Regulating Big Techs in Finance

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Regulating Big Techs in Finance BIS Bulletin No 45 Regulating big techs in finance Agustín Carstens, Stijn Claessens, Fernando Restoy and Hyun Song Shin 2 August 2021 BIS Bulletins are written by staff members of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. The authors are grateful to Leonardo Gambacorta, Jon Frost, Giulio Cornelli, Ilaria Mattei, Philip Wooldridge, Patrick McGuire, Neil Esho, Nikola Tarashev, Blaise Gadanecz, Gong Cheng and Aidan Lawson for their input and to Louisa Wagner for administrative support. The editor of the BIS Bulletin series is Hyun Song Shin. This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2021. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN: 2708-0420 (online) ISBN: 978-92-9197-501-2 (online) Agustín Carstens Stijn Claessens Fernando Restoy Hyun Song Shin [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Regulating big techs in finance Key takeaways Big tech firms entering financial services can scale up rapidly with user data from their existing business lines in e-commerce and social media, and by harnessing the inherent network effects in digital services. In addition to traditional policy concerns such as financial risks, consumer protection and operational resilience, the entry of big techs into financial services gives rise to new challenges surrounding the concentration of market power and data governance. The current framework for regulating financial services follows an activities-based approach where providers must hold licences for specific business lines. There is scope to address the new policy challenges by developing specific entity-based rules, as proposed in several key jurisdictions – notably the European Union, China and the United States. The centrality of data in the digital economy has enabled the entry into financial services and rapid growth of big tech firms. Big techs have existing businesses in e-commerce and social media, among others, from which they can expand into finance. Their business model revolves around the direct interactions of users and the data generated as an essential by-product of these interactions. The distinguishing feature of big techs is that they can overcome limits to scale by utilising user data from their existing businesses to scale up rapidly by harnessing the inherent network effects in digital services. In turn, the greater user activity generates yet more data, reinforcing the advantages that come from network effects. In this way, big techs can establish a substantial presence in financial services very quickly through the so-called “data-network- activities” (DNA) loop.1 This gives rise to concerns about the emergence of dominant firms with excessive concentration of market power and a possibly systemic footprint in the financial system. The rapid growth of big tech firms in financial services presents various policy challenges. Some are variations of familiar themes that lie squarely within the traditional scope of central banks and financial regulators, such as the mitigation of financial risks and the oversight of operational resilience and consumer protection. Assessing big techs’ resilience through a financial cycle will necessitate more systematic monitoring and understanding of big tech business models on the part of the authorities, for instance on whether learning algorithms may inject systematic biases to the detriment of financial stability. As well as issues that arise from traditional financial stability concerns, there are new and unfamiliar challenges stemming from the potential for excessive concentration of market power, as well as broader issues concerning data governance. These new challenges lie outside the traditional scope of the central bank’s remit, but they can nevertheless impinge on the central bank’s core mission of ensuring sound money as well as the integrity and smooth functioning of the payment system. While some central banks’ oversight authority includes the competitive functioning and efficiency of the payment system, their mandates do not normally encompass the broad range of competition and data privacy issues that arise in relation to the activities of big techs in financial services. Nevertheless, since the central bank issues the 1 See BIS (2019), Frost et al (2019) and Croxson et al (forthcoming). BIS Bulletin 3 unit of account in the economy, trust in the currency rests ultimately on the trust placed in the central bank itself. Any impact on the integrity of the monetary system arising from the emergence of dominant platforms ought to be a key concern for the central bank. This Bulletin reviews the policy challenges for central banks and financial regulators in their oversight of the activity of big tech firms in financial services, especially as it relates to the payment system. Traditional demarcations that separate the roles of financial regulators from those of competition authorities and data privacy regulators may become blurred in the case of big techs in finance. Rules that were formulated with specific financial stability risks in mind (credit and liquidity risk, market risk etc) may be inadequate for addressing the unique combination of policy concerns to which big techs give rise. These concerns bear on the central bank’s core mission to maintain the integrity of the monetary system. In this regard, the central bank should work more closely with competition and data privacy authorities. Big techs’ growing footprint in the financial system The market for retail payments is a particularly stark example of the potential for rapid concentration. Graph 1 (left-hand panel) illustrates how rapidly the user base of big techs can take off through the DNA loop once a critical mass of users has been established. The growth of user numbers may also be reinforced through merger and acquisition activity whereby smaller potential competitors are absorbed into the ecosystem of services around the core big tech platform. Big techs’ rapid growth in users underpins their dominance in some markets Graph 1 Big techs’ monthly active users Development of mobile payments in China Billions Billions Market share, % CNY trillions 2.4 0.06 90 360 1.6 0.04 60 240 0.8 0.02 30 120 0.0 0.00 0 0 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 20 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Lhs: Alibaba Tencent Rhs: Kakao Lhs: Sum of the market share of Alipay and Tenpay2 Facebook Google1 Groupon Rhs: Transaction value of mobile payments on Alipay Tenpay3 Other third-party mobile payment providers in China 1 The number of Chrome users is used as a proxy for Google’s number of active users. 