Issue 5___Article 10.Pdf (1.641Mb)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Issue 5___Article 10.Pdf (1.641Mb) 113 i an approach entails risks, ant risks simply allows so- Equitable Efforts and n our opinion, "reciprocal lg of efforts and sacrifices Rejoinder t also clarifies many issues • Lance Compa & Paul J. Baicich >n of Union and Worker in fact achieve a real Drity at Eastern, and we 2 shared by all unions. It f unions are to adequately worthy of emulation. That there will not be serious lways be a tremendous representatives of its rs subject to many forces Most of Randy Barber and Andrew R. Banks' response to our tat Eastern management analysis of the "District 100 model" exaggerates our arguments, then VI official has observed: goes on to attack the exaggerated versions. In charging us with 2 closet. But they're still "inflexible and unthinking 'fightback' and 'no concessions' rhetoric": e them." • They imply, in relation to the blocking of the sale of workers' ptics would have unions common stock, that we say "the union arbitrarily decided that >m approach to the very it didn't want them to be able to recover some of their money ly condemn unions to for two years." the "real" District 100 • They assert that we "argue that the IAM'S agreement has no and believe that this is value simply by saying that it leaves 'real control firmly in Air Lines. We hope that management hands! " J the District 100 Model them. • They say that we "argue against such an agreement on the grounds that the union did not gain complete control of the company" • They suggest that we would have preferred that Eastern employees be "sacrificial lambs" to dramatize the crisis in the industry. • They charge us with holding that "all forms of change in company-union relations are bad." 114 LABOR RESEARCH REVIEW Barber and Banks characterize these arguments, which they impute to us, as "fear-laden," "misleading," "ludicrous," "absurd" and "profoundly conservative." They well may be, but they are not the arguments we made. Detailing a response to each of these charges would be repetitive. We urge the reader to re-read our article for what we actually said on these points. A few other points, nevertheless, need further clarification: 1) It was imprecise on our part to say that Eastern workers were given "watered stock." In Wall Street parlance, it is indeed the existing stockholders whose stock is watered upon the issuance of new shares. But earnings per share are diluted for all stockholders, new and old. It is not just a coincidence that the stock now being sold to workers at a fixed rate of $6.00 per share, hovers around $4.50 per share on the market—a 25% drop. 2) Of the $260 million in the "preferred stock trust" (we find the term imprecise; it is actually a profit-sharing pot), Barber and Banks assert that "all of this money is in fact secured" and would be repaid if the company went out of business tomorrow. But the fact that the debt would be covered if the company liquidated its assets tomorrow only means that it is secure for the moment, not that it is secured for the future as well. Eastern reported a net loss of $28.1 million in the first quarter of 1984. Based on EAL's net worth of $176 million, continued losses at that rate would wipe out the preferred stock trust in six quarters. 3) Barber and Banks point out that the union achieved the right of approval of the 1984 Eastern Business Plan. We think we gave that feature of the agreement the attention it deserved. A "Business Plan" is a mix of scenarios, good intentions, desirable results and bright ideas, all showing how7 a company is going to do the best it can in the coming year. A "veto" over the Business Plan has no practical meaning. At any rate, the union approved the Business Plan, so here we are. 4) Our criticism of the pension plan was not because we belittle union attempts to control them. In voting for the contract back in March 1983, I AM workers were given every reason to believe that they would have 50% of the pension board members. (See Barber's excellent report on this and on the company's subsequent evasion in Labor Research Review, No. 4.) Getting two union votes out of five, nine months after the company has agreed to two union seats on a four-member board is a step backward. It is better than none, and is commendable for that, but that is all. 5) We neglected to include any reference to the unionized lead- man responsibilities in our original piece. This has long been a goal of the District and of the Bryan administration in particular, and has merit. Nowhere, however, does the lead have "complete control of i-^i :;';•••;, ,«»?,. ,,• ^tV. ««MiB*»|&& « laJ^^^ KM ^s^£^te.