that Kondratiev was indeed attempting an endogenous theory of long cycles (Barnett 1998b, p.xlvii), one based on the echo-eVects of large-scale capital investment projects. However, Tylecote’s idea that a ``retreat’’ occurred over the particular type of endogenous explanation being oVered by Kondratiev between 1925 and 1928 and that this CREES, Birmingham University. 1 See Makasheva, Samuels, and Barnett, ed. 2 The fault is not all mine, however, as when I joined the project I suggested revising the existing list of what was to be included, but this suggestion was rejected by Pickering. DownloadedISSN 1042-771 from https://www.cambridge.org/core6 print; ISSN 1469-9656.online University/02 /of040475-0 Athens, on4 27© 200Sep 22021Th ate Histor21:22:26y, subjectof Economic to the Cambridges Society Core termsDOI of use,: 10.1080 available/104277102200002990 at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms4 . https://doi.org/10.1080/1042771022000029904 476 JOURNAL OF THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT could have been due to political factors might appear at ® rst sight to be plausible, but in fact it is unlikely to be true. The idea that in the 1920s Joe Stalin avidly followed rather esoteric debates over the theoretical explanation of business cycles, checking for conformity with ``Marxist’’ concepts of capitalist development, is rather fanciful. As I have argued in my book (Barnett 1998a), Kondratiev was a threat to Stalin because he articulated a market-led industrialization strategy for the USSR and because he was an important policy advisor within the Soviet government, not because of any dispute over endogenous causes of business cycles. It is unlikely that Stalin would even have understood such diVerences. If Kondratiev considered changing any of his views between 1925 and 1928 to placate Stalin, it would have been those on peasant farmsÐ collectivization and industrialization policy. That Kondratiev held to a pro-market stance on policy issues in 1928 is ample evidence that he was not amenable to turning on any theoretical issue, at least under the level of duress that existed in the USSR in the late 1920s. In chapter ® ve of my book, which according to Jan Reijnders gave an ``Aunt Sally’’ account of long cycles, I devoted a lot of space to presenting the main elements of Kondratiev’s 1928 paper on long cycles in their own terms (Barnett 1998a, pp. 121± 27), knowing that this paper was to be excluded from the English- language collected works. Interested readers should compare for themselves this approach to that taken in 1925. In summary, Kondratiev stated that the purpose of the 1928 paper was to uncover the relative dynamics of conjuncture between industrial and agricultural prices, and distinguished between small and long cycles. He detected a reverse movement in the purchasing power of agricultural against industrial goods during most of the nineteenth century, which was explained by a lag in the decline of agricultural costs of production behind industrial. The idea of endogeneity was not explicitly mentioned. If it had been, of course, this would have been extraordinary since the concept was not introduced into Russian economics until sometime later, although this does not mean that I am suggesting that Reijnders and Tylecote are wrong to interpret Kondratiev’s work mainly in these terms. However, if Kondratiev was not forced by political circumstance to modify his position on the explanation question between 1925 and 1928, why might he have done so voluntarily? One possible answer is that the in¯ uence of the work of other economists led him in this direction. Tylecote acknowledged that the criticisms provided from within the USSR by D. I. Oparin might have had such an eVect. In chapter four of my book, which Reijnders referred to as an ``intermezzo,’’ I documented in detail the Western economists with whom Kondratiev made contact with on his trip overseas in 1924± 25 (Barnett 1998a, pp. 87± 104). In response to further exposure to Wesley Mitchell and Irving Fisher, Kondratiev might well have modi® ed his views on the explanation of long cycles, although, as a historian, I make no judgement about whether this change was a step forward or a step backward in terms of economic theory. Tylecote interpreted it as a step backward, and Reijnders might see it as such as well. They should note that whilst in jail in the 1930s, Kondratiev himself provided a list of his most important published works, which included the 1928 paper but excluded the 1925 paper. Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. University of Athens, on 27 Sep 2021 at 21:22:26, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1080/1042771022000029904 WHICH WAS THE ``REAL’’ KONDRATIEV: 1925 OR 1928? 