Monopoly Monopoly Causes of Monopolies Profit Maximization

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Monopoly Monopoly Causes of Monopolies Profit Maximization Monopoly • market with a single seller • Firm demand = market demand Monopoly • Firm demand is downward sloping • Monopolist can alter market price by adjusting its ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory own output level Summer 2004 – Rice University Stanley Gilbert Econ 370 - Monopoly 2 Causes of Monopolies Profit Maximization •Created by law ⇒ US Postal Service • We assume profit maximization • a patent ⇒ a new drug • Earlier we noted – profit maximization • sole ownership of a resource ⇒ a toll highway ⇒ – Marginal Revenue = Marginal Cost • formation of a cartel ⇒ OPEC • With monopolies, that is the relevant test • large economies of scale ⇒ local utility company (natural monopoly) Econ 370 - Monopoly 3 Econ 370 - Monopoly 4 1 Mathematically Significance dp(y) dc(y) p()y + y = π ()y = p ()y y − c ()y dy dy At profit-maximizing output y*: • Since demand is downward sloping: dp/dy < 0 – So a monopoly supplies less than a competitive market dπ ()y d dc(y) would = ()p()y y − = 0 – At a higher price dy dy dy • MR < Price because to sell the next unit of output it has to lower its price on all its product dp()y dc(y) p()y + y = – Not just on the last unit dy dy – Thus further reducing revenue Econ 370 - Monopoly 5 Econ 370 - Monopoly 6 Linear Demand Linear Demand Graph • If demand is q(p) = f – gp • Then the inverse demand function is p – p = f / g – q / g –Let a = f / g, and a –Let b = 1 / g – Then p = a – bq p(y) = a – by • Since output y = demand q, the revenue function is – p(y)·y = (a – by)y = ay – by2 y • Marginal Revenue is a / 2b a / b –MR = a –2by MR(y) = a –2by Econ 370 - Monopoly 7 Econ 370 - Monopoly 8 2 Profit-Maximization: An Example Graphically • Linear Demand: p(y) = a – by • Cost function c(y) = F + αy + βy2 p – So, MC = α +2βy a • At profit maximizing y*, MR = MC, So p(y) = a – by – a –2by = α –2βy p* a − α MC(y) = α + 2βy y* = 2(b + β ) α y* y * * a − α p()y = a − by = a − b 2(b + β ) MR(y) = a –2by Econ 370 - Monopoly 9 Econ 370 - Monopoly 10 Elasticity and Monopolistic Pricing Elasticity and Monopolistic Pricing 2 dp()y ⎡ y dp(y)⎤ MR()y = p ()y + y = p()y ⎢1+ ⎥ Since MR = MC, then dy ⎣ p()y dy ⎦ * ⎡ 1⎤ * p(y ) 1+ = MC(y ) Since Own-price elasticity of demand is ⎣⎢ ε ⎦⎥ p()y dy ε = y dp()y In particular, note that: * ⎡ 1⎤ 1 p(y ) 1+ ≥ 0 ⇒ 1+ ≥ 0 ⇒ ε ≤ −1 ⎡ 1⎤ ⎢ ε ⎥ ε Then MR()y = p ()y 1+ ⎣ ⎦ ⎣⎢ ε ⎦⎥ Econ 370 - Monopoly 11 Econ 370 - Monopoly 12 3 Markup Pricing Pure Profits Tax Levied on a Monopoly • One Interpretation of the elasticity results is • Pure profits tax levied at rate t Markup pricing – Reduces profit from π(y*) to (1 – t)π(y*) – Output price = MC + “markup” – Monopolist maximizes after-tax profit, (1 – t)π(y*) • Issues – Same as maximizing before-tax profit, π(y*) – How big is a monopolist’s markup? • Implications – How does it change with the own-price elasticity of – Profits tax has no effect on monopolist’s choices of demand? output, price or input demands – The profits tax is a neutral tax Econ 370 - Monopoly 13 Econ 370 - Monopoly 14 Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist Quantity Tax Graph • A quantity tax of $t per output unit – Raises the marginal cost of production by $t p – Reduces profit-maxing output – Causes market price to rise – Input demands to fall t p MC(y) + t • The quantity tax is distortionary p* MC(y) yt y* y MR(y) Econ 370 - Monopoly 15 Econ 370 - Monopoly 16 4 Tax impact on Consumers Tax impact on Consumers • Can a monopolist “shift” all of a $t quantity tax to (k + t)ε kε tε p( y t ) − p( y*) = − = consumers? 