Role of International Organizations in Port Infrastructure Development

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Role of International Organizations in Port Infrastructure Development ROLE OF INTERNATIONAL ORGANIZATIONS IN PORT INFRASTRUCTURE DEVELOPMENT Biju Ninan Oommen Ports & Maritime Transport The World Bank Agenda • Current Scenario • Emerging Trends • Port Infra Developments • Role for MDB’s 1 International Seaborne Trade (million tonnes): 2015 Source: UNCTAD 10 2 3 Source: Drewry, IMF, World Bank analysis & estimates Port Capacity (2015) vs Utilization (1H 2016) Source: Alphaliner 10 4 Investments in Port Infrastructure Development: 1990-2015 Total Investment 1990 - 2015 No: of Ports (Billion USD) Total Port Projects 442 $79.08 5 ppi.worldbank.org Ongoing Container Port Infrastructure developments in Asia • Mega ports • Singapore – (PPT 3 & 4) • Malaysia – Pelepas, Westports, Northport • China - Port of Ningbo-Zhoushan • Korea – Busan • Regional Gateway ports • Indonesia ( Jakarta/Surabaya) • Bangladesh (NCT 3&4) • India (Nhava Sheva – 4th terminal) 6 Need for Port Infrastructure development in emerging economies . Chronic port congestion . Slow turnaround of vessels . Over reliance on poorly maintained and congested roads / rail networks . Poor connectivity to demand areas . Shipments are to be trans-shipped through gateway ports in other countries 7 Ports & Waterborne Transport Quality of Port Infrastructure Index & Global Competitiveness Rankings 2015 [2014] Country Port Infra Quality Index Overall Ranking Singapore 6.7 2 [2] Malaysia 5.4 18 [20] Korea, Rep. 5.2 26 [26] China 4.6 28 [28] Thailand 4.2 32 [31] Indonesia 3.9 37 [34] Sri Lanka 4.3 68 [73] Vietnam 3.8 56 [68] India 4.5 55 [71] Philippines 3.2 47 [52] LaoPDR 2.0 83 [93] Bangladesh 3.5 107 [109] Pakistan 3.7 126 [129] Myanmar 2.6 131 [134] Total No Countries 140 [144] Source: World Economic Forum Statistics (Min 1.37 extremely underdeveloped, Max 6.77 extensive & efficient) 12 8 Significant Infrastructure Gap • USD 8 trillion of investment in Asia 2010 – 2020 (Source: ADB) Asia's Infrastructure Investment Needs by Sector 2010 - 2020 (USD Trillion) 0.40 2.40 Energy 4.10 Telecommunications Transport Water & Sanitation Source: ADB1.10 • USD 20 trillion up to 2030 (Global Infrastructure Initiative, G20) 10 9 Emerging Trends • Mega vessel deployments • Trading Patterns • Multiple modal connectivity • E-commerce, market fragmentation 10 The ultra large container vessel (ULCV) MSC Oscar which loads 19,200 containers is deployed on the East-West routes, between the ports in the Far East & North Europe region. The larger capacity vessels enabled ship operators to reduce the operating costs substantially, with the ULCV’s providing almost 50% fuel efficiency gains over the 5,000 teu post panamax vessels deployed on the Europe routes in the 1990s. 11 Source: Maersk/MSC Limited port calls by mega ships, larger infra req at mega ports 12 Source: Maersk, CMA-CGM Ports serving Ultra Large Container Vessels Major transshipment hub ports for Mega shipping alliance 2M (Maersk & MSC) • Asia: China/Ningbo & Yantian; Malaysia/Tanjung Pelepas • Europe: Netherland/Rotterdam, Germany/Bremerhaven, UK/Felixstowe & France/Le Havre 13 Source: Liner schedule analysis Mega port connectivity: Key to harnessing scale economies Major transshipment port calls on 2M services between Asia-Europe • Ningbo – connects Japan/Osaka, Kobe, Nagoya, Tokyo • Tanjung Pelepas – connects South East Asia & Bay of Bengal ports • Rotterdam – gateway to the EU 14 Maersk/MSC schedule analysis Port Infra for Connectivity at Mega ports • Large investments in shore side infra – STS/yard cranes, prime movers • Reliable short sea feeder network to regional feeder ports - SIN/Malaysia connected with number of ports in SE Asia & South Asia • Coastal Shipping network (feeding the hub) – INDIA/Nhava