^aib^a^duLfcfa«^ :W The 1AM District 100 "Model—A Debate 115 : arguments, which they impute the work process." The lead does not control manpower—the size ," "ludicrous," "absurd" and of the crew that is to work under his leadership and direction. As 11 may be, but they are not the to the Washington National Airport situation, the increase in lead- Donse to each of these charges man responsibilities began in June '83, and served as an initial T to re-read our article for what prototype for the system. It preceded the December agreemeent by 6 months. leed further clarification: 6)- Finally, we concur with Barber and Banks that "the real say that Eastern workers were problem" we have with the Eastern agreement is that "it represents arlance, it is indeed the existing a threatening and potentially far-reaching development." Taken as d upon the issuance of new a model tor all unions to emulate, concessions bargaining for uted for all stockholders, new employee stock ownership and participation in management :hat the stock now being sold threatej is to turn the American labor movement into a company ir share, hovers around $4.50 unl a movement, where each union is devoted to the success of a P- single capitalist enterprise. >rred stock trust" (we find the Tiiese are difficult times for the labor movement. Barber and Banks haring pot), Barber and Banks correctly point out that "static solutions are not producing secured" and would be repaid demonstrable gains." In this context, it is tempting to seek what ^morrow. But the fact that the appears to be bold innovations. But is what Banks and Barber liquidated its assets tomorrow advocate really so new? loment, not that it is secured In the 1920s there was a rage for "New Capitalism" inside and ed a net loss of $28.1 million outside the labor movement. The entire labor movement was pressed Mis net worth of $ 176 million, to adopt a bold approach to collective bargaining, which was termed >e out the preferred stock trust "the higher strategy of labor." Many union leaders saw it as their salvation. Enthusiasm grew for such initiatives as the B & O Plan, the union achieved the right where workers exchanged economic concessions for promises of job ness Plan. We think we gave security and joint participation in day-to-day operations. In 1925, ition it deserved. A "Business President Green of the AFL maintained that "organized labor is ;ntions, desirable results and coming to believe that its best interests are promoted through concord any is going to do the best it rather than by conflict." The AFL Executive Council was moved to er the Business Plan has no announce in 1928 that "At no time in its history has the trade union n approved the Business Plan, had greater influence in industrial circles. The constructive policies which we advocate and follow challenge the attention and respect i was not because we belittle of employers in this country and abroad. ." •ting for the contract back in Within a decade, American workers rendered judgement on the every reason to believe that "higher strategy of labor." Industrial unionism, general strikes, sit- oard members. (See Barber's downs, mass community organizing campaigns, innovative political mpany's subsequent evasion action and other policies of aggressive struggle against the employers tting two union votes out of brought millions of workers into the new unions of the CIO, and as agreed to two union seats forced the AFL to shake off its lethargy and organize millions more. ward. It is better than none, We are not taking refuge in an iron law of history. There is none. t is all. Labor's predicament is difficult, and no easy extrication is presently rence to the unionized lead- in view. But American workers move their unions forward in spurts, ce. This has long been a goal not at a steady velocity. The unrelenting employer attacks on workers Oration in particular, and has and unions could well be answered by a new outpouring of class- d have "complete control of conscious, aggressive trade unionism, breaking through barriers in 116 LABOR RESEARCH REVIEW organizing and political action. But this cannot happen if workers are told that reciprocal bargaining for equality of sacrifice and participation in management is the solution to their problems. We are not talking about static solutions at all. We are talking about some of the basic precepts of American trade unionism. Call it old- fashioned; that is not necessarily perjorative. And, it is no more old- fashioned than Barber and Banks' revival of "New Capitalism" pro­ posals. We welcome the debate on these issues. In the end, as they should, rank-and-file union members will decide who is correct.