1 + ε 1 + ε 1 + ε • Suppose MC= k (constant) kε • is amount of tax shifted to buyers. • With no tax (MR=MC=k): p( y*) = 1 + ε •E.g. if ε = -2, amount of tax shifted is 2t • Tax increases MC to (k+t), changing profit- • In general, if ε < -1 (always true for monopolist) maximizing price (MR=MC=k+t) to – ε /(1 + ε) > 1, and (k + t)ε – monopolist passes on more than the tax! p( yt ) = 1 + ε • The amount of tax shifted to buyers is: p(yt) – p(y*) Econ 370 - Monopoly 17 Econ 370 - Monopoly 18 Inefficiency of Monopoly: Graph Inefficiency of Monopoly: Graph • Efficient output level ye satisfies p(y) = MC(y) • Both buyer and seller could gain from production of one more unit…so Pareto Inefficient • Total gains-from-trade are maximized p p DWL p(y) p(y) p* CS CS pe MC(y) pe PS MC(y) PS ye y y* ye y Econ 370 - Monopoly 19 Econ 370 - Monopoly 20 5 Regulating Monopolies Generally Natural Monopoly: Introduction • Licensing (patents) • Natural monopoly – Technology has very large economies-of-scale • Antitrust Remedies – Firm can supply whole market at lower average total – Conduct Remedies cost than possible with more than one firm – Structural Remedies • Regulation (especially natural monopolies) • Considerations – Firm must be allowed to earn profit ≥ 0 – A Firm will use private information to its own advantage – Law of unintended consequences Econ 370 - Monopoly 21 Econ 370 - Monopoly 22 Natural Monopoly: Graph Regulating a Natural Monopoly: Intro $/output unit • Problem facing regulators – Want efficient output (p = MC) ATC(y) –Want DWL = 0 – But impossible with natural monopoly • At efficient output ye, ATC(ye) > p(ye) p* Demand • Regulated monopoly has an economic loss MR(y) DWL MC(y) y y* Econ 370 - Monopoly 23 Econ 370 - Monopoly 24 6 Regulating a Natural Monopoly: Graph Regulating a Natural Monopoly $/output unit • Natural monopoly cannot use p = MC – If so, profit is < 0 ATC(y) – Monopolist will exit – Destroys both the market and any gains-to-trade • Regulatory schemes induce natural monopolist to produce the efficient output w/o exiting Demand MR(y) MC(y) ATC pe Economic Loss y ye Econ 370 - Monopoly 25 Econ 370 - Monopoly 26 Alternative Forms of Monopoly Pricing Types of Price Discrimination • Uniform pricing – single price to all customers • 1st-degree – Each output unit is sold at a different price • Price-discrimination – Prices differ across buyers – Charge different prices to different customers – Requires different markets w/ no trade • 2nd-degree – Price varies with quantity demanded by buyer – Also requires different elasticities – All customers face the same price schedule – Can only raise profits (or get same) • 3rd-degree price discrimination – Price paid by buyers in group is same for all units – Price differs across buyer groups • senior citizen discounts • student discounts • no discounts for middle-aged persons Econ 370 - Monopoly 27 Econ 370 - Monopoly 28 7 1st-degree Price Discrimination: Intro 1st-degree Price Discrimination: Graph • Each output unit is sold at a different price Sell the y’th unit for $p(y’) • Requires that monopolist can discover Sell the y’’th unit for $p(y’’) – the buyer w/ the highest valuation of its product Sell the y’’’ th unit for MC $p(y’’’) – the buyer w/ the next highest valuation $ – Etc., etc., etc. p(y′) p(y′′) MC(y) p(y′′′) p(y) y′ y′′ y′′′ y Econ 370 - Monopoly 29 Econ 370 - Monopoly 30 1st-degree Price Discrimination: Graph 1st-degree Price Discrimination: Graph • Gains to monopolist on these trades are: • The monopolist gets the maximum p(y´) – MC(y´), p(y´´) – MC(y´´), and possible gains from trade zero • First-degree price discrimination • The consumers’ gains are zero $ $ is Pareto-efficient p(y′) p(y′′) MC(y) PS MC(y) p(y′′′) p(y) p(y) y′ y′′ y′′′ y y′′′ y Econ 370 - Monopoly 31 Econ 370 - Monopoly 32 8 1st-degree Price Discrimination: Summary 2nd Degree Price Discrimination • First-degree price discrimination •2nd Degree Price discrimination includes – gives monopolist all