2 Market shares for 2012 are estimated based on market evidence. 3 Tenpay includes WeChat Pay and QQ Wallet. Sources: BIS (2019); Enfodesk; S&P Capital IQ, company reports, analysys.cn; Statista, Industries; BIS calculations. In some jurisdictions, big techs have gained a substantial presence in the retail payment system (FSB (2019a,b)). For instance, in China the two big tech payment firms jointly account for 94% of the mobile payments market (Graph 1, right-hand panel). The rapid growth in payment transactions within a few years shows how quickly big tech firms can establish their footprints. Beyond payments, big techs have also become lenders to individuals and small businesses in some markets as well as offering insurance and wealth management services (Cornelli et al (2020)). 4 BIS Bulletin Even in those jurisdictions where big techs do not currently have a dominant position in the financial system, their potential for rapid growth warrants close attention from central banks. Stablecoin projects and other big tech initiatives could be a game changer for the monetary system if their entry leads to closed loop systems reinforced by network effects from data drawn from social media or e-commerce platforms. Strong network effects and the entrenchment of closed networks could lead to a fragmentation of payment infrastructures to the detriment of the public good nature of money. Given the potential for rapid change, the absence of currently dominant platforms should not be a source of comfort for central banks. Rather, they should anticipate developments and formulate policy based on possible scenarios where big tech initiatives may already have reshaped the payment system, instead of focusing on the market structure of the payment system as it currently stands. Market dominance and data governance Entrenchment of market power also carries implications for the high costs of payment services. High merchant service costs associated with credit and debit cards have remained one of the stubborn shortcomings of the existing payment system, although the costs vary across jurisdictions.2 These costs are not immediately visible to consumers, as charges are usually levied on the merchants, who are not allowed to pass these fees on to consumers. However, the ultimate incidence of these costs depends on how much of the merchant fees are passed on to consumers through higher prices at the checkout (Mariotto and Verdier (2017)). A possible concern is that when big tech firms achieve a dominant position, the economics of platform competition may lead to merchant fees that are even higher than the high costs that exist currently. Merchant fees as high as 4% have been reported in some cases.3 Competition policy does not normally fall within the central bank’s purview. Some central banks are directed to consider the competitive functioning of the financial system (eg Reserve Bank of Australia, Bank of England) or its efficiency (eg Bank of Korea, Netherlands Bank) in implementing their policies. In any case, the central bank’s oversight of the payment system and its mission to ensure its efficiency mean that there is a strong case for the central bank to work closely with the competition authorities.
Recommended publications
  • World Bank Document
    Sg)7 L C/ oy, Research,and ExternalAffairs WC PAPERS Debtand International Flnance Public Disclosure Authorized InternationalEconomics Department TheWorld Bank August1 991 WPS749 Hedging Public Disclosure Authorized Commodity Price Risks in Papua New Guinea Public Disclosure Authorized Stijn Claessens and JonathanColeman With increasing awareness of commodity price risks and with Public Disclosure Authorized technical assistance - strategic advice and assistance in institu- tion building and skills training --developing countries such as Papua New Guinea can learn to use market-based commodity- linked financial instruments to improve their economic manage- ment. The Policy. Research. and Extemal Affairs Complcx distnbics PRE Working Papers todisscminatethe findings of work in progress and to cneouragc the exchange of ideas among lIank staff and all others interested in development issues. These pipemstany the names of the authors, reflect only their views, and should be uscd and cited accordingly. The findings, interprctations, and conclusions are the authors' own. Thcy should not be attributed to the World Bank, its Board of Directors, its management, ur any of iLtsmember countries. i Policy,Research, and ExternalAffairs Debtand Inte;,iationalFinance WPS 749 'Ibijispaper - - a joint product ol tic Debt andi Internaitional Finance and International Trade Divisions, Inteniational Economics Departiicit - is part of a larger clfort in PRE to stu(y' the use of financial ins.ruilcints to mTanagc thc exictrnal exposures ol devcloping couIInties. Copies are ava&lable free from the World Bank, 1818 1I Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Sarah Lipscomb, room S7-062, cxtension 33718 (31 palges, wiih figoures and tables). Papua New Guinea faces substantial exposure to export earnings, short-tcrni hledging tools, such price Iluctuaitionis for its major ptiimalr) coiminocd- as options and lutures, could be used effectively.
