Digital Trade Rules and Big Tech

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Digital Trade Rules and Big Tech PUBLIC SERVICES INTERNATIONAL The global union federation of workers in public services ENGLISH Digital trade rules and big tech: SURRENDERING PUBLIC GOOD TO PRIVATE POWER CONTENTS Abbreviations Overview 1. KEY IMPACTS OF DIGITISATION ON PUBLIC SERVICES 2. BIG TECH’S ‘DIGITAL TRADE’ DEMANDS 3. DIGITISED HEALTHCARE 4. “SMART CITIES” 5. RECOMMENDATIONS References Digital trade rules and Big Tech: SURRENDERING PUBLIC GOOD TO PRIVATE POWER Written by Professor Jane Kelsey, Faculty of Law, The University of Auckland, New Zealand, with research support from Mary Ann Manahan, and peer reviewed by Dr Bill Rosenberg. © Public Services International February 2020 © Cover illustration Anthony Russo 2 DIGITAL TRADE RULES AND BIG TECH: ABBREVIATIONS AI Artificial intelligence AIIB Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank D2D Digital 2 Dozen principles FTA Free trade agreement GAFA Google, Amazon, Facebook, Apple GATS General Agreement on Trade in Services IoT Internet of Things IT Information technology PPP Public Private Partnerships R&D Research and development SOE State-owned enterprise SPV Special Purpose Vehicle TPPA Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement USTR United States Trade Representative WTO World Trade Organization SURRENDERING PUBLIC GOOD TO PRIVATE POWER 3 OVERVIEW ig Tech companies like Google, intelligence that does the work of doc- Amazon, Facebook and Apple – tors, technicians and prison officers. BGAFA for short - are using free Private contractors run the IT opera- trade agreements to protect them- tions and data bases of government selves from regulation. The idea of a agencies, storing our data on their own ‘free and open’ Internet sounds liberat- servers or in the ‘cloud’, which usually ing. But a world in which powerful and means they are controlled in the United unregulated private corporations con- States. This list expands every week, as trol the digital domain on which every- governments become more depend- one, from governments to families, ent on digital technologies and on the has come to depend is the ultimate in firms that control the information and privatisation systems that run them. Digital technologies are becoming ad- Every week, there is more evidence dictive. The Internet and its apps, social of how this power is being abused media, web searches, ride-shares and through tax evasion, breaches of hu- on-line market-places can now organise man rights by profiling of immigrants almost every aspect of our daily lives, and dissidents, and exploitating so- all seemingly for free. But every time called ‘self-employed’ workers. Big OVERVIEW we use them, we generate more data Tech show no sense of responsibility that allows the shadowy corporations or culpability for frauds on consumers, who control them to analyse our activ- mass breaches of data privacy, or even ities, opinions and friendships. Whether the online hosting of extremism and the it’s the US tech giants or their Chinese manipulation of democratic elections. counterparts of Baidu, WeChat, Alibaba and Tencent, this new generation of The last thing the state should be do- transnational corporations is reaching ing is surrendering its right to regulate ever-deeper into our lives. these technologies and their owners. Governments are in a perpetual state of Their power extends to the core of cen- catch-up, trying to understand and re- tral and local government and public spond to existing digital technologies services. They monitor our workplaces, and services only to see new, previous- streets and even devices in our homes, ly inconceivable ones emerge. There is and run our transport, telecommunica- currently very little regulation to control tions and energy infrastructure, some- these activities or hold the tech giants times from outside the country. They to account. Their global reach allows create the algorithms that decide who them to organise their corporate identi- gets a job or gets fired, is given a loan ties, locations and operations to bypass or enters university, and the artificial the limited laws and restrictions, and 4 DIGITAL TRADE RULES AND BIG TECH: tax obligations, that do exist. Big Tech wants to keep it that way. That is the purpose of the new rules on ‘electronic commerce’ or ‘digital trade’ that their governments are secur- ing for them through international free trade agreements. The Trans-Pacific Section Partnership Agreement (TPPA) set the Two se- ©The Conversation, template for later negotiations. Now lects a number of is- CC BY-NC there is pressure to adopt them in the sues of concern for PSI that are directly World Trade Organization (WTO) and ap- affected by the ‘trade’ rules: privatisa- ply them on a global scale. tion of public services, corporate con- trol, data, digital technologies, source These rules have been negotiated un- codes, public infrastructure, employ- der the radar. Governments seem be- ment, working conditions, unionisation, dazzled