Recommended publications
  • The Direct Listing As a Competitor of the Traditional Ipo
    The Direct Listing As a Competitor of the Traditional Ipo Research Paper – Law & Economics Course (IUS/05) Degree: Economics & Business, Dipartimento di Economia e Finanza Academic Year: 2019-2020 Name: Ludovico Morera Student Number: 216721 Supervisor: Prof. Pierluigi Matera The Direct Listing as a Competitor of the Traditional Ipo 2 Abstract In 2018, Spotify SA broke into the NYSE through an unusual direct listing, allowing it to become a publicly traded company without the high underwriting costs of a traditional Initial Public Offering that often deter companies from requesting to list. In order for such procedure to be possible, Spotify had to work closely with NYSE and SEC staff, which allowed for some amendments to their implementations of the Securities Act and the Securities Exchange Act. In this way, Spotify’s listing was done within the limits imposed by the U.S. market authorities. Several rumours concerning the direct listing arose, speculating that it may disrupt the American going public market and get past the standard firm-commitment underwriting procedures. This paper argues that these beliefs are largely wrong given the current regulatory limitations and tries to clarify for what firms direct listing is actually suitable. Furthermore, unlike the United Kingdom whose public exchanges have some experience, the NYSE faced such event for the first time; it follows that liability provisions under § 11 of the securities Act of 1933 may be attributed in different ways, especially due to the absence of an underwriter that may be held liable in case of material misstatements and omissions upon the registered documents. I find out that the direct listing can substitute the traditional IPO partially and only a restricted group of firms with some specific features could successfully do without an underwriter.
    [Show full text]
  • The Financial Provisions of the New Washington Business Corporation Act [Part 1]
    Washington Law Review Volume 41 Number 2 4-1-1966 The Financial Provisions of the New Washington Business Corporation Act [Part 1] Richard O. Kummert University of Washington School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.uw.edu/wlr Part of the Business Organizations Law Commons Recommended Citation Richard O. Kummert, The Financial Provisions of the New Washington Business Corporation Act [Part 1], 41 Wash. L. Rev. 207 (1966). Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.uw.edu/wlr/vol41/iss2/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Reviews and Journals at UW Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Washington Law Review by an authorized editor of UW Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE FINANCIAL PROVISIONS OF TIE NEW WASHINGTON BUSINESS CORPORATION ACT RICHARD 0. KUMIERT* The Model Business CorporationAct adopted by Washington during the 1965 Legislative Session becomes effective July 1, 1967. The finan- cial provisions of the New Act are in many respects very complex and will be a matter of concern to local counsel in their efforts to prospec- tively arrange for the transition from the old to the New Act. The author, in the following pages, which represent the first half of a two- part article, explores the general philosophy, policy decisions and detailed provisions of the financial sections of the New Act. The second half of the article will be published in a subsequent issue of the Review.** On March 20, 1965, Governor Evans approved a new Business Corporation Act for the State of Washington.' The New Act adopts with relatively few changes the Model Business Corporation Act2 pre- *Associate Professor Law, University of Washington.
    [Show full text]
  • Activist Shareholders, Corporate Directors, and Institutional Investment: Some Lessons from the Robber Barons Allen D
    Washington and Lee Law Review Volume 50 | Issue 3 Article 4 Summer 6-1-1993 Activist Shareholders, Corporate Directors, And Institutional Investment: Some Lessons From The Robber Barons Allen D. Boyer Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarlycommons.law.wlu.edu/wlulr Part of the Business Organizations Law Commons Recommended Citation Allen D. Boyer, Activist Shareholders, Corporate Directors, And Institutional Investment: Some Lessons From The Robber Barons, 50 Wash. & Lee L. Rev. 977 (1993), https://scholarlycommons.law.wlu.edu/wlulr/vol50/iss3/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Washington and Lee Law Review at Washington & Lee University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Washington and Lee Law Review by an authorized editor of Washington & Lee University School of Law Scholarly Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ARTICLES ACTIVIST SHAREHOLDERS, CORPORATE DIRECTORS, AND INSTITUTIONAL INVESTMENT: SOME LESSONS FROM THE ROBBER BARONS ALLEN D. BOYER* History never repeats itself, but it rhymes. -Mark Twain I. INTRODUCTION American business has crossed, with little celebration, an economic watershed. As of this decade, 53 percent of the equity in American cor- porations has passed into the hands of institutional shareholders: public pension funds, private pension funds, mutual funds, insurance companies, foundations, and managed trust funds.' In the nation's largest fifty companies, institutional investors own 50.1 percent of outstanding shares. In the next largest fifty companies, they own 59.2 percent of the shares. In some leading industries, the concentration is higher: 56 percent of the aerospace industry, 59 percent of the electrical industry, and 61 percent of the transportation industry.