477 Some of these themes ® nd further echoes in Reijnders review of my book in this journal. In his review, Reijnders accused me of making several interpretative mistakes, the most important of these being that I failed to understand how Kondratiev’s theoretical constructs were interrelated. In fact, what I was trying to do was to provide a comprehensive and historically accurate presentation of Kondratiev’s work, keeping faith with the conceptions of the time, which Reijnders may question because it is not fully commensurate with his own interpretation which employs more recently constructed ideas. Note that I am not arguing that my presentation is correct and Reijnders’s view is false, only that several diVerent interpretations are possible depending on the particular approach being adopted, something that Reijnders doesn’t appear to contemplate. For example, Reijnders stated that Kondratiev’s real contribution was that he generalized the idea of an endogenous cyclical mechanism to economic develop- ment in the long run, ``endogenizing’’ the environmental factors. As rational reconstruction of the 1925 paper this might sound plausible, Reijnders himself providing the particular setting for how Kondratiev’s theoretical constructs are to be interrelated, but Kondratiev thought he was doing something not quite the same in the 1928 paper: analyzing branches of the economy and integrating various cycles, as I outline. This is my historical reconstruction, and it is closer to how Joseph Schumpeter interpreted Kondratiev in the 1930s, i.e., a three-cycle schema (Schumpeter 1939, vol.1, p. 169).3 Kondratiev also pointed out that his analysis of long cycles was intended to be used as an aid to economic forecasting, something that Reijnders does not acknowledge. Thus, my presentation of the 1928 paper isn’t fully commensurate with how some later long cycle theorists have interpreted Kondratiev, although the work of W. W. Rostow is perhaps closest to Kondratiev’s approach in 1928. Rostow conceived of the long cycle as a cycle of relative prices. Chris Freeman and Francisco LoucË aÄ have recently presented Kondratiev’s 1928 paper as conceiving of the long cycle as a deviation away from equilibrium relative to a moving equilibrium, or of a reversible movement within an irreversible one (Freeman and LoucË aÄ , 2000, pp. 79± 80). Again this appears enticing as rational reconstruc- tion, but whether it is ``true’’ or not is a moot point for the historian of ideas. Whether Kondratiev’s entire contribution to business cycle theory can ever be accurately and completely represented by a single sentence, no matter how rationally it is (re)constructed, should be held in doubt. My position would be that Aunt Sally should only be rejected if she doesn’t re¯ ect what particular economists were actually doing; in some cases she might be a good (historical) representation. In the same issue of this journal that contained Reijnders review of my book, Paul Samuelson endorsed a rather worrying ``selected highlights’’ conception of the role of history, with which Reijnders (and I fear many other economists) might agree.
Recommended publications
  • The Recurrence of Long Cycles: Theories, Stylized Facts and Figures
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Recurrence of Long Cycles: Theories, Stylized Facts and Figures Tsoulfidis, Lefteris and Papageorgiou, Aris University of Macedonia, University of Macedonia 10 June 2017 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/82853/ MPRA Paper No. 82853, posted 23 Nov 2017 06:39 UTC The Recurrence of Long Cycles: Theories, Stylized Facts and Figures Lefteris Tsoulfidis* and Aris Papageorgiou* Corresponding Author Professor Lefteris Tsoulfidis Department of Economics, University of Macedonia, Thessaloniki Greece Tel.: 30 2310 891788 Email: [email protected] ABSTRACT Basic innovations and their diffusion, the expansion or contraction of the level of economic activity and the volume of international trade, rising sovereign debts and their defaults, conflicts and the outbreak of wars, are some of the major phenomena appearing during the downswing or upswing phases of long cycles. In this article, we examine the extent to which these phenomena constitute stylized facts of the different phases of long cycles which recur quite regularly in the turbulent economic history of capitalism. The main argument of this paper is that the evolution of long cycles is a result of the long-run movement of profitability. During the downswing of a long cycle, falling profitability induces innovation investment and the associated with it 'creative destruction' of the capital stock that eventually set the stage for the upswing phase of a new long cycle. JEL classifications: B14, B24, E11, E32 Key Words: Long Cycles, Innovations, Profit rate * Department of Economics University of Macedonia. Versions of the paper were presented at the 5th Conference of Evolutionary Economics, Volos-Greece May 2017 and the 19th conference of the Greek Historians of Economic Thought, Thessaloniki, Greece June 2017.