by unsubstantiated claims that public finance and social wellbeing. adopting them will bring new develop- The third section examines the impacts ment opportunities and potential cost in more detail with reference to health- savings, when in reality these rules are care and smart cities. The report con- designed to tie their hands. Few trade cludes with some recommendations. officials really understand the implica- tions of what they are negotiating. Few Hopefully, this will provide a platform people outside those negotiations have for PSI affiliates to mobilise your pow- been aware that these rules were being erful voices to stop the spread of the developed because of the secrecy that e-commerce rules, alongside other ne- screens them from public view. oliberal trade and investment rules, and demand a progressive, people-centred This report raises the alarm for pub- alternative. lic services unions in the Asia Pacific. These agreements will affect you in fundamental ways, as the public sec- tor workforce, as users of public ser- vices, and as citizens. The first section sets out the Tech lobby’s wish list and how that translated into the TPPA rules. SURRENDERING PUBLIC GOOD TO PRIVATE POWER 5 1. Key Impacts of Digitisation on Public Services heerleaders of the 4th industri- z Privatisation of public services: al revolution celebrate it as the The neoliberal market-driven agenda Cnext phase after the (failed) says the state should only do what neoliberal mode of financialised cap- the private sector can’t and what re- italism. Unions have recognised the mains in the public sphere should be potential benefits of a digitised econ- modelled on the private sector, in- omy, but only with a commitment to a cluding the drivers of efficiency, pro- just transition that protects the rights ductivity, labour replacement and of working people and enhances their lowering labour costs. At the same well-being1. That is not the present time, most governments claim an model. The current trajectory, fuelled ongoing commitment to improved by the new e-commerce or digital services to the public with public trade rules, will have a radical and dis- service at its core. There is an illu- ruptive impact on public services, on sion that digitisation enables a gov- public sector workers and unions, and ernment to do both. Where a gov- KEY IMPACTS OF DIGITISATION ON PUBLIC SERVICES on citizens, families and communities. ernment tries, and discovers it can’t, the ‘e-commerce’ trade rules will The recent report for PSI on disable the government from re-reg- Digitalisation and Public Services has ulating data, digital technologies and analysed these challenges in depth2. services in ways that prioritise the The following selection of issues pro- public interest. vides the framework for the case stud- ies in this report on healthcare and z Corporate control: Contracting ‘Smart Cities’. in and outsourcing are inevitable consequences of governments 6 DIGITAL TRADE RULES AND BIG TECH: © PSI 2017 committing to digitisation, because on servers. Often the data is stored they rarely have the capacity to do ‘in the cloud’, which means the the work themselves. The power servers are located in one or more relationship between the state and unspecified places, although they private corporations is turned on are usually controlled from the US. its head, as governments become If the government agency has not captive of the tech industry. If the been very specific in the contract e-commerce rules say the govern- about its data, it may have no con- ment can’t require a corporation pro- trol over what happens to it or even viding the service from offshore to rights to access it for research or have a local presence in the country, planning purposes. Once that data it forfeits even more control. Faced is out of government hands and held with unaffordable costs of new ser- offshore there is no guarantee that vices and upgrades, threatened or protections and obligations under actual exit by the foreign providers, national law will apply or be enforce- or technology or performance fail- able. The e-commerce trade rule will ure, governments have no capacity prevent them requiring the data to to step back in and resume control be held locally, rather than offshore. even if the rules let them. While that rule excludes data held or processed by or for a government, z Data: Control of data is the key to there are many loopholes, such as everything digital. Governments rely national or service-specific data on contractors to design, operate bases that non-government servic- and process personal data from pub- es providers also use. lic and social services, and store it SURRENDERING PUBLIC GOOD TO PRIVATE POWER 7 z Digital technology and source codes: failure, cyber-ransom or civil war, or if The source codes and algorithms that the contractor fails financially or to per- drive the government’s internal sys- form its legal obligations? The e-com- tems, or public services more gener- merce rules say governments can’t re- ally, are a black hole.