    [Show full text]
  • Preferred Stock-Law and Draftsmanship T Richard M
    1954J Preferred Stock-Law and Draftsmanship t Richard M. Buxbaum* pREFERRED STOCK is an anomalous security. It is a debt security when it claims certain absolute rights, especially its right to an accumulated return or to throw the enterprise into receivership for failing to meet its obligations. It is an equity security when it tries to control the enterprise through a practical voting procedure or to share in excess distributions of corporate profits.' Of course, a share of preferred stock is actually a com- posite of many rights. It is entitled to dividends at a set rate which prob- ably accumulate if they are not paid. It is next in line after creditors if the enterprise is liquidated and may share exclusively to a limited amount or participate in any distribution. It is probably subject to redemption and more likely than not has the supposed benefit of a sinking fund to regulate this redemption. A substantial percentage of contemporary issues are con- vertible into common stock. It may, but probably does not, have preemp- tive rights in new stock issues. It probably cannot vote in the election of the corporate management but may have some contingent voting rights for certain proposed actions and upon default in dividend payments. Some of these rights are "inherent;" others are granted by statute; still others are voluntary contractual provisions. The purpose of this paper is to examine these rights; to see the extent to which the share contract creates and pro- tects them and the extent to which the law details them when the share contract is defective.
    [Show full text]
  • Securities Markets 1929-1959 and the S.E.C
    ADVANCEl Hold for Delivery SECURITIES MARKETS 1929-1959 AND THE S.E.C. Address of Edward N. Gadsby Chairman Securities and Exchange Commission before the National Press Club Washington, D. C. July 16, 1959 SECURITIES MARKETS 1929-1959 AND THE S.E.C. Two weeks ago the Securities and Exchange Commission celebrated its twenty-fifth birthday. On July 2, 1934, the original five Commissioners held their first meeting here in Washington and elected Honorable Joseph P. Kennedy as their Chairman. It was their privilege to chart the early courses of an entirely new venture by the Federal Government in the economic activities of our country. I do not intend to try to review the experiences and activities of the Commission or to attempt to evaluate the Commission's work under the Federal securities laws during the past quarter century. Such material has been and will be adequately covered on other occasions. I intend rather to concern myself principally with two questions which I have been asked on several occasions in recent weeks, first, whether the legislation now on the books is adequate to prevent a serious collapse in the market, and second, what can the Commission do to avert such a contingency. The fact that such questions can be asked is enough to raise doubt whether the public and even the press have not come to take this Commission for something which we are not and to expect accomplish- ments of us which we cannot perform and were never intended to perform. To begin with, I think I should remind you that the Commission cannot, and I doubt whether anyone else can, regulate or control the powerful, fundamental forces which operate to cause major market movements.