possible gains-to-trade • 2-part tariffs – leaves buyers with zero consumer surplus – supplies efficient amount of output • Volume Discounts • Fixed Price-Quantity bundles – For example, mobile-phone service is sold this way Econ 370 - Monopoly 33 Econ 370 - Monopoly 34 Two-part tariffs Two-Part Tariffs: Entrance Fee • Two-part tariff • Two part tariff: p1 + p2x – lump-sum fee p1 plus •What p1? is maximum entrance fee = p1? – price p2 for each unit purchased •Maximum p = surplus buyer gains from entering • Thus the cost of buying x units of product is 1 the market • p + p x 1 2 • So, monopolist strategy: –Set p1 = CS – Solve for optimal p2 Econ 370 - Monopoly 35 Econ 370 - Monopoly 36 9 Two-Part Tariffs: Graph Two-Part Tariffs: Graph Should the monopolist set p2 = MC? Should the monopolist set p2 = MC? p1 = CS PS is profit from sales $/output $/output unit p(y) unit p(y) Total profit MC(y) CS p2 = p(y′′) MC(y) p = p(y′′) 2 PS y′′ y Econ 370 - Monopoly 37 Econ 370 - Monopoly y′′ y 38 Two-Part Tariffs: Maximizing Profits 3rd-degree Price Discrimination • Monopolist maximizes profit w/ two-part tariff • Price paid by buyers in a given group is the same – setting unit price p2 = marginal cost and for all units purchased – setting its lump-sum entrance fee p equal to 1 • Price may differ across buyer groups (if demand Consumers’ Surplus at output where p = MC 2 elasticities are different) • Monopolist gets all gains from trade • Monopolist manipulates price by altering quantity • Outcome is efficient supplied to each market • How many units of product will the monopolist supply to each group? Econ 370 - Monopoly 39 Econ 370 - Monopoly 40 10 3rd-degree Price Discrimination 3rd-degree Price Discrimination: Profit • Two markets, 1 and 2 • For given supply levels y1 and y2 the firm’s profit is • y1 = quantity supplied to market 1 • π(y1, y2) = p1(y1)y1 + p1(y2)y2 –c(y1 + y2) • p1(y1) = inverse demand function in market 1 • What values of y1 and y2 maximize profit? • y2 = quantity supplied to market 2 • p2(y2) = inverse demand function in market 2 Econ
Recommended publications
  • Microeconomics Exam Review Chapters 8 Through 12, 16, 17 and 19
    MICROECONOMICS EXAM REVIEW CHAPTERS 8 THROUGH 12, 16, 17 AND 19 Key Terms and Concepts to Know CHAPTER 8 - PERFECT COMPETITION I. An Introduction to Perfect Competition A. Perfectly Competitive Market Structure: • Has many buyers and sellers. • Sells a commodity or standardized product. • Has buyers and sellers who are fully informed. • Has firms and resources that are freely mobile. • Perfectly competitive firm is a price taker; one firm has no control over price. B. Demand Under Perfect Competition: Horizontal line at the market price II. Short-Run Profit Maximization A. Total Revenue Minus Total Cost: The firm maximizes economic profit by finding the quantity at which total revenue exceeds total cost by the greatest amount. B. Marginal Revenue Equals Marginal Cost in Equilibrium • Marginal Revenue: The change in total revenue from selling another unit of output: • MR = ΔTR/Δq • In perfect competition, marginal revenue equals market price. • Market price = Marginal revenue = Average revenue • The firm increases output as long as marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost. • Golden rule of profit maximization. The firm maximizes profit by producing where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. C. Economic Profit in Short-Run: Because the marginal revenue curve is horizontal at the market price, it is also the firm’s demand curve. The firm can sell any quantity at this price. III. Minimizing Short-Run Losses The short run is defined as a period too short to allow existing firms to leave the industry. The following is a summary of short-run behavior: A. Fixed Costs and Minimizing Losses: If a firm shuts down, it must still pay fixed costs.