Recommended publications
  • The Silicon Six
    The Silicon Six and their $100 billion global tax gap December 2019 © Fair Tax Mark 2019 About the Fair Tax Mark The Fair Tax Mark certification scheme was launched in - regulators, investors and municipalities across the UK in 2014, and seeks to encourage and recognise the globe have expressed a desire to support Fair organisations that pay the right amount of corporation tax Tax Mark accreditation (or equivalent) in their at the right time and in the right place. Tax contributions jurisdictions; are a key part of the wider social and economic contribution made by business, helping the communities - there is in many parts of the world an ongoing in which they operate to deliver valuable public services international race to the bottom on tax, and and build the infrastructure that paves the way for growth. this creates a downward pressure on standards everywhere (including in the UK); and More than fifty businesses have now been certified in the UK, including FTSE-listed PLCs, co-operatives, - if no action is taken by civil society, unscrupulous social enterprises and large private business – which accounting and auditing entities will step into the between them have over 7,000 offices and outlets. vacuum and propagate low-bar tax kitemarks. We operate as a not-for-profit social enterprise and believe that companies paying tax responsibly should Further information at: be celebrated, and any race to the bottom resisted. • Website: www.fairtaxmark.net To date, the Fair Tax Mark’s activities have been focused on the UK; however, a new suite of international • Phone: (within UK) 0161 7690427 / standards is now under development.
    [Show full text]
  • The Financialisation of Big Tech
    Engineering digital monopolies The financialisation of Big Tech Rodrigo Fernandez & Ilke Adriaans & Tobias J. Klinge & Reijer Hendrikse December 2020 Colophon Engineering digital monopolies The financialisation of Big Tech December 2020 Authors: Rodrigo Fernandez (SOMO), Ilke Editor: Marieke Krijnen Adriaans (SOMO), Tobias J. Klinge (KU Layout: Frans Schupp Leuven) and Reijer Hendrikse (VUB) Cover photo: Geralt/Pixabay With contributions from: ISBN: 978-94-6207-155-1 Manuel Aalbers and The Real Estate/ Financial Complex research group at KU Leuven, David Bassens, Roberta Cowan, Vincent Kiezebrink, Adam Leaver, Michiel van Meeteren, Jasper van Teffelen, Callum Ward Stichting Onderzoek Multinationale The Centre for Research on Multinational Ondernemingen Corporations (SOMO) is an independent, Centre for Research on Multinational not-for-profit research and network organi- Corporations sation working on social, ecological and economic issues related to sustainable Sarphatistraat 30 development. Since 1973, the organisation 1018 GL Amsterdam investigates multinational corporations The Netherlands and the consequences of their activities T: +31 (0)20 639 12 91 for people and the environment around F: +31 (0)20 639 13 21 the world. [email protected] www.somo.nl Made possible in collaboration with KU Leuven and Vrije Universiteit Brussel (VUB) with financial assistance from the Research Foundation Flanders (FWO), grant numbers G079718N and G004920N. The content of this publication is the sole responsibility of SOMO and can in no way be taken to reflect the views of any of the funders. Engineering digital monopolies The financialisation of Big Tech SOMO Rodrigo Fernandez, Ilke Adriaans, Tobias J. Klinge and Reijer Hendrikse Amsterdam, December 2020 Contents 1 Introduction ..........................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Big Tech and Democracy: the Critical Role of Congress
    TECHNOLOGY AND PUBLIC PURPOSE PROJECT Big Tech and Democracy: The Critical Role of Congress Key Policy Considerations to Address Tech Platforms PAPER APRIL 2019 Technology and Public Purpose Project Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs Harvard Kennedy School 79 JFK Street Cambridge, MA 02138 www.belfercenter.org/TAPP Platform Accountability Project Shorenstein Center for Media, Politics and Public Policy Harvard Kennedy School 124 Mount Auburn Street, 2nd Floor, South Elevators Cambridge, MA 02138 www.shorensteincenter.org Statements and views expressed in this report are solely those of the authors and do not imply endorsement by Harvard University, Harvard Kennedy School, the Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs, or the Shorenstein Center for Media, Politics and Public Policy. Design and layout by Andrew Facini