    [Show full text]
  • Banking Across Borders: Are Chinese Banks Different?
    BIS Working Papers No 892 Banking Across Borders: Are Chinese Banks Different? By Eugenio Cerutti, Catherine Koch, and Swapan-Kumar Pradhan Monetary and Economic Department October 2020 JEL classification: F34, F36, F65, G21 Keywords: Cross-border banking, Chinese banks, Trade, FDI, Gravity model BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2020. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISSN 1682-7678 (online) Banking Across Borders: Are Chinese Banks Different? By Eugenio Cerutti, Catherine Koch, and Swapan-Kumar Pradhan1 October 14, 2020 Abstract We explore the global footprint of Chinese banks and compare it with that of other bank nationalities. Chinese banks have become the largest cross-border creditors for almost half of all emerging market and developing economies (EMDEs). Their global reach resembles that of banks from advanced economies (AEs). We take a nationality approach as international banks, and Chinese banks in particular, grant a substantial share of their cross-border loans from affiliates located abroad. But differences remain. Using a gravity model with a novel measure of distance capturing the role of foreign affiliates across all bank nationalities, we find that larger distances deter cross- border bank lending to EMDEs more than to AEs.
    [Show full text]
  • The Silicon Six
    The Silicon Six and their $100 billion global tax gap December 2019 © Fair Tax Mark 2019 About the Fair Tax Mark The Fair Tax Mark certification scheme was launched in - regulators, investors and municipalities across the UK in 2014, and seeks to encourage and recognise the globe have expressed a desire to support Fair organisations that pay the right amount of corporation tax Tax Mark accreditation (or equivalent) in their at the right time and in the right place. Tax contributions jurisdictions; are a key part of the wider social and economic contribution made by business, helping the communities - there is in many parts of the world an ongoing in which they operate to deliver valuable public services international race to the bottom on tax, and and build the infrastructure that paves the way for growth. this creates a downward pressure on standards everywhere (including in the UK); and More than fifty businesses have now been certified in the UK, including FTSE-listed PLCs, co-operatives, - if no action is taken by civil society, unscrupulous social enterprises and large private business – which accounting and auditing entities will step into the between them have over 7,000 offices and outlets. vacuum and propagate low-bar tax kitemarks. We operate as a not-for-profit social enterprise and believe that companies paying tax responsibly should Further information at: be celebrated, and any race to the bottom resisted. • Website: www.fairtaxmark.net To date, the Fair Tax Mark’s activities have been focused on the UK; however, a new suite of international • Phone: (within UK) 0161 7690427 / standards is now under development.