    [Show full text]
  • “RUSSIAN ECONOMICS” OR ECONOMICS in RUSSIA: WHAT WAS BUILT on the RUINS of the SOVIET UNION? (First Draft)
    Vsevolod Ostapenko* “RUSSIAN ECONOMICS” OR ECONOMICS IN RUSSIA: WHAT WAS BUILT ON THE RUINS OF THE SOVIET UNION? (first draft) Abstract To be added… JEL: A11, A14, B29 * St. Petersburg State University, Faculty of Economics, associate professor, [email protected] 1. Introduction. Dismantling of the Soviet political system and transition to the market economy in Russia were inevitably accompanied by fundamental changes in spheres of science and education. The long- lasting existence of two key branches in the field of economic thought, namely political economy of capitalism and political economy of socialism, broke off. Russian economists started to rethink their research strategies and paradigms within which they had been operating. This process has not been completed yet. Economics profession in the country remains in the situation of blurring scientific standards and substantial fragmentation of the research area. As it is stated by Joachim Zweynert, sphere of economic science in Russia has evolved into something so heterogenous and manifold that one should even use term “economics” with caution. We will thus exploit different paraphrases like “Russian economic thought”. The initial problem arising is whether it’s reasonable to describe economics in national context. Of course, the history of economic thought is rich in examples of using national signs in defining various scientific schools: for example, British political economy or German historical school. More often the title of the school contains also the name of the university (research center), which gave work to its most prominent representatives (like Chicago or Stockholm schools). In 2015 a great volume on national and geographical features of economic science was published under the editorship of Vincent Barnett (Barnett, 2015).
    [Show full text]
  • Issn 2318-2377
    ISSN 2318-2377 TEXTO PARA DISCUSSÃO N 610 UNEVEN AND COMBINED DEVELOPMENT AS A METHODOLOGICAL TOOL: a dynamic approach after a dialogue between Kondratiev and Trotsky Eduardo da Motta e Albuquerque Setembro de 2019 Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais Textos para Discussão Jaime Arturo Ramírez (Reitor) A série de Textos para Discussão divulga resultados Sandra Regina Goulart Almeida (Vice-reitora) preliminares de estudos desenvolvidos no âmbito Faculdade de Ciências Econômicas do Cedeplar, com o objetivo de compartilhar ideias e obter comentários e críticas da comunidade Hugo Eduardo Araujo da Gama Cerqueira (Diretor) científica antes de seu envio para publicação final. Kely César Martins de Paiva (Vice-Diretora) Os Textos para Discussão do Cedeplar começaram a ser publicados em 1974 e têm se destacado pela Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento diversidade de temas e áreas de pesquisa. Regional (Cedeplar) Ficha catalográfica Frederico Gonzaga Jayme Jr (Diretor) A345u Albuquerque, Eduardo da Motta e. Gustavo de Britto Rocha (Vice-Diretor) 2019 Uneven and combined development as a methodological tool: a dynamic approach after Laura Rodríguez Wong (Coordenadora do a dialogue between Kondratiev and Trotsky/ Eduardo da Motta e Albuquerque. - Belo Programa de Pós-graduação em Demografia) Horizonte: UFMG / CEDEPLAR, 2019. Gilberto de Assis L.ibânio (Coordenador do 26 p. - (Texto para discussão, 610) Programa de Pós-graduação em Economia) Inclui bibliografia (p. 22 - 26) ISSN 2318-2377 Adriana de Miranda-Ribeiro (Chefe do Departamento de Demografia) 1. Capitalismo. 2. Efeito de inovações tecnológicas. I. Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais. Centro de Desenvolvimento e Bernardo Palhares Campolina Diniz (Chefe do Planejamento Regional. II. Título.