Cover photo: Adobe Stock Copyright 2019, President and Fellows of Harvard College Printed in the United States of America TECHNOLOGY AND PUBLIC PURPOSE PROJECT Big Tech and Democracy: The Critical Role of Congress Key Policy Considerations to Address Tech Platforms Bogdan Belei Bennett Craig Nicco Mele Toni Bush Daniel Gastfriend Hong Qu Maeve Campbell Dipayan Ghosh Amy Robinson Ash Carter Gene Kimmelman Philip Verveer Lucy Chase Heidi Legg Tom Wheeler Mignon Clyburn Laura Manley PAPER APRIL 2019 Co-Sponsoring Organizations The Technology and Public Purpose (TAPP) Project at the Harvard Kennedy School’s Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs works to ensure that emerging technologies are developed and managed in ways that serve the overall public good. Led by Belfer Center Director, MIT Innovation Fellow, and former Secretary of Defense Ash Carter, the TAPP Project leverages a network of experts from Harvard University, MIT, and Stanford, along with leaders in technology, government, and business.
    [Show full text]
  • A Case Study by Manning & Napier
    Historical Impact of Regulation on Big Tech A Case Study by Manning & Napier Originally Published: January 2019 www.manning-napier.com Introduction After years of growth, the information technology sector is facing renewed regulatory scrutiny over its size and power. The inquiries have come at a time when the roles of privacy, fake news, and information bubbles are being challenged in our increasingly digital lives. While little has derailed the internet giants thus far, calls for government oversight are on the rise. With the immense scale and market power of these companies, we should expect regulatory scrutiny to be an ongoing issue. To better understand the consequences of ongoing regulatory scrutiny, Manning & Napier’s technology group looked at past tech industry leaders that faced similar bouts of government oversight, and analyzed the regulatory impact on historical stock performance. The Process In conducting the analysis, our team analyzed eight US-based technology companies that were dominant in their respective eras. Within the companies, we identified 54 discrete regulatory cases from 1900 through the present day1 . We built regulatory timelines for each case and measured the before and after stock price returns per case, per company. Additionally, among the identified cases that led to a significantly negative impact, we observed key warning signs. 2 www.manning-napier.com Key Takeaways The Companies Studied Regulatory scrutiny is usually a non-event. IBM • The vast majority of the tech companies IBM’s first brush with anti-trust scrutiny was reviewed posted strong absolute and relative in 1932. Then again in the 1950s. The famous returns well beyond their first brush with 1969 -1982 case was actually IBM’s third brush with regulators.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust in Times of Information Technology: an Analysis of Big Tech Monopoly Cases
    University of Denver Digital Commons @ DU Electronic Theses and Dissertations Graduate Studies 2020 Antitrust in Times of Information Technology: An Analysis of Big Tech Monopoly Cases Shamayeta Rahman Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.du.edu/etd Part of the History of Science, Technology, and Medicine Commons, Other Economics Commons, and the Science and Technology Law Commons Antitrust in Times of Information Technology: An Analysis of Big Tech Monopoly Cases ___________ A Thesis Presented To the Faculty of the College of Arts, Humanities and Social Sciences University of Denver ___________ In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Master of Arts ___________ by Shamayeta Rahman March 2020 Advisor: Yavuz Yașar © Copyright by Shamayeta Rahman 2020 All Rights Reserved Author: Shamayeta Rahman Title: Antitrust in Times of Information Technology: An Analysis of Big Tech Monopoly Cases Advisor: Yavuz Yașar Degree Date: March 2020 Abstract The information technology industry is one of the most rapidly growing yet concentrated markets existing today. Big Tech monopolies and their increasingly anticompetitive behavior posits risks for competition, technological innovation and consumer welfare. This ranges from price discrimination, limiting consumer choices to the unethical use of data. The particular nature of information technology, with its network effects and negligible marginal costs, incentivizes and facilitates predatory market practices making antitrust analysis in this industry extremely complex.