Sheva • Inland Water Transport network – CHINA/Shanghai & Ningbo • Multimodal connectivity to hinterland - waterways, rail and road network – EU/Rotterdam-Duisberg • ICT & port systems to deliver integrated services - processing flows from multiple corridors for larger transactions – SIN 15 Presentation Title Boosting Trade through development of Regional Gateway ports Gateway ports: primary role - maximize cargo generation thru connectivity to local, hinterland, far-inland, cross-border markets • Larger port capacity to handle bigger vessels deployed due to cascade effect • Inland ports – extended gates • Inland Water Transport network • Multimodal - waterways, rail and road network • Coastal Shipping network • ICT: National platform – logistics, freight transport, PCS 16 Presentation Title 17 Source: Drewry, Alphaliner, World Bank analysis Reading the signs… • Falling volumes after the surge in 2015 • Migration of volumes to new production centers & gateway ports 18 The trends indicate… Need to boost Regional & Inland Port Connectivity • Infrastructure facilities at regional gateway ports • Coastal Shipping network - feeder / inland ports • Inland Water Transport – River port development • Multimodal connectivity: waterways & railways with road networks 19 The World Bank: Ports & Waterborne Transport sector • Infrastructure Development • National water ways – India / Bangladesh • Extended gates – India (Kolkata) • River Terminals – China: Yichang (Hubei) • Multimodal connectivity to hinterland • Rail : Dedicated Freight corridor – India/DFC, India/EDFC • Waterways: China, Vietnam, India/NW1 & 2 • Roads: Cambodia-Vietnam • ICT & port systems to deliver integrated services - processing flows from multiple corridors for larger transactions 20 River ports on Yangtze: Yichang – Three Gorges Port Centre 21 IBRD/IDA: Major Projects Pakistan: Karachi Port • US$115.8 Million approved in 2010 • Objective: Replace the lost port capacity and reduce shipping costs to the Pakistan economy through the reconstruction of the failed berths (15-17A) / increasing the effectiveness and efficiency of port operations as well as enhancing environmental sustainability. 22 IBRD/IDA: Pipeline Projects Bangladesh Regional Waterway Transport Project 1 Project Background • Improve the navigability and year-round safe transport for passengers and cargo along Bangladesh’s busiest waterways • Build the capacity of the Bangladesh Inland Water Transport Authority to ensure modern and efficient management. • Enhance navigation on 900 km of inland waterways along the Chittagong-Dhaka-Ashuganj Corridor and connecting routes. at an estimated cost of USD 400 million Project Components • Build one new general cargo terminal at Pangaon and improve the existing cargo terminal at Ashuganj. • Project will construct 14 landing Ghats/stations in Chars (shoals), where often waterways are the only mode of transportation. • Build new and rehabilitate existing passenger terminals at Sadarghat, Narayanganj, Chandpur, and Barisal. 23 Project Types • Project types include: • Providing Advisory to Governments in Emerging Economies: • Eg Study of trade flows/ infrastructure/ processes/ recommendations for improvement Consultancy • Providing Financing/ Developing Projects for Logistics Infrastructure: • Eg Air, Land, Sea transport corridors, information systems, customs facilitation systems Goods & Services • Providing Capacity Building to Governments: • Eg Planning, Development, Management & Operation of Transport/ Logistics Infrastructure/ Processes Training/ Consultancy Private Participation in Infrastructure: 1990-2015 Total Investment (Billion 1990-2015 No: of Ports USD) Total Port Projects 442 $79.08 PPP projects 406 $74.57 MDB Supported 56 $12.84 Green Field 193 $44.58 25 ppi.worldbank.org Private participation in Port Infrastructure Development Investment