    [Show full text]
  • The Use of Analogies in Economic Modelling: Vladimir Bazarov's
    The use of analogies in economic modelling: Vladimir Bazarov’s restauration process model Authors: Elizaveta Burina, Annie L. Cot Univeristy of Paris 1 – Panthéon-Sorbonne 2018-2019 Table of contents Acknowledgements ......................................................................................................................... 3 Preface ............................................................................................................................................. 4 Section 1. The framework that determined Bazarov’s work ........................................................... 8 1.1. Russian economic science in 1920s ...................................................................................... 8 1.2. Intellectual biography ........................................................................................................... 9 1.2.1. Before the October Revolution of 1917 ......................................................................... 9 1.2.2. After the October Revolution of 1917.......................................................................... 12 1.3. Bazarov’s work in Gosplan ................................................................................................. 15 1.3.1. Early years’ work ......................................................................................................... 15 1.3.2. Money emission theory ................................................................................................ 16 1.3.3. Planification theory .....................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Coversheet for Thesis in Sussex Research Online
    A University of Sussex DPhil thesis Available online via Sussex Research Online: http://sro.sussex.ac.uk/ This thesis is protected by copyright which belongs to the author. This thesis cannot be reproduced or quoted extensively from without first obtaining permission in writing from the Author The content must not be changed in any way or sold commercially in any format or medium without the formal permission of the Author When referring to this work, full bibliographic details including the author, title, awarding institution and date of the thesis must be given Please visit Sussex Research Online for more information and further details Explaining the paradox of market reform in communist China: the uneven and combined development of the Chinese Revolution and the search for ‘national salvation’ Luke Cooper University of Sussex July 2013 Thesis submitted for the fulfilment of the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in International Relations at the University of Sussex. 2 Abstract This thesis addresses the paradox of capitalist market reform being introduced by a politically undefeated communist state in China. It does so by developing an historical account of the Chinese polity’s relationship with the modern world. Chapter one offers a critique of existing explanations; these tend to focus narrowly on the immediate circumstances surrounding the decision to reform and thereby eschew analysis of the specific dynamics of the Chinese Revolution. In so doing, they also ignore its origins within the welter of contradictions arising from the process of capitalist internationalization, giving no causal efficacy to ‘the international’ in explaining this dramatic social transformation.
    [Show full text]
  • Econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Syrquin, Moshé Working Paper Simon Kuznets and Russia: An uneasy relation CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2021-13 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Syrquin, Moshé (2021) : Simon Kuznets and Russia: An uneasy relation, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2021-13, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/234953 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Simon Kuznets and Russia: An Uneasy Relation Moshe Syrquin CHOPE Working Paper No. 2021-13 June 2021 Simon Kuznets and Russia: An Uneasy Relation Moshe Syrquin [email protected] June 2021 Abstract: Simon Kuznets was born and educated in Russia and the Soviet Ukraine.
    [Show full text]
  • Value Is Dead, Long Live Value