    [Show full text]
  • The Record of Weak U.S. Merger Enforcement in Big Tech
    The Record of Weak U.S. Merger Enforcement in Big Tech Diana L. Moss1 July 8, 2019 “As the pace of innovation accelerates, and top talent joins startups rather than large companies, startups might become threats faster than you can buy them.” – John Chambers, Chairman Emeritus, Cisco, 20182 I. Introduction The term “Big Tech” is often used to describe the five largest multinational online service or computer hardware and software companies: Amazon, Apple, Facebook, Google, and Microsoft. These companies hold five of the top six slots, by market value, for publicly traded firms.3 The growth of Big Tech over the past three decades is a function of numerous forces. These range from economic phenomena such as network effects and winner-take-all markets, organic growth resulting from innovative business models and technologies, to expansion through a series of acquisitions of smaller, potential, or nascent rivals. While Big Tech has undoubtedly produced benefits, significant concerns have coalesced around it. The growth of Big Tech has created controversy over the companies’ role in our society and raised a suite of competition issues that are attracting attention from Congress and enforcers.4 These include effects on innovation and market entry; incentives to compete 1 Diana L. Moss is President, American Antitrust Institute (AAI). The AAI is an independent non- profit education, research and advocacy organization. Its mission is to advance the role of competition in the economy, protect consumers, and sustain the vitality of the antitrust laws. For more information, see www.antitrustinstitute.org. AAI is a frequent commenter on proposed mergers, has testified numerous times before Congress, in federal court, and before state regulatory commissions on the likely effects of proposed mergers.
    [Show full text]
  • Competing with Big Tech
    COMPETING ABOUT WITH BIG TECH: LINEUP SYSTEMS Lineup Systems caters to many of the biggest, most 4 STRATEGIES TO WIN MORE SALES iconic and innovative media organizations in the world. Our first-of-its-kind media he relationship between Google and results is now increasingly taken up by links sales solution, Adpoint, is T news media publishers has historically to Google-owned platforms like YouTube, credited with transforming media companies by helping been symbiotic: publishers allow Google to and paid ads take up most of the space to increase revenue, improve aggregate their content for free and in “above the fold,” pushing organic results productivity and reduce costs. exchange, Google makes that content further down the screen. Additionally, Adpoint combines order accessible to the billions of people using Google has started to publish snippets from management with a media- the search engine every day, also for free. news stories directly at the top of search focused CRM, finance and analytics suite. No more In return, Google gets usage and clicks on results, diverting traffic and ad revenue “swivel chair syndrome” — paid ads adjacent to its search results, and from the news publishers. instead, manage your ad news publishers get traffic and, by proxy, All this adds up to the potential for Big sales from lead to billing from one easy-to-use, clicks to their advertisers’ websites. Tech to manipulate ad buyers who base customizable solution. But over the past decade, this relation- their strategies and budgets on certain ship between publishers and the search expectations, only to have the platforms platform has evolved into a vicious cycle.
