Market Power and Monopoly Introduction 9

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Market Power and Monopoly Introduction 9 9 Market Power and Monopoly Introduction 9 Chapter Outline 9.1 Sources of Market Power 9.2 Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.3 Profit Maximization for a Firm with Market Power 9.4 How a Firm with Market Power Reacts to Market Changes 9.5 The Winners and Losers from Market Power 9.6 Governments and Market Power: Regulation, Antitrust, and Innovation 9.7 Conclusion Introduction 9 In the real world, there are very few examples of perfectly competitive industries. Firms often have market power, or an ability to influence the market price of a product. The most extreme example is a monopoly, or a market served by only one firm. • A monopolist is the sole supplier (and price setter) of a good in a market. Firms with market power behave in different ways from those in perfect competition. Sources of Market Power 9.1 The key difference between perfect competition and a market structure in which firms have pricing power is the presence of barriers to entry, or factors that prevent entry into the market with large producer surplus. • Normally, positive producer surplus in the long run will induce additional firms to enter the market until it is driven to zero. • The presence of barriers to entry means that firms in the market may be able to maintain positive producer surplus indefinitely. Sources of Market Power 9.1 Extreme Scale Economies: Natural Monopoly One common barrier to entry results from a production process that exhibits economies of scale at every quantity level • Long-run average total cost curve is downward sloping; diseconomies never emerge. Results in a natural monopoly: • It’s more efficient for a single firm to produce the entire industry output. • Splitting output across multiple firms raises the average cost of production. ‒ An example is a production process with the following total cost structure: 100 TC 100 10Q ATC 10 Q What are some industries that might exhibit continuously declining average total costs as output increases? Sources of Market Power 9.1 Switching Costs Another barrier to entry results from the presence of consumers’ switching costs, which can result from • brand-related opportunity costs (e.g., preferred status on an airline). • technology constraints (e.g., software compatibility issues between Apple and Microsoft Windows–based operating systems). • search costs (e.g., health insurance plans). Some goods have characteristics that make them network goods. • A good whose value to each consumer increases with the number of other consumers of the product What are some network goods? ‒ Telecommunications ‒ Computer operating systems Sources of Market Power 9.1 Product Differentiation For most noncommodity markets, consumers may not treat products from different firms as perfect substitutes • Example: Burger King and Chipotle compete for fast-food customers, but their products are highly differentiated. How? Product differentiation refers to imperfect substitutability across varieties of a product. Sources of Market Power 9.1 Absolute Cost Advantages or Control of Key Inputs Many production processes rely on scarce inputs (e.g., natural resource products). • Example: Saudi Aramco (Saudi Arabia’s state-run oil company) maintains control over a vast oil supply with relatively low extraction costs. In other circumstances, firms may develop absolute cost advantages by engaging in long-term contracts with intermediate suppliers. • Apple has developed this type of relationship with Foxconn, a Chinese company that assembles many of Apple’s products. Sources of Market Power 9.1 Government Regulation A final important barrier is government regulation that limits entry to a market. • Examples: ‒ Patents ‒ Licensing requirements (e.g., medical board certification) ‒ Prohibition of competition (e.g., U.S. Postal Service) Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.2 A true monopolist faces the market demand curve: • There are no competing firms in this market. • Price is not fixed; the only way to sell more of a product is to lower the price. How does this differ from perfect competition? ‒ Perfectly competitive firms can sell as much as they want at the market price. Other market structures associated with downward-sloping demand: • Oligopoly is a market structure in which a few competitors operate (e.g., the automobile industry) • Monopolistic competition is a market structure with a large number of firms selling differentiated products (e.g., the fast food industry) ‒ In these structures, the demand curve facing a given firm depends on the production decisions of other firms—strategic behavior, discussed further in the next chapter. Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.2 Marginal Revenue In perfect competition, the demand curve facing an individual firm is horizontal, and marginal revenue is equal to price. If a firm has market power, the demand curve for its product(s) will have a downward slope. What does this imply for the shape of the marginal revenue curve? ‒ It must also be downward sloping. Consider the production decisions of Durkee-Mower, Inc., a Massachusetts firm that makes Marshmallow Fluff. • Has had a dominant market position since the 1920s • Table 9.1 shows how price and marginal revenue are related to the quantity of Fluff produced. Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.2 Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.2 Marginal revenue is not equivalent to price for a firm facing a downward- sloping demand curve. Why is this the case? ‒ When a firm produces more of a product, the price for all of its products in the marketplace falls. • This occurs because we are considering a specific market (time and place); decisions are not sequential, so firms cannot price-discriminate. • Price discrimination is a pricing strategy in which firms with market power charge different prices to different customers based on their willingness to pay. Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.2 Marginal revenue is not equivalent to price for a firm facing a downward- sloping demand curve. Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue associated with an increase in output, which is composed of two parts Two components for a firm with market power 1. Increase in total revenue associated with an increase in sales 2. Decrease in total revenue associated with the fall in market price for all previously produced units of output Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.2 Figure 9.1 Understanding Marginal Revenue Price Revenue lost from increasing output Revenue unchanged x P1 A y Revenue gained from P2 increasing output B C Demand Quantity Q1 Q2 Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.2 The two opposing effects on marginal revenue of an increase in production by a monopolist can be examined mathematically: 1. The additional revenue from selling one more unit at market price DRevenue = P 2. The fall in revenue associated with a decline in market price for all units produced DP DRevenue = ´Q DQ Combining these effects gives the equation for marginal revenue: DP MR = P + ´Q DQ Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.2 Consider what the equation for marginal revenue means DP Consider a linear demand curve ( D Q is constant) The inverse demand curve is given by P = a - b Q ; therefore: P P MR P Q a bQ Q a bQ bQ a 2bQ Q Q MR a 2bQDP MR = P + ´Q DQ Profit Maximization for a Firm with Market Power 9.3 How to Maximize Profit Firms with market power are still assumed to maximize profits. • However, unlike in perfect competition, production decisions influence price. MR ¹ P How much will firms choose to produce? • They will engage in production until MR = MC Will a monopolist produce more or less than the aggregate production in an identical perfectly competitive industry? ‒ LESS! Profit Maximization for a Firm with Market Power 9.3 Profit Maximization: A Graphical Approach Consider the market for iPads; assume that the marginal cost of production for Apple is constant at $200 per unit. There are three steps to determining the profit-maximizing quantity of production: 1. Derive the marginal revenue curve from the demand curve. 2. Find the output quantity at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost. 3. Determine the profit-maximizing price by locating the point on the demand curve at the optimal quantity level. Profit Maximization for a Firm with Market Power 9.3 Figure 9.3 How a Firm with Market Power Maximizes Profit Price ($/iPad) Profit is maximized when marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. P * = $600 200 MC D 0 Q* = 80 Quantity of iPads MR (millions) Profit Maximization for a Firm with Market Power 9.3 Profit Maximization: A Mathematical Approach Consider again the market for iPads. The marginal cost of production for Apple is constant at $200 per unit. Now suppose demand is given by Q = 200-0.2P where quantity is measured in millions and price in dollars. How do we determine the profit-maximizing price–quantity combination that Apple should choose? 1. Derive the marginal revenue curve from the demand curve. 2. Find the output quantity for which marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. 3. Determine the profit-maximizing price by locating the point on the demand curve at the optimal quantity level. Profit Maximization for a Firm with Market Power 9.3 Profit Maximization: A Mathematical Approach 1. Derive the marginal revenue curve from the demand curve. Q = 200-0.2P 0.2PQPQ 200 1,000 5 This is a linear demand curve, so marginal revenue takes the form MR a 2 bQ 1,000 10 Q Profit Maximization for a Firm with Market Power 9.3 2. Find the output quantity for which marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. For this step, simply set the equation for marginal revenue equal to $200 and solve for quantity. * MR MC 1,000 10Q 200 Q 80 million 3.
Recommended publications
  • Microeconomics Exam Review Chapters 8 Through 12, 16, 17 and 19
    MICROECONOMICS EXAM REVIEW CHAPTERS 8 THROUGH 12, 16, 17 AND 19 Key Terms and Concepts to Know CHAPTER 8 - PERFECT COMPETITION I. An Introduction to Perfect Competition A. Perfectly Competitive Market Structure: • Has many buyers and sellers. • Sells a commodity or standardized product. • Has buyers and sellers who are fully informed. • Has firms and resources that are freely mobile. • Perfectly competitive firm is a price taker; one firm has no control over price. B. Demand Under Perfect Competition: Horizontal line at the market price II. Short-Run Profit Maximization A. Total Revenue Minus Total Cost: The firm maximizes economic profit by finding the quantity at which total revenue exceeds total cost by the greatest amount. B. Marginal Revenue Equals Marginal Cost in Equilibrium • Marginal Revenue: The change in total revenue from selling another unit of output: • MR = ΔTR/Δq • In perfect competition, marginal revenue equals market price. • Market price = Marginal revenue = Average revenue • The firm increases output as long as marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost. • Golden rule of profit maximization. The firm maximizes profit by producing where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. C. Economic Profit in Short-Run: Because the marginal revenue curve is horizontal at the market price, it is also the firm’s demand curve. The firm can sell any quantity at this price. III. Minimizing Short-Run Losses The short run is defined as a period too short to allow existing firms to leave the industry. The following is a summary of short-run behavior: A. Fixed Costs and Minimizing Losses: If a firm shuts down, it must still pay fixed costs.