    [Show full text]
  • Nova Law Review
    Nova Law Review Volume 15, Issue 3 1991 Article 13 The Financial Provisions of Florida’s New Business Corporation Act-The Model Act with Anti-Takeover Twists David S. Felman∗ ∗ Copyright c 1991 by the authors. Nova Law Review is produced by The Berkeley Electronic Press (bepress). https://nsuworks.nova.edu/nlr The Financial Provisions of Florida’s New Business Corporation Act-The Model Act with Anti-Takeover Twists David S. Felman Abstract Effective July 1, 1990, the Florida Legislature revamped Florida’s corporate law by enacting the Florida Business Corporation Act.’ KEYWORDS: takeover, act, model Felman: The Financial Provisions of Florida's New Business Corporation Ac The Financial Provisions of Florida's New Business Corporation Act-The Model Act with Anti-Takeover Twists David S. Felman* I. INTRODUCTION Effective July 1, 1990, the Florida Legislature revamped Florida's corporate law by enacting the Florida Business Corporation Act.' Ex- cept for provisions concerning foreign corporations doing business in Florida, the Act generally applies only to corporations incorporated in Florida.2 The Act repeals the Florida General Corporation Act,3 and with significant exceptions, adopts the Revised Model Business Corpo- ration Act.4 This article addresses the financial provisions in chapter VI * B.A., Wake Forest University, 1979; J.D., Duke University School of Law, 1982; partner, Glenn, Rasmussen, Fogarty, Merryday & Russo, Tampa, Florida. The author co-chaired the committee of The Florida Bar responsible for drafting proposed technical amendments to the Business Corporations Act that are now pending in the Florida Legislature. The author gratefully acknowledges the suggestions and assistance of Bob Ras- mussen, Sharon Docherty, and Betty Atkins of his firm, and Professors Stuart Cohn of the University of Florida School of Law and Marleen O'Connor of the Stetson Univer- sity School of Law.
    [Show full text]
  • Shares of Stock Without Par Value James H
    NORTH CAROLINA LAW REVIEW Volume 1 | Number 1 Article 5 1922 Shares of Stock without Par Value James H. Pou Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.unc.edu/nclr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation James H. Pou, Shares of Stock without Par Value, 1 N.C. L. Rev. 26 (1922). Available at: http://scholarship.law.unc.edu/nclr/vol1/iss1/5 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Carolina Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in North Carolina Law Review by an authorized administrator of Carolina Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE NORTH CAROLINA LAW REVIEW to retain the power to use the club of the Sherman Law to protect the common people against possible evils of monopoly. In view of this sentiment, no poli- tician would probably dare to advocate such an amendment of the Sherman Law. It is suggested that the trade associations might send their information directly to some governmental agency such as the Department of Commerce, which would undertake to publish this information broadcast and which would also authorize co-operation and standardization under government supervision. This method would undoubtedly supplement the internal activities of the trade associations, but it could not supplant them entirely, for trade associations have many functions that the government could not perform. The most probable solution seems to lie in distinguishing the activities of the Hardwood Association from the activities of other similar associations. Sub- tract from the principal case the somewhat inept letters of the manager of statistics and the accidental rise in prices that happened to be contemporaneous with the letters and it is doubtful whether the Supreme Court would have reached the same decision.
    [Show full text]
  • The Establishment of Liability on Watered Stock in Missouri
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by Washington University St. Louis: Open Scholarship Washington University Law Review Volume 1952 Issue 4 1952 The Establishment of Liability on Watered Stock in Missouri A. E. S. Schmid Washington University School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation A. E. S. Schmid, The Establishment of Liability on Watered Stock in Missouri, 1952 WASH. U. L. Q. 559 (1952). Available at: https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview/vol1952/iss4/3 This Note is brought to you for free and open access by the Law School at Washington University Open Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Washington University Law Review by an authorized administrator of Washington University Open Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. NOTES THE ESTABLISHMENT OF LIABILITY ON WATERED STOCK IN MISSOURI INTRODUCTION It has been a long-established policy in Missouri that the holders of "watered" stock in a corporation or their transferees with notice will be liable under certain circumstances to the creditors of the company in the event that the company becomes insolvent and there are no corporate assets upon which to levy.1 Connected with that policy, however, are at least two problems. One involves deciding whether or not a particular stockholder should be classed as a watered stockholder. Stated another way, the court must decide whether the service rendered or the prop- erty given by the stockholder in exchange for a certain number of purportedly full paid and non-assessable par value shares 2 was sufficient to justify the corporation's having paid for it with that amount of stock.