    [Show full text]
  • Labor Demand: First Lecture
    Labor Market Equilibrium: Fourth Lecture LABOR ECONOMICS (ECON 385) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD Extension: the minimum wage revisited •Here we reexamine the effect of the minimum wage in a non-competitive market. Specifically the effect is different if the market is characterized by a monopsony—a single buyer of a good. •Consider the supply curve for a labor market as before. Also consider the downward-sloping VMPL curve that represents the labor demand of a single firm. • But now instead of multiple competitive employers, this market has only a single firm that employs workers. • The effect of this on labor demand for the monopsony firm is that wage is not a constant value set exogenously by the competitive market. The wage now depends directly (and positively) on the amount of labor employed by this firm. , = , where ( ) is the market supply curve facing the monopsonist. Π ∗ − ∗ − Monopsony hiring • And now when the monopsonist considers how much labor to supply, it has to choose a wage that will attract the marginal worker. This wage is determined by the supply curve. • The usual profit maximization condition—with a linear supply curve, for simplicity—yields: = + = 0 Π where the last term in parentheses is the slope ∗ of the −labor supply curve. When it is linear, the slope is constant (b), and the entire set of parentheses contains the marginal cost of hiring labor. The condition, as usual implies that the employer sets marginal benefit ( ) equal to marginal cost; the only difference is that marginal cost is not constant now. Monopsony hiring (continued) •Specifically the marginal cost is a curve lying above the labor supply with twice the slope of the supply curve.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation and Economic Progress
    THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS 12, NO. 1 (2009): 17–35 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND ECONOMIC PROGRESS RANDALL G. HOLCOMBE ABSTRACT: In neoclassical theory, product differentiation provides consumers with a variety of different products within a particular industry, rather than a homogeneous product that characterizes purely competitive markets. The welfare-enhancing benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of products available to consumers, which comes at the cost of a higher average total cost of production. In reality, firms do not differentiate their products to make them different, or to give consumers variety, but to make them better, so consumers would rather buy that firm’s product rather than the product of a competitor. When product differentiation is seen as a strategy to improve products rather than just to make them different, product differentiation emerges as the engine of economic progress. In contrast to the neoclassical framework, where product differentiation imposes a cost on the economy in exchange for more product variety, in real- ity product differentiation lowers costs, creates better products for consumers, and generates economic progress. n the neoclassical theory of the firm, product differentiation enhances consumer welfare by offering consumers greater variety, Ibut that benefit is offset by the higher average cost of production for monopolistically competitive firms. In the neoclassical framework, the only benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of prod- ucts available, but the reason firms differentiate their products is not just to make them different from the products of other firms, but to make them better. By improving product quality and bringing new Randall G.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Profit Maximization
    Central Washington University ScholarWorks@CWU All Faculty Scholarship for the College of Business College of Business Fall 2011 A Primer on Profit aM ximization Robert Carbaugh Central Washington University, [email protected] Tyler Prante Los Angeles Valley College Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.cwu.edu/cobfac Part of the Economic Theory Commons, and the Higher Education Commons Recommended Citation Carbaugh, Robert and Tyler Prante. (2011). A primer on profit am ximization. Journal for Economic Educators, 11(2), 34-45. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Business at ScholarWorks@CWU. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship for the College of Business by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@CWU. 34 JOURNAL FOR ECONOMIC EDUCATORS, 11(2), FALL 2011 A PRIMER ON PROFIT MAXIMIZATION Robert Carbaugh1 and Tyler Prante2 Abstract Although textbooks in intermediate microeconomics and managerial economics discuss the first- order condition for profit maximization (marginal revenue equals marginal cost) for pure competition and monopoly, they tend to ignore the second-order condition (marginal cost cuts marginal revenue from below). Mathematical economics textbooks also tend to provide only tangential treatment of the necessary and sufficient conditions for profit maximization. This paper fills the void in the textbook literature by combining mathematical and graphical analysis to more fully explain the profit maximizing hypothesis under a variety of market structures and cost conditions. It is intended to be a useful primer for all students taking intermediate level courses in microeconomics, managerial economics, and mathematical economics. It also will be helpful for students in Master’s and Ph.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Profit Maximization and Cost Minimization ● Average and Marginal Costs