    [Show full text]
  • Labor Demand: First Lecture
    Labor Market Equilibrium: Fourth Lecture LABOR ECONOMICS (ECON 385) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD Extension: the minimum wage revisited •Here we reexamine the effect of the minimum wage in a non-competitive market. Specifically the effect is different if the market is characterized by a monopsony—a single buyer of a good. •Consider the supply curve for a labor market as before. Also consider the downward-sloping VMPL curve that represents the labor demand of a single firm. • But now instead of multiple competitive employers, this market has only a single firm that employs workers. • The effect of this on labor demand for the monopsony firm is that wage is not a constant value set exogenously by the competitive market. The wage now depends directly (and positively) on the amount of labor employed by this firm. , = , where ( ) is the market supply curve facing the monopsonist. Π ∗ − ∗ − Monopsony hiring • And now when the monopsonist considers how much labor to supply, it has to choose a wage that will attract the marginal worker. This wage is determined by the supply curve. • The usual profit maximization condition—with a linear supply curve, for simplicity—yields: = + = 0 Π where the last term in parentheses is the slope ∗ of the −labor supply curve. When it is linear, the slope is constant (b), and the entire set of parentheses contains the marginal cost of hiring labor. The condition, as usual implies that the employer sets marginal benefit ( ) equal to marginal cost; the only difference is that marginal cost is not constant now. Monopsony hiring (continued) •Specifically the marginal cost is a curve lying above the labor supply with twice the slope of the supply curve.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Bertrand Model
    ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1 Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition Both the monopoly and the perfectly competitive market structure has in common is that neither has to concern itself with the strategic choices of its competition. In the former, this is trivially true since there isn't any competition. While the latter is so insignificant that the single firm has no effect. In an oligopoly where there is more than one firm, and yet because the number of firms are small, they each have to consider what the other does. Consider the product launch decision, and pricing decision of Apple in relation to the IPOD models. If the features of the models it has in the line up is similar to Creative Technology's, it would have to be concerned with the pricing decision, and the timing of its announcement in relation to that of the other firm. We will now begin the exposition of Oligopolistic Competition. 1 Bertrand Model Firms can compete on several variables, and levels, for example, they can compete based on their choices of prices, quantity, and quality. The most basic and funda- mental competition pertains to pricing choices. The Bertrand Model is examines the interdependence between rivals' decisions in terms of pricing decisions. The assumptions of the model are: 1. 2 firms in the market, i 2 f1; 2g. 2. Goods produced are homogenous, ) products are perfect substitutes. 3. Firms set prices simultaneously. 4. Each firm has the same constant marginal cost of c. What is the equilibrium, or best strategy of each firm? The answer is that both firms will set the same prices, p1 = p2 = p, and that it will be equal to the marginal ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 2 cost, in other words, the perfectly competitive outcome.