    [Show full text]
  • The Financialisation of Big Tech
    Engineering digital monopolies The financialisation of Big Tech Rodrigo Fernandez & Ilke Adriaans & Tobias J. Klinge & Reijer Hendrikse December 2020 Colophon Engineering digital monopolies The financialisation of Big Tech December 2020 Authors: Rodrigo Fernandez (SOMO), Ilke Editor: Marieke Krijnen Adriaans (SOMO), Tobias J. Klinge (KU Layout: Frans Schupp Leuven) and Reijer Hendrikse (VUB) Cover photo: Geralt/Pixabay With contributions from: ISBN: 978-94-6207-155-1 Manuel Aalbers and The Real Estate/ Financial Complex research group at KU Leuven, David Bassens, Roberta Cowan, Vincent Kiezebrink, Adam Leaver, Michiel van Meeteren, Jasper van Teffelen, Callum Ward Stichting Onderzoek Multinationale The Centre for Research on Multinational Ondernemingen Corporations (SOMO) is an independent, Centre for Research on Multinational not-for-profit research and network organi- Corporations sation working on social, ecological and economic issues related to sustainable Sarphatistraat 30 development. Since 1973, the organisation 1018 GL Amsterdam investigates multinational corporations The Netherlands and the consequences of their activities T: +31 (0)20 639 12 91 for people and the environment around F: +31 (0)20 639 13 21 the world. [email protected] www.somo.nl Made possible in collaboration with KU Leuven and Vrije Universiteit Brussel (VUB) with financial assistance from the Research Foundation Flanders (FWO), grant numbers G079718N and G004920N. The content of this publication is the sole responsibility of SOMO and can in no way be taken to reflect the views of any of the funders. Engineering digital monopolies The financialisation of Big Tech SOMO Rodrigo Fernandez, Ilke Adriaans, Tobias J. Klinge and Reijer Hendrikse Amsterdam, December 2020 Contents 1 Introduction ..........................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • International Banking and Prudential Spillovers. Some Evidence And
    International Banking and Prudential Spillovers. Some evidence and thoughts Stijn Claessens Head of Financial Stability Policy, Monetary and Economic Department Joint IBRN-IMF Conference The Transmission of Macro Prudential and Monetary Policies Across Borders Washington DC, Wednesday, April 19, 2017 Disclaimer: The opinions expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect views of the Bank for International Settlements. Outline of Presentation A. Many conceptual and empirical challenges on spillovers . Early for definitive conceptual framework, much to be done . With imperfect data (not granular enough), empirics hard B. Analyses on financial spillovers show much heterogeneity . Exposures of various flows to global factors vary . Foreign banks affect booms and busts in various ways C. Policies: macroprudential, including capital flows management . Need to be clear on why such prudential tools are needed . While spillovers can arise, whether they matter in what way is unclear. Policy advice may thus be at early days 2 A1. Many Conceptual Challenges “First best:” Perfect risk-sharing, but no “bad” spillovers . First best does not mean stable capital flows. And asset prices to reflect both local and international factors. But not excessive spillovers, limited regulatory arbitrage (?) Macroprudential (MAP) and capital flows management (CFM) policies can spillover in many ways: Q and P; direct, indirect But again need not all be adverse, ie, w/ negative externalities . Unclear as to which spillovers we need to worry about . Likely depends, in part, on: state of financial cycles in both countries; other financial frictions; ZLB/ELB; other tools; etc 3 A2. Many Empirical Challenges Hard to document spillovers as they arise in many ways .
    [Show full text]
  • Push Factors and Capital Flows to Emerging Markets: Why Knowing Your Lender Matters More Than Fundamentals
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Cerutti, Eugenio M.; Claessens, Stijn; Puy, Damien Working Paper Push factors and capital flows to emerging markets: Why knowing your lender matters more than fundamentals ADB Economics Working Paper Series, No. 528 Provided in Cooperation with: Asian Development Bank (ADB), Manila Suggested Citation: Cerutti, Eugenio M.; Claessens, Stijn; Puy, Damien (2017) : Push factors and capital flows to emerging markets: Why knowing your lender matters more than fundamentals, ADB Economics Working Paper Series, No. 528, Asian Development Bank (ADB), Manila, http://dx.doi.org/10.22617/WPS179146-2 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/203368 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]
  • Big Tech and Democracy: the Critical Role of Congress
    TECHNOLOGY AND PUBLIC PURPOSE PROJECT Big Tech and Democracy: The Critical Role of Congress Key Policy Considerations to Address Tech Platforms PAPER APRIL 2019 Technology and Public Purpose Project Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs Harvard Kennedy School 79 JFK Street Cambridge, MA 02138 www.belfercenter.org/TAPP Platform Accountability Project Shorenstein Center for Media, Politics and Public Policy Harvard Kennedy School 124 Mount Auburn Street, 2nd Floor, South Elevators Cambridge, MA 02138 www.shorensteincenter.org Statements and views expressed in this report are solely those of the authors and do not imply endorsement by Harvard University, Harvard Kennedy School, the Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs, or the Shorenstein Center for Media, Politics and Public Policy. Design and layout by Andrew Facini Cover photo: Adobe Stock Copyright 2019, President and Fellows of Harvard College Printed in the United States of America TECHNOLOGY AND PUBLIC PURPOSE PROJECT Big Tech and Democracy: The Critical Role of Congress Key Policy Considerations to Address Tech Platforms Bogdan Belei Bennett Craig Nicco Mele Toni Bush Daniel Gastfriend Hong Qu Maeve Campbell Dipayan Ghosh Amy Robinson Ash Carter Gene Kimmelman Philip Verveer Lucy Chase Heidi Legg Tom Wheeler Mignon Clyburn Laura Manley PAPER APRIL 2019 Co-Sponsoring Organizations The Technology and Public Purpose (TAPP) Project at the Harvard Kennedy School’s Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs works to ensure that emerging technologies are developed and managed in ways that serve the overall public good. Led by Belfer Center Director, MIT Innovation Fellow, and former Secretary of Defense Ash Carter, the TAPP Project leverages a network of experts from Harvard University, MIT, and Stanford, along with leaders in technology, government, and business.