Capacity Contract period & Debt Funding Project Sponsors Type of PPI (Million USD) Type method (Million USD) PSA Panama 2 Million 20 years, Direct International Terminal $400.00 PSA Corp (100% / ..) Greenfield: BOT $150.00 TEUS Negotiation - Phase 2 Brownfield: Build Chabahar port 250,000 $235.00 India Ports Global Rehabilitate, 10 years $150.00 development TEUS Operate & Transfer Bharat Mumbai Brownfield: Build 4.8 Million 30 years, Competitive Container Terminals $765.10 PSA Corp (100% / Singapore) Rehabilitate, $497.30 TEUS bidding Private Limited Operate & Transfer Brownfield: Build 6 Million Matarani Port $335.00 Grupo Romero (100% / Mexico) Rehabilitate, 30 years $280.00 TEUS Operate & Transfer Karanja Terminal and Skil Ports & Logistics Limited (100% / 30 years, Direct Logistics Private $160.80 Lighterage Greenfield: BOT $78.70 India) Negotiation 26Limited Private participation in Port Infra Development with MDB loans Capacity Contract period & MDB Loan (Debt Project Investment Sponsors Type of PPI Type method Funding) Brownfield: Build Kingston Freeport China Merchant Holdings (International) 3.2 Million 30 years, Competitive $437 M Rehabilitate, $175 M Terminal Limited Co Ltd (49% / ..), CMA-CGM (51% / ..) TEUS bidding Operate & Transfer Manzanillo TEC II International Container Terminal 1.4 Million $345 M Greenfield: BOT 34 years $260 M (Phase II) Services Inc. (ICTSI) (100% / ..) TEUS Tuxpan Container Stevedoring Services of America (SSA) 0.9 Million 20 years, Competitive $370 M Greenfield: BOT $75 M Terminal, Veracruz Inc. (71% / United States) TEUS bidding Puerto Quetzal Terminal de Contenidores de Barcelona 0.34 Million 25 years, Competitive $120 M Greenfield: BLT $35 M Container Terminal (100% / Spain) TEUS bidding 70,000 Channel dredging & Port Lafito $57 M Gilbert Bigio Group (100% / Haiti) Greenfield: BOO $15 M TEUS Terminal 27 Presentation Title But We Are Not Just a Bank… UPSTREAM Infra Data & Trend Knowledge Analysis Capacity building for PPP Units and Regulators Regulatory
Recommended publications
  • Lakes Port & Harbor: Infrastructure & Dredging Cost Estimate Matrix Tool
    Great Lakes Port & Harbor: Infrastructure & Dredging Cost Estimate Matrix Tool and Duluth, MN/Superior, WI and Toledo, OH Case Studies Gene Clark1 and Dale Bergeron2 1 WI Sea Grant [email protected] 2 MN Sea Grant dbergeron@ d.umn.edu Defining the parameters of the Matrix Great Lakes ports, harbors and marinas are vulnerable to several potential climate change impacts. The two major impacts most relevant and potentially most costly are water level and storm intensity. Both rising and falling water levels can impact infrastructure stability and overall strength, as well as requiring additional channel dredging. A climatic change resulting in an increase in severe storms (more precipitation, higher winds and greater number of storm events) is also viewed as having detrimental affects on infrastructure. More severe storms can create larger waves, more extreme Seiche events and greater storm-surges that can damage port and harbor infrastructure requiring costly rehabilitation or replacement. In addition to infrastructure issues, an increased storm frequency and intensity will increase channel silting and sedimentation, compounding dredging problems analogous to lower water level scenarios. Climate model predictions for specific weather outcomes vary greatly throughout the Great Lakes Basin, and include both higher and lower water levels scenarios. However, all predictions seem to include an increase in both the number and intensity of major storm events. This combination can result in unanticipated water level change, larger waves, more dramatic Seiches and greater storm surges than considered in original design parameters (all of this in addition to the antiquated and sometime dilapidated state of our Great Lakes infrastructure).