    [Show full text]
  • Amazon's Antitrust Paradox
    LINA M. KHAN Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox abstract. Amazon is the titan of twenty-first century commerce. In addition to being a re- tailer, it is now a marketing platform, a delivery and logistics network, a payment service, a credit lender, an auction house, a major book publisher, a producer of television and films, a fashion designer, a hardware manufacturer, and a leading host of cloud server space. Although Amazon has clocked staggering growth, it generates meager profits, choosing to price below-cost and ex- pand widely instead. Through this strategy, the company has positioned itself at the center of e- commerce and now serves as essential infrastructure for a host of other businesses that depend upon it. Elements of the firm’s structure and conduct pose anticompetitive concerns—yet it has escaped antitrust scrutiny. This Note argues that the current framework in antitrust—specifically its pegging competi- tion to “consumer welfare,” defined as short-term price effects—is unequipped to capture the ar- chitecture of market power in the modern economy. We cannot cognize the potential harms to competition posed by Amazon’s dominance if we measure competition primarily through price and output. Specifically, current doctrine underappreciates the risk of predatory pricing and how integration across distinct business lines may prove anticompetitive. These concerns are height- ened in the context of online platforms for two reasons. First, the economics of platform markets create incentives for a company to pursue growth over profits, a strategy that investors have re- warded. Under these conditions, predatory pricing becomes highly rational—even as existing doctrine treats it as irrational and therefore implausible.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Curve
    Econ 201: Introduction to Economics Analysis September 4 Lecture: Supply and Demand Jeffrey Parker Reed College Daily dose of The Far Side Keeping with the vegetable theme from Wednesday… www.thefarside.com 2 Preview of this class session • Basic principles of market analysis using supply and demand curves are central to economics • Formal conditions for “perfectly competitive” markets are strict and rarely satisfied • We discuss what supply curves and demand curves are • We define market equilibrium and why we expect markets to move there • We consider effects of shifts in curves on equilibrium price and quantity 3 “Two-curve” analysis • Why is it useful? • Two key variables (price, quantity) • One curve slopes up and the other down • Some exogenous variables affect one curve, others the other • Few affect both • Change in any exogenous variable affects one curve in predictable way: • Intersection moves SE, NE, NW, or SE • Predictable changes in price and quantity exchanged https://www.econgraphs.org/graphs/micro/supply_and_demand/supply_and_demand?textbook=varian 4 Demand function • Relates quantity of good demanded to its relative price • Quantity demanded = amount buyers are willing and able to purchase • Relative price is price of good holding all other goods constant • Reflects decision-making by potential buyers • Demand function: QD = D (P ) • Negative relationship • Downward-sloping curve • Need not be straight line https://www.econgraphs.org/graphs/micro/supply_and_demand/supply_and_demand?textbook=varian 5 Demand curves 6 Demand
    [Show full text]
  • Apple and Amazon's Antitrust Antics
    APPLE AND AMAZON’S ANTITRUST ANTICS: TWO WRONGS DON’T MAKE A RIGHT, BUT MAYBE THEY SHOULD Kerry Gutknecht‡ I. INTRODUCTION The exploding market for books of all kinds in the form of digital files (“e- books”), which can be read on mobile devices and personal computers, has attracted aggressive competition between the two leading online e-book retail- ers, Amazon, Inc. (“Amazon”) and Apple Inc. (“Apple”).1 While both Amazon and Apple have been accused by critics of engaging in anticompetitive practic- es with regard to e-book sales,2 the U.S. Department of Justice has focused on Apple. In 2012, federal prosecutors brought an antitrust suit against Apple and five of the nation’s largest book publishers—HarperCollins Publishers LLC (“HarperCollins”), Hachette Book Group, Inc. and Hachette Digital (“Hachette”); Holtzbrinck Publishers, LLC d/b/a Macmillan (“Macmillan”); Penguin Group (USA), Inc. (“Penguin”); and Simon & Schuster, Inc. and (“Simon & Schuster”) (collectively, the “Publisher Defendants”)3—for collud- ing in violation of the Sherman Act to raise the retail prices of e-books.4 Each ‡ J.D. Candidate, May 2014, The Catholic University of America, Columbus School of Law. The author would like to thank Calla Brown for her daily support and the CommLaw Conspectus staff for their diligent effort during the writing and editing process. Finally, a special thanks to Antonio F. Perez for providing expert advice during the writing of this paper. 1 Complaint at 2–3, United States v. Apple Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638 (S.D.N.Y. 2013) (No. 12 CV 2826) [hereinafter Complaint].