    [Show full text]
  • Big Food, Big Tech, and the Global Childhood Obesity Pandemic
    Big Food, Big Tech, and the Global Childhood Obesity Pandemic AUTHORS: Jeff Chester, MSW Kathryn C. Montgomery, PhD MAY 2021 Katharina Kopp, PhD Big Food, Big Tech, and the Global Childhood Obesity Pandemic | 2 Acknowledgments This report is part of a unique partnership of four organizations—Berkeley Media Studies Group, Color of Change, UnidosUS, and Center for Digital Democracy—working together to promote policies to ensure health equity for youth, communities of color, and other at-risk populations. The partnership is funded through a generous grant from the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation, which has also supported CDD’s ongoing research to investigate how contemporary digital marketing and Big Data practices impact young people’s health. We are very grateful to the Foundation’s commitment to these efforts. We also want to thank the following individuals and organizations who helped us with the writing and publication of the report: Jamie Bussel, Lori Dorfman, Gary O. Larson, and Burness Communications. Big Food, Big Tech, and the Global Childhood Obesity Pandemic INTRODUCTION | 3 INTRODUCTION devastating. For decades, there has been a steady and disturbing rise in The coronavirus pandemic triggered a dramatic obesity among children and youth. For example, obesity rates among increase in online use. With tens of millions of families teens ages 12 to 19 have quadrupled remaining in their homes, people turned to the internet since the 1980s. According to the most recent public health data, 19.3 to order food, stay up with the fast-breaking news, percent of all youth between the ages and engage with family and friends.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Enforcement and Big Tech: After the Remedy Is Ordered
    ARTICLE Antitrust Enforcement and Big Tech: After the Remedy Is Ordered Jay L. Himes,* Jason Nieh,** & Ron Schnell*** Abstract. Each of us—one an attorney and the other two software experts—has substantial experience monitoring the implementation of court-ordered remedies in two leading hi-tech cases: United States v. Microsoft Corp. and United States v. Bazaarvoice, Inc. We discuss challenges that attorney and expert monitors confront in overseeing company compliance with antitrust remedial decrees in cases against hi-tech companies. We first summarize the legal principles applicable to antitrust remedies. Thereafter, we discuss oversight in the Microsoft and Bazaarvoice cases. Finally, we offer takeaways on effective antitrust decree monitoring. Two takeaways are particularly noteworthy. First, expect the unexpected. During monitoring oversight, implementing the court decree’s relatively general relief provisions will likely uncover unanticipated issues that prove challenging to resolve and may often require hi-tech expertise to do so. Second—and relatedly— be skeptical of company resistance. Court-ordered relief is unlikely to align with company business interests; if it did, the company probably would have adopted the practice without being ordered to do so. Accordingly, company incentives probably will militate toward a cramped view of decree implementation. Monitors therefore should refrain from taking company protestations at face value and should be prepared to leverage hi-tech expertise to probe company systems, data, and personnel for verification or refutation of company positions. Finally, with artificial intelligence and computational law (including antitrust) continuing to develop, we call attention to opportunities to use computer-automated processes to inform compliance oversight.
    [Show full text]
  • The Promise and Peril of Big Tech in India
    TANDEM RESEARCH | JULY 2020 A Balancing Act The Promise and Peril of Big Tech in India # Authors Acknowledgements Urvashi Aneja & Angelina Chamuah We would like to thank Omidyar Network India for their support. Akshat Jain and Subhashish With inputs from Bhadra, in particular, provided invaluable support Harsh Ghildiyal & Joanne D’Cunha and guidance. We would also like to thank all our interviewees and workshop attendees for their Design time and insights. A big thanks to the Tandem LMNO Design (www.lmno.in) team, particularly Harsh Ghildiyal and Joanne D’Cunha, as well as Abishek Reddy and Anushree Aneja.U, & Chamuah, A (2020). Gupta. Any errors or omissions are our own. A Balancing Act: The Promise & Peril of Big Tech in India. Tandem Research. Copyright ©Tandem Research 2020 # Abbreviations 04 4 How is Big Tech transforming India? 