Campos V. Ticketmaster Corp., 140 F.3D 1166 (1998) 1998-1 Trade Cases P 72,112

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Campos V. Ticketmaster Corp., 140 F.3D 1166 (1998) 1998-1 Trade Cases P 72,112 Campos v. Ticketmaster Corp., 140 F.3d 1166 (1998) 1998-1 Trade Cases P 72,112 Decided April 10, 1998. KeyCite Yellow Flag - Negative Treatment Buyers of tickets to large-scale popular music concerts Declined to Extend by Dickson v. Microsoft Corp., 4th Cir.(Md.), brought antitrust action under Clayton Act against October 28, 2002 alleged monopoly supplier of ticket distribution services. 140 F.3d 1166 The United States District Court for the Eastern District United States Court of Appeals, of Missouri, Stephen Limbaugh, J., dismissed action on Eighth Circuit. standing grounds, and buyers appealed. The Court of Appeals, Melloy, Chief District Judge, held that: (1) Alex CAMPOS; Dania Campos; Albert Alfonso, buyers were indirect purchasers and did not have standing Individually and on behalf of all others to sue supplier for money damages under Clayton Act; (2) similarly situated; Plaintiffs/Appellants, buyers had antitrust standing to seek injunctive relief; and v. (3) affidavit of supplier's officer was insufficient to show TICKETMASTER CORPORATION; that supplier did not transact business in states in which Defendant/Appellee. its subsidiaries were located, for purposes of Clayton Act's Stephen HINES; Dirk Schnable; Todd venue provision. Vicsik; Jamie Saltzman; Mike Ellis; Brad Cheskes; Suzanne Crawford, on behalf of Affirmed in part, reversed in part, and remanded. themselves and on behalf of a class of persons Morris Sheppard Arnold, Circuit Judge, filed dissenting similarly situated; Plaintiffs/Appellants, opinion. v. TICKETMASTER CORPORATION; Defendant/Appellee. Joseph CROWLEY, Individually and on behalf of West Headnotes (12) all others similarly situated; Plaintiff/Appellant, v. [1] Antitrust and Trade Regulation TICKETMASTER CORPORATION; Indirect purchasers Defendant/Appellee. Antitrust and Trade Regulation Tony STEPHENS, Individually and on behalf of Persons liable all others similarly situated; Plaintiff/Appellant, An “indirect purchaser” is one who bears v. some portion of a monopoly overcharge TICKETMASTER CORPORATION; only by virtue of an antecedent transaction Defendant/Appellee. between the monopolist and another, Ebon PETTY; Arlean Azzo; John Azzo; Scott independent purchaser. Clayton Act, § 4, 15 Henry Buettner; Scott J. Freedland; Brian Homer; U.S.C.A. § 15. Roger Hutton; Garrett Pfetzing; Christopher W. 7 Cases that cite this headnote Quinn; Thomas Rockov; James Stewart; Hilary Tompkins, on behalf of themselves and others, [2] Antitrust and Trade Regulation in a class to be certified; Plaintiffs/Appellants, Indirect purchasers v. Indirect purchasers who bear some portion TICKETMASTER CORPORATION; of a monopoly overcharge only by virtue Defendant/Appellee. of an antecedent transaction between No. 96–2883. the monopolist and another, independent | purchaser may not sue under Clayton Act Submitted Feb. 14, 1997. to recover damages for the portion of the | overcharge they bear; the right to sue for damages rests with the direct purchasers, who © 2017 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 1 Campos v. Ticketmaster Corp., 140 F.3d 1166 (1998) 1998-1 Trade Cases P 72,112 participate in the antecedent transaction with services had antitrust standing to seek the monopolist. Clayton Act, § 4, 15 U.S.C.A. injunctive relief under Clayton Act, although § 15. they were indirect purchasers of supplier's services; all buyers claimed to have purchased 10 Cases that cite this headnote tickets through supplier and to have paid monopolistic service fees. Clayton Act, § 5, 15 [3] Antitrust and Trade Regulation U.S.C.A. § 16. Indirect purchasers 20 Cases that cite this headnote In Eighth Circuit, an antitrust plaintiff cannot avoid the Illinois Brick direct purchaser rule by characterizing a direct purchaser as a party [7] Antitrust and Trade Regulation to the antitrust violation, unless the direct Venue purchaser is joined as a defendant. Clayton When venue is asserted over a parent Act, § 4, 15 U.S.C.A. § 15. corporation on the basis of a subsidiary's business activities, the question is whether 9 Cases that cite this headnote the parent exercises sufficient control over its subsidiary to cause the parent to transact [4] Federal Courts business in the judicial district within the Proceedings by transferee court; special venue provision of the Clayton Act. improper change Clayton Act, § 12, 15 U.S.C.A. § 22. Consolidated antitrust cases were controlled Cases that cite this headnote by the law of circuit into which they were