    [Show full text]
  • All Aboard: the Aggregate Effects of Port Development
    All aboard: The aggregate effects of port development César Ducruet1, Réka Juhász2, Dávid Krisztián Nagy3, and Claudia Steinwender4 1CNRS 2Columbia University 3CREI, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE 4MIT Sloan ∗ July 3, 2019 Abstract This paper studies the distributional and aggregate economic effects of new port technologies developed in the second half of the 20th century. We show that new technologies have led to a significant reallocation of shipping activity from large to small cities. This was driven by a land price mechanism; as new port technologies are more land-intensive, ports moved from large, high land price cities to smaller, lower land price ones. We add endogenous port development to a standard quantitative model of cross- city trade to account for both the benefits and the costs of port development. According to the model, the adoption of new port technologies leads to benefits through increasing market access but is costly, requiring the extensive use of land, suggesting a reallocation of shipping activities towards cities with low land prices and thus net gains from new port technologies that are heterogeneous across cities. Counterfactual results suggest that new port technologies led to sizable aggregate gains for the world economy, with substantial heterogeneity in the effects across countries. More generally, accounting for the costs of port infrastructure development endogenously has the potential to alter the size and distribution of the gains from trade. ∗We thank David Atkin, Don Davis, Dave Donaldson, Joseph Doyle, Matt Grant, Gordon Hanson, Tom Holmes, Amit Khandelwal, Jim Rauch, Roberto Rigobon, Esteban Rossi-Hansberg and Tavneet Suri for helpful comments and discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Regulation of Utility Infrastructure
    4 Economic Regulation of Utility Infrastructure Janice A. Beecher ublic infrastructure has characteristics of both public and private goods and earns a separate classification as a toll good. Utilities demonstrate a Pvariety of distinct and interrelated technical, economic, and institutional characteristics that relate to market structure and oversight. Except for the water sector, much of the infrastructure providing essential utility services in the United States is privately owned and operated. Private ownership of utility infrastructure necessitates economic regulation to address market failures and prevent abuse of monopoly power, particularly at the distribution level. The United States can uniquely boast more than 100 years of experience in regulation in the public in- terest through a social compact that balances and protects the interests of inves- tors and ratepayers both. Jurisdiction is shared between independent federal and state commissions that apply established principles through a quasi-judicial pro- cess. The commissions continue to rely primarily on the method known as rate base/rate-of-return regulation, by which regulators review the prudence of in- frastructure investment, along with prices, profits, and performance. Regulatory theory and practice have adapted to emerging technologies and evolving market conditions. States—and nation-states—have become the experimental laborato- ries for structuring, restructuring, and regulating infrastructure industries, and alternative methods have been tried, including price-cap and performance regu- lation in the United Kingdom and elsewhere. Aging infrastructure and sizable capital requirements, in the absence of effective competition, argue for a regula- tory role. All forms of regulation, and their implementation, can and should be Review comments from Tim Brennan, Carl Peterson, Ken Costello, David Wagman, and the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy are greatly appreciated.
    [Show full text]
  • Improving Road Infrastructure and Traffic Flows IRU Resolution Adopted by the Council of Direction at Its Meeting in Brussels on 18 May 2000
    Improving road infrastructure and traffic flows IRU Resolution adopted by the Council of Direction at its meeting in Brussels on 18 May 2000 The mobility of people and goods is dependent on the efficient use of existing traffic infrastructure, and the modernisation and expansion of traffic infrastructure to meet the future demand for transport services efficiently and cost-effectively. This applies in particular to roads, since road transport accounts for more than 90% of all passenger transport and more than 80% of all goods transport in most countries in terms of passengers and tonnes carried. Impediments to mobility such as traffic restrictions, road blockades, closures of certain road infrastructure sections, or congestion due to bottlenecks in road infrastructure ignore the fact that • road infrastructure investments are a vital prerequisite for improving road safety, (see annex 1) • revenues from the transport of goods by road (fuel taxes, vehicle ownership taxes, road user charges) more than cover expenditure on road building and maintenance, as do revenues from the transport by bus and coach (see annex 2) • congested traffic leads to a significant increase of fuel consumption by a factor of up to 3, (see annex 3) • on average, only 0.5% of total land surface in most countries is used for road infrastructure, (see annex 4) • the economic benefits of road infrastructure investments are 29 times its investment costs, and thus the highest of all infrastructure sectors, including other transport modes, (see annex 5) • the economic cost of impediments to road transport (congestion, border delays, traffic bans, blockades etc.) amounts to 0.5% of GDP, i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • Environmental Product Declaration in Accordance with ISO 14025 and EN 15804:2012+A1:2013 For