    Theory of the Firm Moshe Ben-Akiva 1.201 / 11.545 / ESD.210 Transportation Systems Analysis: Demand & Economics Fall 2008 Outline ● Basic Concepts ● Production functions ● Profit maximization and cost minimization ● Average and marginal costs 2 Basic Concepts ● Describe behavior of a firm ● Objective: maximize profit max π = R(a ) − C(a ) s.t . a ≥ 0 – R, C, a – revenue, cost, and activities, respectively ● Decisions: amount & price of inputs to buy amount & price of outputs to produce ● Constraints: technology constraints market constraints 3 Production Function ● Technology: method for turning inputs (including raw materials, labor, capital, such as vehicles, drivers, terminals) into outputs (such as trips) ● Production function: description of the technology of the firm. Maximum output produced from given inputs. q = q(X ) – q – vector of outputs – X – vector of inputs (capital, labor, raw material) 4 Using a Production Function ● The production function predicts what resources are needed to provide different levels of output ● Given prices of the inputs, we can find the most efficient (i.e. minimum cost) way to produce a given level of output 5 Isoquant ● For two-input production: Capital (K) q=q(K,L) K’ q3 q2 q1 Labor (L) L’ 6 Production Function: Examples ● Cobb-Douglas : ● Input-Output: = α a b = q x1 x2 q min( ax1 ,bx2 ) x2 x2 Isoquants q2 q2 q1 q1 x1 x1 7 Rate of Technical Substitution (RTS) ● Substitution rates for inputs – Replace a unit of input 1 with RTS units of input 2 keeping the same level of production x2 ∂x ∂q ∂x RTS
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 16: Profit Maximization and Long-Run Competition
    Lecture 16: Profit Maximization and Long-Run Competition Session ID: DDEE EC101 DD & EE / Manove Profits and Long Run Competition p 1 EC101 DD & EE / Manove Clicker Question p 2 Cost, Revenue and Profits Total Cost (TC): TC = FC + VC Average Cost (AC): AC = TC / Q Sometimes called Average Total Cost (ATC) Profits: = Total Revenue − Total Cost = (P x Q) − TC = (P x Q) − AC x Q = (P − AC) Q Producer surplus is the same as profits before fixed costs are deducted. =(P x Q) − VC − FC =PS− FC EC101 DD & EE / Manove Producer Costs>Cost Concepts p 3 A Small Firm in a Competitive Market The equilibrium price P* is determined by the entire market. If all of the other firms charge P* and produce total output Q0, then … Market Last Small Firm P S P D P* P* Q* = Q0 + QF D Q Q Q Q0 0 QF for the last small firm, the remaining demand near the market price seems very large and very elastic. The last firm’s supply determines its own equilibrium quantity: it will also charge the market price (and be a price-taker). EC101 DD & EE / Manove Perfect Competition>Small Firm p 4 Supply Shifts in a Competitive Market Suppose Farmer Jones discovers that hip-hop music increases his hens’ output of eggs. Then his supply curve would shift to the right. But his price wouldn’t change. EC101 DD & EE / Manove Perfect Competition>Small Firm>Supply Shift p 5 How does the shift of his supply curve affect Farmer Jones? P P S S S’ P* D D Q Q Market Farmer Jones Farmer Jones’ supply shifts to the right, but his equilibrium price remains the same.
    [Show full text]
  • Microeconomic Theory
    PROFIT MAXIMIZATION [See Chap 11] 1 Profit Maximization • A profit-maximizing firm chooses both its inputs and its outputs with the goal of achieving maximum economic profits 2 Model • Firm has inputs (z1,z2). Prices (r1,r2). – Price taker on input market. • Firm has output q=f(z1,z2). Price p. – Price taker in output market. • Firm’s problem: – Choose output q and inputs (z1,z2) to maximise profits. Where: = pq - r1z1 – r2z2 3 One-Step Solution • Choose (z1,z2) to maximise = pf(z1,z2) - r1z1 – r2z2 • This is unconstrained maximization problem. • FOCs are f (z1, z2 ) f (z1, z2 ) p r1 and p r2 z1 z2 • Together these yield optimal inputs zi*(p,r1,r2). • Output is q*(p,r1,r2) = f(z1*, z2*). This is usually called the supply function. • Profit is (p,r1,r2) = pq* - r1z1* - r2z2* 4 1/3 1/3 Example: f(z1,z2)=z1 z2 1/3 1/3 • Profit is = pz1 z2 - r1z1 – r2z2 • FOCs are 1 1 pz 2/3z1/3 r and pz1/3z2/3 r 3 1 2 1 3 1 2 2 • Solving these two eqns, optimal inputs are 3 3 * 1 p * 1 p z1 ( p,r1,r2 ) 2 and z2 ( p,r1,r2 ) 2 27 r1 r2 27 r1r2 • Optimal output 2 * * 1/3 * 1/3 1 p q ( p,r1,r2 ) (z1 ) (z2 ) 9 r1r2 • Profits 3 * * * * 1 p ( p,r1,r2 ) pq r1z1 r2 z2 27 r1r2 5 Two-Step Solution Step 1: Find cheapest way to obtain output q. c(r1,r2,q) = minz1,z2 r1z1+r2z2 s.t f(z1,z2) ≥ q Step 2: Find profit maximizing output.