transferred, rather than that of the various circuits in which they were first filed. [8] Antitrust and Trade Regulation Venue 11 Cases that cite this headnote Sufficient control over the operations of a subsidiary renders the subsidiary [5] Antitrust and Trade Regulation the instrument, rather than merely the Indirect purchasers investment, of the parent, and supports the conclusion that the parent is transacting Buyers of tickets to large-scale popular music business in a district for purposes of the concerts that were distributed by alleged Clayton Act's venue provision, despite the monopoly supplier of ticket distribution formal separation of corporate entities. services were indirect purchasers and did Clayton Act, § 12, 15 U.S.C.A. § 22. not have standing to sue supplier for money damages under Clayton Act; buyers Cases that cite this headnote purchased supplier's services only because concert venues were required to buy those services first as alleged result of supplier's [9] Antitrust and Trade Regulation long term exclusive contracts with concert Venue promoters. Clayton Act, § 4, 15 U.S.C.A. § 15. Sufficient control necessary for parent corporation to transact business in 6 Cases that cite this headnote subsidiary's district under Clayton Act's venue provision does not require that the subsidiary [6] Antitrust and Trade Regulation be controlled to an ultimate degree by its Consumers parent, although something more than mere passive investment by the parent is required. Buyers of tickets to large-scale popular music Clayton Act, § 12, 15 U.S.C.A. § 22. concerts that were distributed by alleged monopoly supplier of ticket distribution © 2017 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 2 Campos v. Ticketmaster Corp., 140 F.3d 1166 (1998) 1998-1 Trade Cases P 72,112 Cases that cite this headnote Attorneys and Law Firms *1168 George W.Sampson, Seattle, WA, argued (Steve [10] Antitrust and Trade Regulation W. Berman, Seattle, WA, on the brief), for Plaintiffs/ Venue Appellants. Parent must have and exercise control and direction over the affairs of its subsidiary in Phil C. Neal, Chicago, IL, argued (James K. Gardner, order for venue in subsidiary's district to be Charles Evans Gerber, Chicago, IL, Francis P. Barron, proper under Clayton Act. Clayton Act, § 12, New York City, David W. Harlan, Michael A. Kahn, St. 15 U.S.C.A. § 22. Louis, MO, on the brief), for Defendant/Appellee. Cases that cite this headnote Before HANSEN and MORRIS SHEPPARD ARNOLD, Circuit Judges, and MELLOY, 1 Chief District Judge. [11] Antitrust and Trade Regulation Venue Opinion Day-to-day control of the activities of the subsidiary is not required in order for a parent MELLOY, Chief District Judge. corporation to be carrying on business of The plaintiffs, individually and as a proposed class any substantial character within a judicial of popular music fans, sued Ticketmaster Corporation district, for purposes of Clayton Act's venue (“Ticketmaster”) for damages and injunctive relief. provision; it is enough if the parent exercises Sixteen cases, originally filed in various districts, were continuing supervision of and intervention consolidated for pretrial proceedings in the Eastern in the subsidiaries' affairs, especially if the District of Missouri. Eleven of the cases were dismissed. parent exercises its ability to influence major The plaintiffs in the remaining five cases then filed decisions of the subsidiary which lead or a consolidated complaint superseding the individual could lead to violations of the antitrust laws. complaints. The consolidated complaint alleged that Clayton Act, § 12, 15 U.S.C.A. § 22. Ticketmaster violated § 1 of the Sherman Act by engaging 2 Cases that cite this headnote in price fixing with various concert venues and promoters and by boycotting the band Pearl Jam; that Ticketmaster violated § 2 of the Sherman Act by monopolizing, [12] Antitrust and Trade Regulation or attempting to monopolize, the market for ticket Venue distribution services; and that Ticketmaster violated § 7 Affidavit of corporation's officer that of the Clayton Act by acquiring its competitors. See 15 corporation owned no property and had no U.S.C. § 1 et seq. The plaintiffs claimed standing to sue offices in states in which its subsidiaries were based on their payment of monopoly overcharges, in the located and that all day-to-day operations form of service and handling fees, for Ticketmaster's ticket of subsidiaries were under control of distribution services. subsidiaries' officers was insufficient to show that corporation did not transact business The district court dismissed the suit, holding that the in those states for purposes of Clayton plaintiffs lacked standing to sue because they were indirect Act's venue provision. Clayton Act, § 12, 15 purchasers within the meaning of Illinois Brick Co. v. U.S.C.A. § 22. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 97 S.Ct. 2061, 52 L.Ed.2d 707 (1977) and its progeny. The district court also held Cases that cite this headnote that, even if the plaintiffs were not indirect purchasers, they were nevertheless inappropriate plaintiffs under the standards set forth by the Supreme Court in Associated General Contractors of California, Inc. v. California State Council of Carpenters, 459 U.S. 519, 103 S.Ct. 897, 74 © 2017 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 3 Campos v. Ticketmaster Corp., 140 F.3d 1166 (1998) 1998-1 Trade Cases P 72,112 L.Ed.2d 723 (1983). Finally, the district court held that plaintiffs contend that they suffer injury to their property three of the consolidated cases had been improperly within the meaning of Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 15 venued, and dismissed the cases originally filed in Georgia, U.S.C.
Recommended publications
  • Microeconomics Exam Review Chapters 8 Through 12, 16, 17 and 19
    MICROECONOMICS EXAM REVIEW CHAPTERS 8 THROUGH 12, 16, 17 AND 19 Key Terms and Concepts to Know CHAPTER 8 - PERFECT COMPETITION I. An Introduction to Perfect Competition A. Perfectly Competitive Market Structure: • Has many buyers and sellers. • Sells a commodity or standardized product. • Has buyers and sellers who are fully informed. • Has firms and resources that are freely mobile. • Perfectly competitive firm is a price taker; one firm has no control over price. B. Demand Under Perfect Competition: Horizontal line at the market price II. Short-Run Profit Maximization A. Total Revenue Minus Total Cost: The firm maximizes economic profit by finding the quantity at which total revenue exceeds total cost by the greatest amount. B. Marginal Revenue Equals Marginal Cost in Equilibrium • Marginal Revenue: The change in total revenue from selling another unit of output: • MR = ΔTR/Δq • In perfect competition, marginal revenue equals market price. • Market price = Marginal revenue = Average revenue • The firm increases output as long as marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost. • Golden rule of profit maximization. The firm maximizes profit by producing where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. C. Economic Profit in Short-Run: Because the marginal revenue curve is horizontal at the market price, it is also the firm’s demand curve. The firm can sell any quantity at this price. III. Minimizing Short-Run Losses The short run is defined as a period too short to allow existing firms to leave the industry. The following is a summary of short-run behavior: A. Fixed Costs and Minimizing Losses: If a firm shuts down, it must still pay fixed costs.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Bertrand Model
    ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1 Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition Both the monopoly and the perfectly competitive market structure has in common is that neither has to concern itself with the strategic choices of its competition. In the former, this is trivially true since there isn't any competition. While the latter is so insignificant that the single firm has no effect. In an oligopoly where there is more than one firm, and yet because the number of firms are small, they each have to consider what the other does. Consider the product launch decision, and pricing decision of Apple in relation to the IPOD models. If the features of the models it has in the line up is similar to Creative Technology's, it would have to be concerned with the pricing decision, and the timing of its announcement in relation to that of the other firm. We will now begin the exposition of Oligopolistic Competition. 1 Bertrand Model Firms can compete on several variables, and levels, for example, they can compete based on their choices of prices, quantity, and quality. The most basic and funda- mental competition pertains to pricing choices. The Bertrand Model is examines the interdependence between rivals' decisions in terms of pricing decisions. The assumptions of the model are: 1. 2 firms in the market, i 2 f1; 2g. 2. Goods produced are homogenous, ) products are perfect substitutes. 3. Firms set prices simultaneously. 4. Each firm has the same constant marginal cost of c. What is the equilibrium, or best strategy of each firm? The answer is that both firms will set the same prices, p1 = p2 = p, and that it will be equal to the marginal ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 2 cost, in other words, the perfectly competitive outcome.