    Environmental Product Declaration In accordance with ISO 14025 and EN 15804:2012+A1:2013 for: Under Ballast Mat, type UBM-H35-C from Programme: The International EPD® System, www.environdec.com Programme operator: EPD International AB EPD registration number: S-P-02061 Publication date: 2021-02-08 Valid until: 2026-02-08 An EPD should provide current information and may be updated if conditions change. The stated validity is therefore subject to the continued registration and publication at www.environdec.com PAGE 1/13 General information Programme information Programme: The International EPD® System EPD International AB Box 210 60 Address: SE-100 31 Stockholm Sweden Website: www.environdec.com E-mail: [email protected] CEN standard EN 15804 serves as the Core Product Category Rules (PCR) Product category rules (PCR): Product Category Rules for construction products and construction services of 2012:01, version 2.33 valid: 2021-12-31 PCR review was conducted by: Technical Committee of the International EPD® System, A full list of members available on www.environdec.com. The review panel may be contacted via [email protected]. Independent third-party verification of the declaration and data, according to ISO 14025:2006: ☐ EPD process certification ☒ EPD verification Third party verifier: Damien Prunel from Bureau Veritas LCIE Approved by: The International EPD® System Procedure for follow-up of data during EPD validity involves third party verifier: ☐ Yes ☒ No The EPD owner has the sole ownership, liability, and responsibility for the EPD. EPDs within the same product category but from different programmes may not be comparable. EPDs of construction products may not be comparable if they do not comply with EN 15804.
    [Show full text]
  • Road Transport Infrastructure
    © IEA ETSAP - Technology Brief T14 – August 2011 - www.etsap.org Road Transport Infrastructure HIGHLIGHTS TECHNOLOGY STATUS - Road transport infrastructure enables movements of people and goods within and between countries. It is also a sector within the construction industry that has demonstrated significant developments over time and ongoing growth, particularly in the emerging economies. This brief highlights the different impacts of the road transport infrastructure, including those from construction, maintenance and operation (use). The operation (use) phase of a road transport infrastructure has the most significance in terms of environmental and economic impact. While the focus in this phase is usually on the dominant role of tail-pipe GHG emissions from vehicles, the operation of the physical infrastructure should also accounted for. In total, the road transport infrastructure is thought to account for between 8% and 18% of the full life cycle energy requirements and GHG emissions from road transport. PERFORMANCE AND COSTS - Energy consumption, GHG emissions and costs of road transport infrastructure fall broadly into the three phases: (i) construction, (ii) maintenance, and (iii) operation (decommissioning is not included in this brief). The construction and maintenance costs of a road transport infrastructure vary according to location and availability of raw materials (in general, signage and lighting systems are not included in the construction costs). GHG emissions resulting from road construction have been estimated to be between 0.37 and 1.07 ktCO2/km for a 13m wide road – depending on construction methods. Maintenance over the road lifetime (typically 40 years) can also be significant in terms of costs, energy consumption and GHG emissions.
    [Show full text]
  • Lectures 13 to 15 CHAPTER 3: PUBLIC GOODS
    Lectures 13 to 15 CHAPTER 3: PUBLIC GOODS 3.1: Public Goods Pure Private to Pure Public Good • Private good consumed only by one person: food, holidays, clothes • Family/household: all collective decisions and no market. ‘Micro- collective’. Share kitchens, TV, bathrooms. • Many families/household: roads and paths, communal halls, clubs etc. Tennis and golf clubs, plus Tidy Towns’ committees for example. ‘Mini- collective’. • Option public goods: fire brigade, hospitals, museums, etc. Provided by state but not used by all. ‘Partial full collective’ • Pure public goods benefit ALL. ‘Full collective’. National security, environment, lakes, sea and mountains. Used by all but to varying degrees. • Exclusion impossible. Raises free-rider problem: e.g. lighthouse, but now excludable. Firework display a good example (see later) • Public goods bring benefits just like private goods: Ui = F(A, B, C, D) • Same supply for ALL: G1=G2=G3= etc. Not same utility though. • Private good, A; same price and utility but different supply • Pure v impure PGs: security v bridge (Fig 3.1) • Fire brigade example (p. 144). Available to all, but only used when needed if ever. Private company would protect only those how had paid. • Public goods v natural monopolies (e.g. electricity or water) but private A fireworks display is a public good because it is non-excludable (impossible to prevent people from viewing it) and non-rivalrous (one individual's use does not reduce availability to others). Voluntary payment (Fig 3.3) • MC curve same as that for private goods (Fig 3.3): n people benefit though from every extra unit.