    [Show full text]
  • Theory of Public Goods
    Public Goods Private versus Public Goods A private good (bread) exhibits the following two properties: exclusive: A good is exclusive if once you have purchased a good, then you can exclude others from consuming it. rival: A good is rival in consumption, in the sense that once someone buys a loaf of bread and consumes it, then that precludes you from consuming that same loaf of bread. • A rival good is depletable. A technical consequence of depletability is that consumption of additional amounts of rival goods involve some marginal costs of production. A public good (air quality) may exhibit the following two properties: nonexclusive: A good is nonexclusive if no one can be excluded from benefiting from or consuming the good once it is produced. An implication of nonexclusivity is that goods can be enjoyed without direct payment. nonrivalrous: One person's consumption of a good does not diminish the amount or quality available for others. • A nonrival good is nondepletable. A technical consequence of nondepletability is that the marginal cost of providing a nonrival good to an additional consumer is zero. • All public goods exhibit the nonexcludability property but they do not necessarily exhibit the nonrivalrous property. nonrival rival • water pollution in small body of private good excludable water, indoor air pollution pure public good/bad congestible public good/bad • users neither interfere with each • users affect good's usefulness to other nor increase good's others — mutual interference usefulness to each other of users creates negative nonexcludable (free–rider problem) externality (free–access • biodiversity, greenhouse gases problem) • noise, defence, radio signal • ocean fishery, parks • bridge, highway Aggregate Demand Curves for Private and Public Goods 1.
    [Show full text]
  • The Marginal Cost Controversy in Intellectual Property John F Duffyt
    The Marginal Cost Controversy in Intellectual Property John F Duffyt In 1938, Harold Hotelling formally advanced the position that "the optimum of the general welfare corresponds to the sale of everything at marginal cost."' To reach this optimum, Hotelling argued, general gov- ernment revenues should "be applied to cover the fixed costs of electric power plants, waterworks, railroad, and other industries in which the fixed costs are large, so as to reduce to the level of marginal cost the prices charged for the services and products of these industries."2 Other major economists of the day subsequently endorsed Hotelling's view' and, in the late 1930s and early 1940s, it "aroused considerable interest and [had] al- ready found its way into some textbooks on public utility economics."' In his 1946 article, The MarginalCost Controversy,Ronald Coase set forth a detailed rejoinder to the Hotelling thesis, concluding that the social subsidies proposed by Hotelling "would bring about a maldistribu- tion of the factors of production, a maldistribution of income and proba- bly a loss similar to that which the scheme was designed to avoid."' The article, which Richard Posner would later hail as Coase's "most impor- tant" contribution to the field of public utility pricing,6 was part of a wave of literature debating the merits of the Hotelling proposal.' Yet the very success of the critique by Coase and others has led to the entire contro- t Professor of Law, George Washington University Law School. The author thanks Michael Abramowicz. Richard Hynes, Eric Kades. Doug Lichtman, Chip Lupu, Alan Meese, Richard Pierce, Anne Sprightley Ryan, and Joshua Schwartz for comments on earlier drafts.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Failure Guide
    Market failure guide A guide to categorising market failures for government policy development and evaluation industry.nsw.gov.au Published by NSW Department of Industry PUB17/509 Market failure guide—A guide to categorising market failures for government policy development and evaluation An external academic review of this guide was undertaken by prominent economists in November 2016 This guide is consistent with ‘NSW Treasury (2017) NSW Government Guide to Cost-Benefit Analysis, TPP 17-03, Policy and Guidelines Paper’ First published December 2017 More information Program Evaluation Unit [email protected] www.industry.nsw.gov.au © State of New South Wales through Department of Industry, 2017. This publication is copyright. You may download, display, print and reproduce this material provided that the wording is reproduced exactly, the source is acknowledged, and the copyright, update address and disclaimer notice are retained. To copy, adapt, publish, distribute or commercialise any of this publication you will need to seek permission from the Department of Industry. Disclaimer: The information contained in this publication is based on knowledge and understanding at the time of writing July 2017. However, because of advances in knowledge, users are reminded of the need to ensure that the information upon which they rely is up to date and to check the currency of the information with the appropriate officer of the Department of Industry or the user’s independent advisor. Market failure guide Contents Executive summary
    [Show full text]
  • Monopoly Monopoly Causes of Monopolies Profit Maximization