    [Show full text]
  • Amazon's Antitrust Paradox
    LINA M. KHAN Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox abstract. Amazon is the titan of twenty-first century commerce. In addition to being a re- tailer, it is now a marketing platform, a delivery and logistics network, a payment service, a credit lender, an auction house, a major book publisher, a producer of television and films, a fashion designer, a hardware manufacturer, and a leading host of cloud server space. Although Amazon has clocked staggering growth, it generates meager profits, choosing to price below-cost and ex- pand widely instead. Through this strategy, the company has positioned itself at the center of e- commerce and now serves as essential infrastructure for a host of other businesses that depend upon it. Elements of the firm’s structure and conduct pose anticompetitive concerns—yet it has escaped antitrust scrutiny. This Note argues that the current framework in antitrust—specifically its pegging competi- tion to “consumer welfare,” defined as short-term price effects—is unequipped to capture the ar- chitecture of market power in the modern economy. We cannot cognize the potential harms to competition posed by Amazon’s dominance if we measure competition primarily through price and output. Specifically, current doctrine underappreciates the risk of predatory pricing and how integration across distinct business lines may prove anticompetitive. These concerns are height- ened in the context of online platforms for two reasons. First, the economics of platform markets create incentives for a company to pursue growth over profits, a strategy that investors have re- warded. Under these conditions, predatory pricing becomes highly rational—even as existing doctrine treats it as irrational and therefore implausible.
    [Show full text]
  • Apple and Amazon's Antitrust Antics
    APPLE AND AMAZON’S ANTITRUST ANTICS: TWO WRONGS DON’T MAKE A RIGHT, BUT MAYBE THEY SHOULD Kerry Gutknecht‡ I. INTRODUCTION The exploding market for books of all kinds in the form of digital files (“e- books”), which can be read on mobile devices and personal computers, has attracted aggressive competition between the two leading online e-book retail- ers, Amazon, Inc. (“Amazon”) and Apple Inc. (“Apple”).1 While both Amazon and Apple have been accused by critics of engaging in anticompetitive practic- es with regard to e-book sales,2 the U.S. Department of Justice has focused on Apple. In 2012, federal prosecutors brought an antitrust suit against Apple and five of the nation’s largest book publishers—HarperCollins Publishers LLC (“HarperCollins”), Hachette Book Group, Inc. and Hachette Digital (“Hachette”); Holtzbrinck Publishers, LLC d/b/a Macmillan (“Macmillan”); Penguin Group (USA), Inc. (“Penguin”); and Simon & Schuster, Inc. and (“Simon & Schuster”) (collectively, the “Publisher Defendants”)3—for collud- ing in violation of the Sherman Act to raise the retail prices of e-books.4 Each ‡ J.D. Candidate, May 2014, The Catholic University of America, Columbus School of Law. The author would like to thank Calla Brown for her daily support and the CommLaw Conspectus staff for their diligent effort during the writing and editing process. Finally, a special thanks to Antonio F. Perez for providing expert advice during the writing of this paper. 1 Complaint at 2–3, United States v. Apple Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638 (S.D.N.Y. 2013) (No. 12 CV 2826) [hereinafter Complaint].