    Value is Dead, Long Live Value Chris Meredith Value investing is a bedrock principle for quantitative and fundamental equity managers, as there O'Shaughnessy Asset is long-term efficacy to buying cheap stocks over expensive growth stocks. While Value investing Management remains attractive over the entire history of available data, it has been under extraordinary pressure since the beginning of 2007. As of June 30, 2019, the Russell 1000 Value has underperformed the Russell 1000 Growth by a cumulative -136%, for an annualized return gap of -4.3% over twelve and a half years. Since the middle of 2017 alone, Value has trailed an additional -21%. This recent underperformance has left the investment community on its heels, as Value managers struggle to explain why their style has been out of favor for so long, and allocators question overweight positions in Value. The severity and length of Value’s underperformance will entice some to capitulation. This may take the form of terminating a manager with a sound investment process, and proven track record, or adjustments to strategic allocations because “Value is dead.” We believe that the key principle to investment success is maintaining one’s discipline in periods when performance works against you. Discipline is fostered from a conviction in the investment process. And conviction is born out of extensive research. This research piece attempts to answer the questions about Value’s underperformance by setting this most recent period within a larger historical context, providing some explanations for why we are in a Growth Regime, and try to set expectations for, if, and when, Value investing will return to favor.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Economy, Capitalism and the Rule of Law
    Cleveland State University EngagedScholarship@CSU Law Faculty Articles and Essays Faculty Scholarship 1-15-2016 Political Economy, Capitalism and the Rule of Law David R. Barnhizer Cleveland State University, [email protected] Daniel D. Barnhizer Michigan State University College of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/fac_articles Part of the Law Commons How does access to this work benefit ou?y Let us know! Repository Citation Barnhizer, David R. and Barnhizer, Daniel D., "Political Economy, Capitalism and the Rule of Law" (2016). Law Faculty Articles and Essays. 821. https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/fac_articles/821 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at EngagedScholarship@CSU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law Faculty Articles and Essays by an authorized administrator of EngagedScholarship@CSU. For more information, please contact [email protected]. CLEVELAND-MARSHALL COLLEGE OF LAW Research Paper 16-292 January 2016 Political Economy, Capitalism and the Rule of Law by David Barnhizer Professor Emeritus of Law, Cleveland-Marshall College of Law and Daniel Barnhizer Professor of Law, Michigan State University College of Law Working Paper This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2716372 Political Economy, Capitalism and the Rule of Law David Barnhizer and Daniel Barnhizer Contents Political Economy and the Rule of Law The
    [Show full text]
  • Marco Paulo Vianna Franco Leonardo Costa Ribeiro Eduardo Da Motta E Albuquerque
    ISSN 2318-2377 TEXTO PARA DISCUSSÃO N 621 JEAN-BAPTISTE FOURIER AT THE MOSCOW CONJUNCTURE INSTITUTE: HARMONIC ANALYSIS OF BUSINESS CYCLES Marco Paulo Vianna Franco Leonardo Costa Ribeiro Eduardo da Motta e Albuquerque Abril de 2020 Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais Textos para Discussão Sandra Regina Goulart Almeida (Reitora) A série de Textos para Discussão divulga resultados Alessandro Fernandes Moreira (Vice-Reitor) preliminares de estudos desenvolvidos no âmbito do Cedeplar, com o objetivo de compartilhar ideias Faculdade de Ciências Econômicas e obter comentários e críticas da comunidade Hugo Eduardo Araujo da Gama Cerqueira (Diretor) científica antes de seu envio para publicação final. Kely César Martins de Paiva (Vice-Diretora) Os Textos para Discussão do Cedeplar começaram a ser publicados em 1974 e têm se destacado pela Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento diversidade de temas e áreas de pesquisa. Regional (Cedeplar) Ficha catalográfica F825j Franco, Marco Paulo Vianna. Frederico Gonzaga Jayme Jr (Diretor) 2020 Jean-Baptiste Fourier at the Moscow Gustavo de Britto Rocha (Vice-Diretor) Conjuncture Institute: Harmonic Analysis of Business Cycles / Marco Paulo Vianna Franco; Leonardo Costa Ribeiro; Eduardo da Laura Rodríguez Wong (Coordenadora do Motta e Albuquerque. - Belo Horizonte: Programa de Pós-graduação em Demografia) UFMG / CEDEPLAR, 2020. 31 p. : il. - (Texto para discussão, 621) Gilberto de Assis L.ibânio (Coordenador do Inclui bibliografia. Programa de Pós-graduação em Economia) ISSN 2318-2377 1. Ciclos econômicos. 2. Análise Adriana de Miranda-Ribeiro (Chefe do harmônica. 3. Análise espectral. I. Ribeiro, Departamento de Demografia) Leonardo Costa. II. Albuquerque, Eduardo da Motta e. III. Universidade Federal de Bernardo Palhares Campolina Diniz (Chefe do Minas Gerais.