    Monopoly • market with a single seller • Firm demand = market demand Monopoly • Firm demand is downward sloping • Monopolist can alter market price by adjusting its ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory own output level Summer 2004 – Rice University Stanley Gilbert Econ 370 - Monopoly 2 Causes of Monopolies Profit Maximization •Created by law ⇒ US Postal Service • We assume profit maximization • a patent ⇒ a new drug • Earlier we noted – profit maximization • sole ownership of a resource ⇒ a toll highway ⇒ – Marginal Revenue = Marginal Cost • formation of a cartel ⇒ OPEC • With monopolies, that is the relevant test • large economies of scale ⇒ local utility company (natural monopoly) Econ 370 - Monopoly 3 Econ 370 - Monopoly 4 1 Mathematically Significance dp(y) dc(y) p()y + y = π ()y = p ()y y − c ()y dy dy At profit-maximizing output y*: • Since demand is downward sloping: dp/dy < 0 – So a monopoly supplies less than a competitive market dπ ()y d dc(y) would = ()p()y y − = 0 – At a higher price dy dy dy • MR < Price because to sell the next unit of output it has to lower its price on all its product dp()y dc(y) p()y + y = – Not just on the last unit dy dy – Thus further reducing revenue Econ 370 - Monopoly 5 Econ 370 - Monopoly 6 Linear Demand Linear Demand Graph • If demand is q(p) = f – gp • Then the inverse demand function is p – p = f / g – q / g –Let a = f / g, and a –Let b = 1 / g – Then p = a – bq p(y) = a – by • Since output y = demand q, the revenue function is – p(y)·y = (a – by)y = ay – by2 y • Marginal Revenue is a / 2b a / b –MR
    [Show full text]
  • The Demand Curve
    Introduction to Supply and Demand Markets are … Consumers and producers Exchange goods/services for payment Most basic is a COMPETITIVE MARKET 5 Elements of S&D Model Demand curve 5 Elements of S&D Model Demand curve Supply curve 5 Elements of S&D Model Demand curve Supply curve Equilibrium 5 Elements of S&D Model Demand curve Supply curve Equilibrium Demand and Supply factors Changes in equilibrium The Demand Curve Chapter 3: Supply and Demand (pages 62-71) Think for a minute… How do we calculate the amount of coffee demanded in a given year? We need a DEMAND SCHEDULE… Demand Schedule and Curve Price Quantity Law of Demand ⇑ Price=⇓ Quantity Demanded Downward-sloping curves Change in quantity demanded Caused by a ∆ in PRICE Demand schedule unchanged Movement along curve Determinants of Demand M.E.R.I.T. shifts the curve Market size (# consumers) Expectations Related prices Income Tastes and preferences Shifts in Demand Demand shifts with ∆ M.E.R.I.T. Increase = shift to right Decrease = shift to left Market Size Amount of goods demanded at a given price will change More buyers = ⇑ Demand Fewer buyers = ⇓ Demand Example: Cost of prescription drugs as the population gets older Expectations Future prices, product availability, and income can shift demand Example: What do you do if the price of gas is expected to fall next week? Example: If the iPhone 5 will be released in October what happens to demand for iPhone 4? Related prices Depends on whether the good is a SUBSTITUTE ⇑P for good 1 ⇑D for good 2 Example: Coffee and Tea COMPLEMENT ⇑P for good 1 ⇓D for good 2 Example: Peanut butter and jelly Income ⇑Income = ⇑Demand (usually…) True for NORMAL goods INFERIOR goods are different ⇑ Income = ⇓ Demand Example: Bus vs.
    [Show full text]
  • Investment Characteristics of Natural Monopoly Companies
    Investment Characteristics of Natural Monopoly Companies Škapa Stanislav Abstract This paper explores the possibilities of investment by private investors in natural monopoly companies. The paper analyzes the broad issue of risk measurement with focus on downside risk measurement principle. The main scientific aim is to adopt a more sophisticated and theo- retically advanced statistical technique and apply them to the findings. The preferred method used for the estimation of selected characteristics and ratios was the robust statistical methods and a bootstrap method. Key words: natural monopoly, investor, investment, downside risk 1. INTRODUCTION Natural monopoly companies lead to a variety of economic performance problems: excessive prices, production inefficiencies, costly duplication of facilities, poor service quality and they have potentially undesirable distributional impacts. In the eyes of consumers, it is the high prices and poor service quality that they most probably perceive. However, the question that arises is: what brings the investment into the natural monopoly company to investors? 2. THEORETICAL SOLUTIONS 2.1 Natural monopoly Economists have been analyzing natural monopolies for more than 150 year. Sharkey (1982) provides an overview of the intellectual history of economic analysis of natural monopolies and he concludes that John Stuart Mill was the first to speak of natural monopolies in 1848. One of the main questions is how a natural monopoly should be defined. There are some characteristics which should help to understand what a natural monopoly mean. According Thomas Farrer (1902, referenced by Sharkey, 1982) a natural monopoly is associated with supply and demand of characteristics that include: the product or supplied service must be essential the products must be non-storable the supplier must have a favourable production location.
    [Show full text]