    [Show full text]
  • The Marginal Cost Controversy in Intellectual Property John F Duffyt
    The Marginal Cost Controversy in Intellectual Property John F Duffyt In 1938, Harold Hotelling formally advanced the position that "the optimum of the general welfare corresponds to the sale of everything at marginal cost."' To reach this optimum, Hotelling argued, general gov- ernment revenues should "be applied to cover the fixed costs of electric power plants, waterworks, railroad, and other industries in which the fixed costs are large, so as to reduce to the level of marginal cost the prices charged for the services and products of these industries."2 Other major economists of the day subsequently endorsed Hotelling's view' and, in the late 1930s and early 1940s, it "aroused considerable interest and [had] al- ready found its way into some textbooks on public utility economics."' In his 1946 article, The MarginalCost Controversy,Ronald Coase set forth a detailed rejoinder to the Hotelling thesis, concluding that the social subsidies proposed by Hotelling "would bring about a maldistribu- tion of the factors of production, a maldistribution of income and proba- bly a loss similar to that which the scheme was designed to avoid."' The article, which Richard Posner would later hail as Coase's "most impor- tant" contribution to the field of public utility pricing,6 was part of a wave of literature debating the merits of the Hotelling proposal.' Yet the very success of the critique by Coase and others has led to the entire contro- t Professor of Law, George Washington University Law School. The author thanks Michael Abramowicz. Richard Hynes, Eric Kades. Doug Lichtman, Chip Lupu, Alan Meese, Richard Pierce, Anne Sprightley Ryan, and Joshua Schwartz for comments on earlier drafts.
    [Show full text]
  • Imperfect Competition: Monopoly
    Imperfect Competition: Monopoly New Topic: Monopoly Q: What is a monopoly? A monopoly is a firm that faces a downward sloping demand, and has a choice about what price to charge – an increase in price doesn’t send most or all of the customers away to rivals. A Monopolistic Market consists of a single seller facing many buyers. Monopoly Q: What are examples of monopolies? There is one producer of aircraft carriers, but there few pure monopolies in the world - US postal mail faces competition from Fed-ex - Microsoft faces competition from Apple or Linux - Google faces competition from Yahoo and Bing - Facebook faces competition from Twitter, IG, Google+ But many firms have some market power- can increase prices above marginal costs for a long period of time, without driving away consumers. Monopoly’s problem 3 Example: A monopolist faces demand given by p(q) 12 q There are no variable costs and all fixed costs are sunk. How many units should the monopoly produce and what price should it charge? By increasing quantity from 2 units to 5 units, the monopolist reduces the price from $10 to $7. The revenue gained is area III, the revenue lost is area I. The slope of the demand curve determines the optimal quantity and price. Monopoly’s problem 4 The monopoly faces a downward sloping demand curve and chooses both prices and quantity to maximize profits. We let the monopoly choose quantity q and the demand determine the price p(q) because it is more convenient. TR(q) p(q) MR [ p(q)q] q p(q) q q q • The monopoly’s chooses q to maximize profit: max (q) TR(q) TC(q) p(q)q TC(q) q The FONC gives: Marginal revenue 5 TR(q) p(q) The marginal revenue MR(q) p(q) q q q p Key property: The marginal revenue is below the demand curve: MR(q) p(q) Example: demand is p(q) =12-q.
    [Show full text]
  • 3. Labor Demand 3A. Labor Demand Model 3B. Short-Run Labor Demand 3B. Short-Run (Cont.)
    3. Labor Demand 3A. Labor Demand Model E151A: C.Cameron n What happens when wage changes? 1. Firms maximize profit (rev - cost). In short-run? Implies produce where marginal profit = zero. In long-run? Maintained assumption throughout course. n What happens if markets are not 2. Two homogeneous factors of competitive due to monopoly or production: labor and capital. monopsony? Q = f(K, L) (Relaxed later) n What is effect of payroll tax? a. Short-run (capital is fixed) b. Long-run (capital may vary) 3A. Model (cont.) 3A. Model (cont.) 3. Price of labor = hourly wage rate. 4. Firms are price-takers in input and output markets. Implies no fringe benefits and no distinction Then marginal cost equals price between increasing labor by increasing the and marginal revenue equals price. number of workers and increasing labor by having current workers work more. Relax to allow: Monopoly: Price-maker in output good market Relax this assumption in ch. 5. Monopsony: Price-maker in input good market 3B. Short-Run (cont.) 3B. Short-Run Labor Demand n Price-taker in labor market: n MRP = Marginal Revenue Product of L L Then always MEL = w = Increase in Revenue due to So hire until MRPL = w one unit increase in Labor So MRPL curve is labor demand curve. = MR x P (P is price) n Price-taker in output market n ME = Marginal Revenue Product of L L Then always MRPL = MPLxP = Increase in Expenses due to n So in competitive markets hire until one unit increase in Labor MPLxP = w or MPL= w/P n L L Profit-maximizer hires until MRPL = MEL n MPL slopes down Þ DL slopes down 1 MRPL IS LABOR DEMAND CURVE 3C.