    [Show full text]
  • Principles of Microeconomics
    PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS A. Competition The basic motivation to produce in a market economy is the expectation of income, which will generate profits. • The returns to the efforts of a business - the difference between its total revenues and its total costs - are profits. Thus, questions of revenues and costs are key in an analysis of the profit motive. • Other motivations include nonprofit incentives such as social status, the need to feel important, the desire for recognition, and the retaining of one's job. Economists' calculations of profits are different from those used by businesses in their accounting systems. Economic profit = total revenue - total economic cost • Total economic cost includes the value of all inputs used in production. • Normal profit is an economic cost since it occurs when economic profit is zero. It represents the opportunity cost of labor and capital contributed to the production process by the producer. • Accounting profits are computed only on the basis of explicit costs, including labor and capital. Since they do not take "normal profits" into consideration, they overstate true profits. Economic profits reward entrepreneurship. They are a payment to discovering new and better methods of production, taking above-average risks, and producing something that society desires. The ability of each firm to generate profits is limited by the structure of the industry in which the firm is engaged. The firms in a competitive market are price takers. • None has any market power - the ability to control the market price of the product it sells. • A firm's individual supply curve is a very small - and inconsequential - part of market supply.
    [Show full text]
  • Outline 1. Profit Maximization: Monopoly 2. Price Discrimination 3
    Economics 101A (Lecture 19) Stefano DellaVigna April 3, 2014 Outline 1. Profit Maximization: Monopoly 2. Price Discrimination 3. Oligopoly? 1Profit Maximization: Monopoly Nicholson, Ch. 11, pp. 371-380 • Nicholson, Ch. 14, pp. 501-510 • Perfect competition. Firms small • Monopoly. One, large firm. Firm sets price to • maximize profits. What does it mean to set prices? • Firm chooses demand given by = () • (OR: firm sets quantity .Price ()= 1 ()) • − Write maximization with respect to • Firm maximizes profits, that is, revenue minus costs: • max () () − Notice ()= 1 () • − First order condition: • () + () ()=0 0 − 0 or () 0 () 1 − = 0 () = − − Compare with f.o.c. in perfect competition • Check s.o.c. • Elasticity of demand determines markup: • — very elastic demand low mark-up → — relatively inelastic demand higher mark-up → Graphically, is where marginal revenue () + () • ∗ 0 equals marginal cost (0 ()) ¡ ¢ Find on demand function • Example. • Linear inverse demand function = • − Linear costs: ()= with 0 • Maximization: • max ( ) − − Solution: • ( )= − ∗ 2 and + ( )= − = ∗ − 2 2 s.o.c. • Figure • Comparative statics: • — Change in marginal cost — Shiftindemandcurve Monopoly profits • Case 1. High profits • Case 2. No profits • Welfare consequences of monopoly • — Too little production — Too high prices Graphical analysis • 2 Price Discrimination Nicholson, Ch. 14, pp. 513-519 • Restriction of contract space: • — So far, one price for all consumers. But: — Can sell at different prices to differing consumers
    [Show full text]
  • Profit Maximization
    PROFIT MAXIMIZATION [See Chap 11] 1 Profit Maximization • A profit-maximizing firm chooses both its inputs and its outputs with the goal of achieving maximum economic profits 2 Model • Firm has inputs (z 1,z 2). Prices (r 1,r 2). – Price taker on input market. • Firm has output q=f(z 1,z 2). Price p. – Price taker in output market. • Firm’s problem: – Choose output q and inputs (z 1,z 2) to maximise profits. Where: π = pq - r1z1 – r2z2 3 1 One-Step Solution • Choose (z 1,z 2) to maximise π = pf(z 1,z 2) - r1z1 – r2z2 • This is unconstrained maximization problem. • FOCs are ∂ ( , ) ∂ ( , ) f z1 z2 = f z1 z2 = p r1 and