    [Show full text]
  • Kondratiev and a New Methodological Agenda for Economics Natalia A
    Russian Journal of Economics 7 (2021) 50–66 DOI 10.32609/j.ruje.7.56826 Publication date: 31 March 2021 www.rujec.org Kondratiev and a new methodological agenda for economics Natalia A. Makasheva* HSE University, Moscow, Russia Abstract This article addresses Kondratiev’s approach to the problems of economic dynam- ics, cycle and conjuncture in the context of a new methodological agenda which was formulated in the 1920’s in Europe and the USA by representatives of the “brilliant generation of economists,” mostly members of the econometric movement and its ad- herents among Russian economists. A distinguishing feature of this generation was that its representatives were striving to make economics an objective science penetrated by rigorous ways of thinking and based on a unification between the theoretical quantitative and the empirical quantitative approaches to the study of economic phenomena. This paper discusses Kondratiev’s project on the general theory of economic dynamics as an embodiment of that methodological agenda. It also highlights a free exchange of ideas between Kondratiev and economists from different countries as a breeding ground for the emergence of the project and a necessary condition for its implementation. Keywords: Kondratiev, economic methodology, economic dynamics, statistical approach. JEL classification: B1, B2, B3, B4. 1. Introduction Nikolai Dmitrievich Kondratiev (1892–1938), Russia’s most internationally renowned economist, who gained worldwide recognition mainly for his idea of large cycles (major cycles, long waves) in economic development, belonged to the generation whom he described regretfully thus: “The heavy chariot of history has passed our generation by” (Kondratiev, 1998, vol. 4, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Kondratieff Waves, Warfare and World Security
    Kondratieff Waves, Warfare and World Security Edited by Tessaleno C. Devezas University of Beira Interior, Covilhã, Portugal Amsterdam • Berlin • Oxford • Tokyo • Washington, DC Published in cooperation with NATO Public Diplomacy Division NATO Security through Science Series This Series presents the results of scientific meetings supported under the NATO Programme for Security through Science (STS). Meetings supported by the NATO STS Programme are in security-related priority areas of Defence Against Terrorism or Countering Other Threats to Security. The types of meeting supported are generally “Advanced Study Institutes” and “Advanced Research Workshops”. The NATO STS Series collects together the results of these meetings. The meetings are co-organized by scientists from NATO countries and scientists from NATO’s “Partner” or “Mediterranean Dialogue” countries. The observations and recommendations made at the meetings, as well as the contents of the volumes in the Series, reflect those of participants and contributors only; they should not necessarily be regarded as reflecting NATO views or policy. Advanced Study Institutes (ASI) are high-level tutorial courses to convey the latest developments in a subject to an advanced-level audience Advanced Research Workshops (ARW) are expert meetings where an intense but informal exchange of views at the frontiers of a subject aims at identifying directions for future action Following a transformation of the programme in 2004 the Series has been re-named and re- organised. Recent volumes on topics not related to security, which result from meetings supported under the programme earlier, may be found in the NATO Science Series. The Series is published by IOS Press, Amsterdam, and Springer Science and Business Media, Dordrecht, in conjunction with the NATO Public Diplomacy Division.
    [Show full text]
  • Smuta: Cyclical Visions of History in Contemporary Russian Thought and the Question of Hegemony
    Stud East Eur Thought https://doi.org/10.1007/s11212-018-9298-0 Smuta: cyclical visions of history in contemporary Russian thought and the question of hegemony Ka˚re Johan Mjør1 Ó The Author(s) 2018. This article is an open access publication Abstract In the post-Soviet context, various cyclical models of recurrent Russian ‘‘Times of Troubles’’ (smuty) have become increasingly popular. This perspective emerged first in Soviet dissident circles (Alexander Yanov, Aleksandr Akhiezer), who used it as a means to expose as mistaken the Soviet belief in continual his- torical progress on Russian soil. In post-Soviet Russia this critical approach has been continued by members of the ‘‘Akhezier circle,’’ the economist Egor Gaidar, and others. Meanwhile it was given an affirmative, conservative reinterpretation by Aleksandr Panarin, according to whom Russia has always managed to overcome its phases of devastating Westernization and state collapse. This idea of Russian history has become influential; even Vladimir Putin has talked about Russia as a strong state able to survive various ‘‘Times of Troubles’’ from the early seventeenth century to the early post-Soviet period. It also figures prominently among members of the neoconservative Izborsk Club. This article analyzes different conceptions of Rus- sian history as cyclical and their prominent place in the prevailing civilizational discourse of post-Soviet Russia. By means of postcolonial perspectives, this dis- course is seen on the one hand as an attempt to question and reject Western hegemony, attempts that on the other hand nevertheless seem unable to liberate themselves from a normative dependence on the West.
    [Show full text]