    [Show full text]
  • The Revenue Functions of a Monopoly
    SOLUTIONS 3 Microeconomics ACTIVITY 3-10 The Revenue Functions of a Monopoly At the opposite end of the market spectrum from perfect competition is monopoly. A monopoly exists when only one firm sells the good or service. This means the monopolist faces the market demand curve since it has no competition from other firms. If the monopolist wants to sell more of its product, it will have to lower its price. As a result, the price (P) at which an extra unit of output (Q) is sold will be greater than the marginal revenue (MR) from that unit. Student Alert: P is greater than MR for a monopolist. 1. Table 3-10.1 has information about the demand and revenue functions of the Moonglow Monopoly Company. Complete the table. Assume the monopoly charges each buyer the same P (i.e., there is no price discrimination). Enter the MR values at the higher of the two Q levels. For example, since total revenue (TR) increases by $37.50 when the firm increases Q from two to three units, put “+$37.50” in the MR column for Q = 3. Table 3-10.1 The Moonglow Monopoly Company Average revenue Q P TR MR (AR) 0 $100.00 $0.00 – – 1 $87.50 $87.50 +$87.50 $87.50 2 $75.00 $150.00 +$62.50 $75.00 3 $62.50 $187.50 +$37.50 $62.50 4 $50.00 $200.00 +$12.50 $50.00 5 $37.50 $187.50 –$12.50 $37.50 6 $25.00 $150.00 –$37.50 $25.00 7 $12.50 $87.50 –$62.50 $12.50 8 $0.00 $0.00 –$87.50 $0.00 2.
    [Show full text]
  • Legal Restrictions on Exploitation of the Patent Monopoly: an Economic Analysis
    The Yale Law Journal Volume 76, No. 2, December 1966 Legal Restrictions on Exploitation of the Patent Monopoly: An Economic Analysis William F. Baxter* I. A Frame of Reference The patent laws confer on a patentee power to exclude all others from making, using or selling his invention.' In furtherance of a con- stitutionally recognized goal-"To promote the Progress of Science and the useful Arts"-Congress has thus adopted a constitutionally authorized means--"securing... to Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective . Discoveries."2 The constitutional clause is re- markable in several respects. Its recognition of the possibility that invention might require encouragement implies not only that techno- logical innovation is desirable but also that, but for legal subsidization, the quantity of innovation forthcoming would or might be less than optimum. This recognition, coming on the morn of an era during which the tendency of a free market to achieve optimality in all activ- ities was greatly and religiously overestimated, 3 prompts brief inquiry into the soundness of the supposition. Several considerations support the view that the market would yield less than optimum innovative activity.4 Invention consists primarily of knowledge; and he whose research, experimentation and insight has * Professor of Law, Stanford University. A.B. 1951, LLB. 1956, Stanford University. 1. 35 U.S.C. § 154 (1964). 2. US. CoNsr. art.I, § 8. 3. Cf. JAFFE, A m mTr LAw, CASES AND MATERus 3-8 (1954). 4. See, e.g., Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources For Invention, in THE RATE AND DIRECTION or INVENTIVE Acrrvry: ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL FAcTOrtS 609 (1962); Machiup, An Economic Review of the Patent System, Study #15 of the Sub.