    [Show full text]
  • Capital Flows to Central and Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Capital Flows and the Emerging Economies: Theory, Evidence, and Controversies Volume Author/Editor: Sebastian Edwards, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-18470-6 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/edwa00-1 Conference Date: February 20-21, 1998 Publication Date: January 2000 Chapter Title: Capital Flows to Central and Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union Chapter Authors: Stijn Claessens, Daniel Oks, Rossana Polastri Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c6171 Chapter pages in book: (p. 299 - 339) ~ Capital Flows to Central and Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union Stijn Claessens, Daniel Oks, and Rossana Polastri 9.1 Introduction and Background Capital flows to Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) and the former Soviet Union (FSU) represent a relatively small, albeit growing, share of capital flows to developing countries. Taking all flows together, total net flows to these twenty-five countries were about $44 billion in 1996 (and a preliminary figure of $57 billion for 1997),’ or about one-eighth of aggre- gate net flows to all developing countries. These countries accounted, how- ever, for about 20 and 22 percent, respectively, of all developing countries’ gross domestic product (GDP) and exports in 1996. As a fraction of their GDP, total inflows were consequently smaller than for many other devel- oping countries, and averaged about 5.4 percent over the 1990-96 period. Taking debt service and capital flight into account, resource inflows were much lower and even negative to some countries (capital flight from Rus- sia alone has been estimated at some $50 billion for 1992-96).
    [Show full text]
  • A Case Study by Manning & Napier
    Historical Impact of Regulation on Big Tech A Case Study by Manning & Napier Originally Published: January 2019 www.manning-napier.com Introduction After years of growth, the information technology sector is facing renewed regulatory scrutiny over its size and power. The inquiries have come at a time when the roles of privacy, fake news, and information bubbles are being challenged in our increasingly digital lives. While little has derailed the internet giants thus far, calls for government oversight are on the rise. With the immense scale and market power of these companies, we should expect regulatory scrutiny to be an ongoing issue. To better understand the consequences of ongoing regulatory scrutiny, Manning & Napier’s technology group looked at past tech industry leaders that faced similar bouts of government oversight, and analyzed the regulatory impact on historical stock performance. The Process In conducting the analysis, our team analyzed eight US-based technology companies that were dominant in their respective eras. Within the companies, we identified 54 discrete regulatory cases from 1900 through the present day1 . We built regulatory timelines for each case and measured the before and after stock price returns per case, per company. Additionally, among the identified cases that led to a significantly negative impact, we observed key warning signs. 2 www.manning-napier.com Key Takeaways The Companies Studied Regulatory scrutiny is usually a non-event. IBM • The vast majority of the tech companies IBM’s first brush with anti-trust scrutiny was reviewed posted strong absolute and relative in 1932. Then again in the 1950s. The famous returns well beyond their first brush with 1969 -1982 case was actually IBM’s third brush with regulators.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomic Implications of Financial Imperfections: a Survey
    BIS Working Papers No 677 Macroeconomic implications of financial imperfections: a survey by Stijn Claessens and M Ayhan Kose Monetary and Economic Department November 2017 JEL classification: D53, E21, E32, E44, E51, F36, F44, F65, G01, G10, G12, G14, G15, G21 Keywords: asset prices, balance sheets, credit, financial accelerator, financial intermediation, financial linkages, international linkages, leverage, liquidity, macrofinancial linkages, output, real-financial linkages BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2017. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISSN 1682-7678 (online) Macroeconomic implications of financial imperfections: a survey Stijn Claessens and M. Ayhan Kose Abstract This paper surveys the theoretical and empirical literature on the macroeconomic implications of financial imperfections. It focuses on two major channels through which financial imperfections can affect macroeconomic outcomes. The first channel, which operates through the demand side of finance and is captured by financial accelerator-type mechanisms, describes how changes in borrowers’ balance sheets can affect their access to finance and thereby amplify and propagate economic and financial shocks. The second channel, which is associated with the supply side of finance, emphasises the implications of changes in financial intermediaries’ balance sheets for the supply of credit, liquidity and asset prices, and, consequently, for macroeconomic outcomes.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Regulations for Improving Financial Inclusion a CGD Task Force Report
    Financial Regulations for Improving Financial Inclusion A CGD Task Force Report Chairs: Stijn Claessens Liliana Rojas-Suarez CENTER FOR GLOBAL DEVELOPMENT Financial Regulations for Improving Financial Inclusion A CGD Task Force Report Chairs: Stijn Claessens Liliana Rojas-Suarez c Center for Global Development. 2016. Some Rights Reserved. Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 3.0 Center for Global Development 2055 L Street NW, Floor 5 Washington DC 20036 www.cgdev.org ISBN 978-1-933286-96-9 Cover photos, clockwise from top left: c Erik Hersman, CC BY 2.0; Arne Hoel/World Bank, CC BY-NC-ND 2.0; Tim Moffatt, CC BY 2.0; Meena Kadri, CC BY-NC-ND 2.0. Editing, design, and production by Communications Development Incorporated, Washington, D.C. Task force members Chairs Stijn Claessens Liliana Rojas-Suarez Task force members Thorsten Beck,Professor, Cass Business School Massimo Cirasino, Head of the Payment Systems Development Group, World Bank Stijn Claessens, Senior Adviser, Federal Reserve Board Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, Director of Research, Development Research Group, World Bank Alan Gelb, Senior Fellow, Center for Global Development James Hanson, Former Senior Financial Policy Advisor, World Bank Ishrat Husain, Former Governor, Central Bank of Pakistan Ben Leo, Senior Fellow, Center for Global Development Nachiket Mor, Member of the Board, Reserve Bank of India Mark Napier, Director, Financial Sector Deepening (FSD), Africa Mthuli Ncube, Former Vice President, African Development Bank Njuguna Ndung’u, Former Governor, Central Bank of Kenya
    [Show full text]
  • Digital Trade Rules and Big Tech
    PUBLIC SERVICES INTERNATIONAL The global union federation of workers in public services ENGLISH Digital trade rules and big tech: SURRENDERING PUBLIC GOOD TO PRIVATE POWER CONTENTS Abbreviations Overview 1. KEY IMPACTS OF DIGITISATION ON PUBLIC SERVICES 2. BIG TECH’S ‘DIGITAL TRADE’ DEMANDS 3. DIGITISED HEALTHCARE 4. “SMART CITIES” 5. RECOMMENDATIONS References Digital trade rules and Big Tech: SURRENDERING PUBLIC GOOD TO PRIVATE POWER Written by Professor Jane Kelsey, Faculty of Law, The University of Auckland, New Zealand, with research support from Mary Ann Manahan, and peer reviewed by Dr Bill Rosenberg. © Public Services International February 2020 © Cover illustration Anthony Russo 2 DIGITAL TRADE RULES AND BIG TECH: ABBREVIATIONS AI Artificial intelligence AIIB Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank D2D Digital 2 Dozen principles FTA Free trade agreement GAFA Google, Amazon, Facebook, Apple GATS General Agreement on Trade in Services IoT Internet of Things IT Information technology PPP Public Private Partnerships R&D Research and development SOE State-owned enterprise SPV Special Purpose Vehicle TPPA Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement USTR United States Trade Representative WTO World Trade Organization SURRENDERING PUBLIC GOOD TO PRIVATE POWER 3 OVERVIEW ig Tech companies like Google, intelligence that does the work of doc- Amazon, Facebook and Apple – tors, technicians and prison officers. BGAFA for short - are using free Private contractors run the IT opera- trade agreements to protect them- tions and data bases of government selves from regulation. The idea of a agencies, storing our data on their own ‘free and open’ Internet sounds liberat- servers or in the ‘cloud’, which usually ing. But a world in which powerful and means they are controlled in the United unregulated private corporations con- States.
    [Show full text]