42 Prologue: Why we 4.1 Market Power wrote this report 05 4.2 Informational Gateway 4.3 Privacy 4.4 Sovereign Interests Executive Summary 06 ••• Is there an Indian Big Tech? 1 Varied and Evolving Contexts 18 5 Policy Pathways for India 58 5.1 Market Power 5.2 Informational Gateway 5.3 Privacy 5.4 Sovereign Interests 2 What is Big Tech? 5.5 A Graded Approach to Regulation 5.6 Conclusion: Principles for Competing Values Four Conceptual Markers 20 2.1 Data-centric Models 2.2 Network Effects 2.3 Infrastructural Role 2.4 Civic Function 6 Epilogue: The Covid-19 2.5 Cyclical Relationship of Conceptual Markers moment for Big Tech 78 3 Who are the key Big Tech Glossary 82 players in India? 32 82 3.1 Big Tech market
    [Show full text]
  • Technology Giants the “Moligopoly” Hypothesis and Holistic Competition
    Work in progress, 20 October 2016. TECHNOLOGY GIANTS, THE “MOLIGOPOLY” HYPOTHESIS AND HOLISTIC COMPETITION: A PRIMER Nicolas Petit* INTRODUCTION This paper originates from a disconnect. On the one hand, technology pundits daily describe the information and communications technologies giants (the “technology giants” or the “tech giants”) as oligopoly firms at war with each other. In 2012, Farhad Manjoo wrote in Fast Company a column entitled “The Great Tech War of 2012: Apple, Facebook, Google, and Amazon Battle for the Future of the Innovation Economy”.1 A year later, Manjoo inaugured in Slate a fictional dialogue with Matt Yglesias entitled “WarGames: Google vs. Apple” with the following sub-narrative “what would happen if the world’s two great powers went to (actual) war”.2 Their fictional conversation closed with Microsoft Bing becoming the default search engine in the US. On the other hand, antitrust lawyers and economists tend to classify the technology giants as entrenched monopolists, shielded from competition. In 2010, Columbia Law School Professor Tim Wu concluded an op-ed titled “In the Grip of the New Monopolists” in the Wall Street Journal with the following statement “let's not pretend that we live in anything but an age of monopolies”.3 Since then, not a year has passed without a major antitrust jurisdiction levelling monopolization concerns against companies like Google, Amazon, Microsoft, Apple or Facebook (hereafter, “GAFAM”).4 * Professor, University of Liege (ULg), Belgium. [email protected]. This study has benefited from no funding. I wish to express my gratitude to Jorge Marcos Ramos for excellent research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • American Tech Giants Are Fiercely Competitive Monopolies
    ESB Market power ESB Market power DESIGN American tech giants are fiercely competitive monopolies In virtually every country, antitrust agencies and regulators support the moligopoly hypothesis. They offer a new characterize US tech giants as monopolists. The press now picture of the FAANG firms’ competition. One in which each FAANG takes competition from other refers to them as ‘big tech’, the ‘frightful 5’, or FAANGs FAANGs, non-FAANGs (like AT&T, DELL, IBM (for Facebook, Apple, Amazon, Netflix and Google). Do and Oracle), foreign tech firms (like Spotify, Baidu and Tencent), and related companies (like Facebook versus they deserve to be vilified as monopolists regulated like Instagram or Google Maps versus Google Waze). Once public utilities or even broken up? this is understood, it is possible to see a lot of variations across FAANGs, and doubts that one-size-fits-all regu- latory proposals are in order. NICOLAS PETIT ntitrust and regulatory agencies say THE NATURE OF MOLIGOPOLY COMPETITION Professor at the FAANGs are monopolies. Other obser- How do moligopolists actually compete, is the next University of vers, including FAANGs themselves, logical question. The data, again, suggests that FAAN- Liege, Belgium, and consider digital markets as intensely com- Gs display four features, though there are significant Research Fellow at Apetitive. What if both were right? This intuition, which discrepancies at firm level. Stanford University I present in Petit (2016) and discuss in a forthcoming First, FAANGs are conglomerates. All have a book is what I call the moligopoly hypothesis. This is core business: Apple in hardware, Amazon in online the idea that FAANGs – or perhaps just a few of them, retail, and Google in search engines.
    [Show full text]