    [Show full text]
  • THE RELATIVE RIGIDITY of MONOPOLY PRICING by Julio J
    HD28 Apr : .K414 T^rG AJ> m WORKING PAPER ALFRED P. SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT THE RELATIVE RIGIDITY OF MONOPOLY PRICING By Julio J. Rotemberg and Garth Saloner* WP#1777-86 April 1986 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 THE RELATIVE RIGIDITY OF MONOPOLY PRICING By Julio J. Rotemberg and Garth Saloner* WP#1777-86 April 1986 *Sloan School of Management and Department of Economics, M.I.T. respectively. We would like to thank Olivier Blanchard for helpful discussions and the National Science Foundation (grants SES-8209266 and lST-8510162 respectively) for financial support. \ APR 1 6 i937 I. INTRODUCTION The relationship between industry structure and pricing is a najor focus of Industrial Organization. One of the most striking facts to have emerged about this relationship is that monopolists tend to change their prices less frequently than tight oligOi^olies . Although tne first evidence in this regard was presented by Stigler (1947) almost forty years ago, no theoretical explanations have been offered. The objective of this paper is to develop models capable of explaining these facts. Stigler 's objective in comparing the relative rigidity of monopoly and duopoly prices was to test the kinked demand curve theory of Hall and Hitch (1939) ana Sweezy (1939)- Since the work of Gardiner Means (1935) seemed to show that concentrated industries exhibited greater price rigidity than their unconcentrated counterparts, the kinked demand curve was developed and embraced as providing a theoretical foundation for the rigidity of prices. It was widely regarded to be an implication of that theory that duopolists would not change their prices in response to small changes in their costs.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Power and Monopoly Introduction 9
    9 Market Power and Monopoly Introduction 9 Chapter Outline 9.1 Sources of Market Power 9.2 Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.3 Profit Maximization for a Firm with Market Power 9.4 How a Firm with Market Power Reacts to Market Changes 9.5 The Winners and Losers from Market Power 9.6 Governments and Market Power: Regulation, Antitrust, and Innovation 9.7 Conclusion Introduction 9 In the real world, there are very few examples of perfectly competitive industries. Firms often have market power, or an ability to influence the market price of a product. The most extreme example is a monopoly, or a market served by only one firm. • A monopolist is the sole supplier (and price setter) of a good in a market. Firms with market power behave in different ways from those in perfect competition. Sources of Market Power 9.1 The key difference between perfect competition and a market structure in which firms have pricing power is the presence of barriers to entry, or factors that prevent entry into the market with large producer surplus. • Normally, positive producer surplus in the long run will induce additional firms to enter the market until it is driven to zero. • The presence of barriers to entry means that firms in the market may be able to maintain positive producer surplus indefinitely. Sources of Market Power 9.1 Extreme Scale Economies: Natural Monopoly One common barrier to entry results from a production process that exhibits economies of scale at every quantity level • Long-run average total cost curve is downward sloping; diseconomies never emerge.
    [Show full text]
  • Module 1: Pricing Behavior
    Module 1: Pricing Behavior Market Organization & Public Policy (Ec 731) George Georgiadis · Monopoly Pricing Consider a monopolist facing demand curve D (p), where D0(p) < 0. ◦ – i.e., if the price is p, then demand for the good will be equal to q = D(p). 1 – Write P (q) to denote the inverse demand function; i.e., p = D− (q). The cost of producing q units of the good is c(q), where c0(q) > 0. ◦ The monopolist wants to choose the price to maximize his profit. So he solves: ◦ max pD(p) c (D(p)) p { − } First order condition: ◦ D(p)+pD0(p) = c0 (D(p)) D0(p) marginal revenue marginal cost | {z } | D(p{z) } = p c0 (D(p)) = ) − −D0(p) p c0 (D(p)) 1 = − = (1) ) p ✏ where ✏ = pD0(p) denotes the demand elasticity at price p. − D(p) – Demand elasticity: % change in demand in response to a 1% price reduction. – We usually denote this price pm. – Equation (1) tells us that the relative markup (i.e., the ratio between the profit margin and the price), also called the Lerner index, is inversely proportional to the demand elasticity. 1 Note: We assume that D( ) and c( ) are such that the monopolist’s objective function ◦ · · is concave in p, so that the FOC is sufficient for a maximum. 2 – i.e., we assume that 2D0(p)+pD00(p) c00 (D(p)) [D0(p)] 0. − Cournot Competition Same setup as above with two changes: ◦ 1. n instead of single firm compete in the market. 2. Each firm i chooses a quantity qi to produce, and the market price is determined n by p = P ( i=1 qi).
    [Show full text]