p r2 z1 z2 • Together these yield optimal inputs zi*(p,r 1,r 2). • Output is q*(p,r 1,r 2) = f(z 1*, z2*). This is usually called the supply function. π • Profit is (p,r1,r 2) = pq* - r1z1* - r2z2* 4 1/3 1/3 Example: f(z 1,z 2)=z 1 z2 π 1/3 1/3 • Profit is = pz 1 z2 - r1z1 – r2z2 • FOCs are 1 1 pz − 3/2 z 3/1 = r and pz 3/1 z − 3/2 = r 3 1 2 1 3 1 2 2 • Solving these two eqns, optimal inputs are 3 3 * = 1 p * = 1 p z1 ( p,r1,r2 ) 2 and z2 ( p,r1, r2 ) 2 27 r1 r2 27 1rr 2 • Optimal output 2 * = * 3/1 * 3/1 = 1 p q ( p, r1,r2 ) (z1 ) (z2 ) 9 1rr 2 • Profits 3 π * = * − * − * = 1 p ( p, r1,r2 ) pq 1zr 1 r2 z2 27 1rr 2 5 Two-Step Solution Step 1: Find cheapest way to obtain output q.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Power and Monopoly Introduction 9
    9 Market Power and Monopoly Introduction 9 Chapter Outline 9.1 Sources of Market Power 9.2 Market Power and Marginal Revenue 9.3 Profit Maximization for a Firm with Market Power 9.4 How a Firm with Market Power Reacts to Market Changes 9.5 The Winners and Losers from Market Power 9.6 Governments and Market Power: Regulation, Antitrust, and Innovation 9.7 Conclusion Introduction 9 In the real world, there are very few examples of perfectly competitive industries. Firms often have market power, or an ability to influence the market price of a product. The most extreme example is a monopoly, or a market served by only one firm. • A monopolist is the sole supplier (and price setter) of a good in a market. Firms with market power behave in different ways from those in perfect competition. Sources of Market Power 9.1 The key difference between perfect competition and a market structure in which firms have pricing power is the presence of barriers to entry, or factors that prevent entry into the market with large producer surplus. • Normally, positive producer surplus in the long run will induce additional firms to enter the market until it is driven to zero. • The presence of barriers to entry means that firms in the market may be able to maintain positive producer surplus indefinitely. Sources of Market Power 9.1 Extreme Scale Economies: Natural Monopoly One common barrier to entry results from a production process that exhibits economies of scale at every quantity level • Long-run average total cost curve is downward sloping; diseconomies never emerge.
    [Show full text]
  • A Little Algebraic Insight on Profit Maximization
    ANTITRUST LAW: CASE DEVELOPMENT AND LITIGATION STRATEGY Dale Collins Unit 1: Introduction to Price Fixing: Legal and Economic Foundations NYU School of Law A LITTLE ALGEBRAIC INSIGHT ON PROFIT MAXIMIZATION Let p * and q* be the profit-maximizing price and the associated profit-maximizing quantity. (Remember that prices and quantities are related to one another through the firm’s (residual) demand curve as shown in the diagram.) If fixed costs are zero and marginal cost is a constant c, then profits * are: **pq**cq (1) Let p be a positive increase in price and q be the associated reduction in the profit- maximizing quantity, so that pp is the new price and qq is the new quantity. Since by definition p * and q *are the profit-maximizing price and quantity, the firm’s profits at these prices must be at least equal to if not greater than the firm’s profits at any other price, that is, pq**cq** pp qq** cq q. (2) Expanding the right-hand side of Equation 2 yields: pq**cq**pq**pqqp**pqcq cq. (3) Cancelling terms that appear on both sides of the equation 0*pqqp* pqcq (4) and rearranging 0*pq qq pc*. (5) ANTITRUST LAW: CASE DEVELOPMENT AND LITIGATION STRATEGY Dale Collins Unit 1: Introduction to Price Fixing: Legal and Economic Foundations NYU School of Law Equation 5 has an important and straightforward interpretation: since the right-hand side is no more than zero, the gain in profits resulting from the price increase on the decreased quantity of sales pq * q can be no more than the loss of margin on the lost sales qp *.c At best, the firm breaks even on the price increase and it could well lose money.
    [Show full text]