    [Show full text]
  • Trends in Bulkcarrier Market & Port Activity.Pptx
    If necessary change logos on covers/ chapter dividers and in the footer. Dedicated logos are available in the template tool at the end of the list Trends In Bulkcarrier If you want to update Title and Subtitle in the Market & Port Activity footer, go to View tab → Slide Master Presentation to the International and change it on Dry Bulk Terminals Group first slide in the left pane 11 April 2019, Barcelona Trevor Crowe, Director, Date format: Day, month and year Clarksons Research e.g. 30 June 2018 Ref: A4036b Agenda Trends In Bulkcarrier Market & Port Activity 1. Introduction to the Clarksons group, Clarksons Research and Sea/net 2. Global Dry Bulk Port Activity – Looking At The Big Picture 3. Profiles & Case Studies - Drilling Down For Port Intelligence 4. Summary Trends In Bulkcarrier Market & Port Activity | International Dry Bulk Terminals Group, 11 April 2019 2 EnablingThe Clarksons Global Group Trade Clarksons is the 167 YEARS world’s leading provider 48 OFFICES of integrated shipping services IN 22 COUNTRIES FTSE 250 Our intelligence adds value by 15+ YEARS enabling clients to make more INCREASING DIVIDENDS efficient and informed decisions to achieve their business objectives 24/7 5,000+ INTERNATIONAL CLIENTS Trends In Bulkcarrier Market & Port Activity | International Dry Bulk Terminals Group, 11 April 2019 Clarksons Research Market leader, excellent brand, >120 staff globally, broad and diverse product range and client base OFFSHORE AND ENERGY SHIPPING AND TRADE The leading provider offshore Market leaders in timely and data for more than 30 years. authoritative information on all Providing clients with the key aspects of shipping.
    [Show full text]
  • Infrastructure Failure I. Introduction Two Broad Areas of Concern
    Infrastructure Failure I. Introduction Two broad areas of concern regarding infrastructure failure include: • Episodic failure: temporary loss of power, technology associated with maintenance of the babies may fail, or some other temporary issue may occur. • Catastrophic failure: significant damage to hospital infrastructure or anticipated prolonged outage of critical systems may trigger a decision to perform a hospital evacuation. Preplanning requires recognition of potential threats or hazards and then development of management strategies to locate the resources and support patient needs. • In disasters, departmental leaders need to develop an operational chart to plan for a minimum of 96 hours for staff needs, as well as patient care needs and supplies that may be depleted as supplies are moved with the patients. In the event that supplies or equipment cannot be replenished, staff may need to improvise. It is important that staff become familiar with non-traditional methodologies to assist equipment-dependent emergencies for neonatal patients. • The first task in dealing with infrastructure emergencies is to complete a pre-disaster assessment of critical infrastructure (see Appendix A). A key consideration in deciding whether to issue a pre-event evacuation order is to assess vulnerabilities and determine anticipated impact of the emergency on the hospital and its surrounding community. II. Critical Infrastructure Self-Assessment Worksheet A Pre-Disaster Assessment of Critical Infrastructure Worksheet (Appendix A) is divided into eight sections: municipal water, steam, electricity, natural gas, boilers/chillers, powered life support equipment, information technology, telecommunications, and security. The Worksheet can be used in conjunction with the National Infrastructure Protection Plan (NIPP), which is a management guide for protecting critical infrastructure and key resources.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Goods for Economic Development
    Printed in Austria Sales No. E.08.II.B36 V.08-57150—November 2008—1,000 ISBN 978-92-1-106444-5 Public goods for economic development PUBLIC GOODS FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT FOR ECONOMIC GOODS PUBLIC This publication addresses factors that promote or inhibit successful provision of the four key international public goods: fi nancial stability, international trade regime, international diffusion of technological knowledge and global environment. Each of these public goods presents global challenges and potential remedies to promote economic development. Without these goods, developing countries are unable to compete, prosper or attract capital from abroad. The undersupply of these goods may affect prospects for economic development, threatening global economic stability, peace and prosperity. The need for public goods provision is also recognized by the Millennium Development Goals, internationally agreed goals and targets for knowledge, health, governance and environmental public goods. Because of the characteristics of public goods, leaving their provision to market forces will result in their under provision with respect to socially desirable levels. Coordinated social actions are therefore necessary to mobilize collective response in line with socially desirable objectives and with areas of comparative advantage and value added. International public goods for development will grow in importance over the coming decades as globalization intensifi es. Corrective policies hinge on the goods’ properties. There is no single prescription; rather, different kinds of international public goods require different kinds of policies and institutional arrangements. The Report addresses the nature of these policies and institutions using the modern principles of collective action. UNITED NATIONS INDUSTRIAL DEVELOPMENT ORGANIZATION Vienna International Centre, P.O.
    [Show full text]
  • Data for the Public Good
    Data for the public good NATIONAL INFRASTRUCTURE COMMISSION National Infrastructure Commission report | Data for the public good Foreword Advances in technology have always transformed our lives and indeed whole industries such as banking and retail. In the same way, sensors, cloud computing, artificial intelligence and machine learning can transform the way we use and manage our national infrastructure. Government could spend less, whilst delivering benefits to the consumer: lower bills, improved travel times, and reduced disruption from congestion or maintenance work. The more information we have about the nation’s infrastructure, the better we can understand it. Therefore, data is crucial. Data can improve how our infrastructure is built, managed, and eventually decommissioned, and real-time data can inform how our infrastructure is operated on a second-to-second basis. However, collecting data alone will not improve the nation’s infrastructure. The key is to collect high quality data and use it effectively. One path is to set standards for the format of data, enabling high quality data to be easily shared and understood; much that we take for granted today is only possible because of agreed standards, such as bar codes on merchandise which have enabled the automation of checkout systems. Sharing data can catalyse innovation and improve services. Transport for London (TfL) has made information on London’s transport network available to the public, paving the way for the development of apps like Citymapper, which helps people get about the city safely and expediently. But it is important that when information on national infrastructure is shared, this happens with the appropriate security and privacy arrangements.
    [Show full text]
  • Transportation Infrastructure, Productivity, and Externalities
    Transportation Infrastructure, Productivity, and Externalities Charles R. Hulten University of Maryland and National Bureau of Economic Research August, 2004 Revised February, 2005 ABSTRACT This paper summarizes the results of three studies linking investment in highway infrastructure to productivity growth in the manufacturing sector of the U.S., Spanish, and Indian economies. The goal of this research is (1) to trace the overall impact of highway investment on the growth of this strategic sector, (2) to examine the interregional effects of such investments, with particular attention to the issue of whether highway investment encourages regional convergence and relocation of economic activity, and (3) to assess the extent of the spillover externalities on manufacturing industry associated with such investments. This last issue is of particular importance for infrastructure policy, since spillover externalities tend to go uncounted in formal project investment analyses, leading to the possibility of under-investment. The comparative study of three countries at different stages of economic development using virtually the same model allows a fourth issue to be examined: the possibility that the effects of infrastructure investment differ according to the level of development and the extent to which existing infrastructure networks have already been built up. These issues are first framed in the larger context of the literature on infrastructure and productivity. Paper prepared for the 132nd Round Table of the European Conference of Ministers of Transport, at the Joint OECD/EMCT Transport Research Center, Paris, France, December 2 and 3, 2004. 1. Transportation Infrastructure and Productivity: Historical Background The idea that transportation infrastructure is a type of capital investment distinct from other forms of capital is an accepted part of the fields of economic development, location theory, urban and regional economics, and, of course, transport economics.
    [Show full text]