    [Show full text]
  • Copyrighted Material
    INDEX 363 Autocorrelation, 324 Capital asset pricing model A Average collection period, 263 (CAPM) method, 186 Abnormal spoilage, 292 Average fixed cost (AFC), 130 Capital budgeting, 227 Absolute advantage, 138 Average total cost (ATC), 130 Accounting rate of return Absorption (full) costing, 312, Average variable cost (AVC), (ARR) method, 229 315 130 Excess present value Accelerator theory, 135 Avoidable costs, 228, 313 (profitability) index, 230 Access controls, 77, 92 Internal rate of return (IRR) B Accounting rate of return method, 230 (ARR), 229 Backflush costing, 174 Net present value (NPV) Accounts payable (trade credit), Backup and recovery, 78, 93 method, 229 176 Balance of payments, 139 Capital budgeting function, 167 Accounts receivable financing, Balanced scorecard, 256 Capital rationing, 231 178 Banker’s acceptance, 171 Capital surplus, 44 Activity-based budgeting, 312, Batch (control) total, 93 Carrying costs, 173 319 Batch processing, 74 Cartridge tape, 71 Activity-based costing (ABC), Batch-level costs, 293 Cash conversion cycle, 168 292 Benchmarking, 269, 313 Cash flow hedge, 222 Activity-based management, 294 Benchmarks, 269 Cash flow ROI, 262 Advantages, 181 Best practices, 269 Cash management, 169 Advantages of issuing common Bit, 75 Cause-and-effect, 270 stock, 182 Black-Scholes option-pricing Fishbone, 270 Advantages of issuing preferred model, 223 Ishikawa, 270 stock, 183 Blanket inventory lien, 178 Central processing unit, 70 Agency Bonds Centralized processing, 75 Partnership relationships, 29, 32 Amortization
    [Show full text]
  • California Bar Examination – Essay Questions
    California Bar Examination Essay Questions and Selected Answers July 2015 The State Bar Of California Committee of Bar Examiners/Office of Admissions 180 Howard Street • San Francisco, CA 94105-1639 • (415) 538-2300 845 S. Figueroa Street • Los Angeles, CA 90017-2515 • (213) 765-1500 ESSAY QUESTIONS AND SELECTED ANSWERS JULY 2015 CALIFORNIA BAR EXAMINATION This publication contains the six essay questions from the July 2015 California Bar Examination and two selected answers for each question. The answers were assigned high grades and were written by applicants who passed the examination after one read. The answers were produced as submitted by the applicant, except that minor corrections in spelling and punctuation were made for ease in reading. They are reproduced here with the consent of the authors. Question Number Subject 1. Civil Procedure 2. Real Property 3. Criminal Law and Procedure 4. Community Property 5. Business Associations/ Professional Responsibility 6. Constitutional Law/Real Property ESSAY EXAMINATION INSTRUCTIONS Your answer should demonstrate your ability to analyze the facts in the question, to tell the difference between material facts and immaterial facts, and to discern the points of law and fact upon which the case turns. Your answer should show that you know and understand the pertinent principles and theories of law, their qualifications and limitations, and their relationships to each other. Your answer should evidence your ability to apply the law to the given facts and to reason in a logical, lawyer-like manner from the premises you adopt to a sound conclusion. Do not merely show that you remember legal principles.
    [Show full text]
  • The Modernization of Corporation Law, 1920-1940
    THE MODERNIZATION OF CORPORATION LAW, 1920-1940 Harwell Wells* INTRODUCTION What forces shape corporation law? The basic framework that produces corporation law in the United States is readily apparent. Under the United States’ system of corporate law federalism,1 each state has the power to make its own laws concerning how corporations are to be governed, and a corporation may then select which state’s law will regulate its internal affairs by incorporating in that state, even if the corporation is based elsewhere.2 Identifying this framework does not, however, explain how such basic arrangements set in motion the complex processes that have over the past century produced modern corporation law. When explaining corporation law’s evolution, scholars have identified as overwhelmingly important a consequence of corporation law federalism: * J.D., Ph.D., Assistant Professor of Law, Temple University Beasley School of Law. My thanks to Jane Baron, David Hoffman, Gregory Mark, Lawrence Mitchell, Robert Thompson, and Wyatt Wells, for helpful comments, Sarah Maguire and Josette Oakley for excellent research assistance, and the Temple University Beasley School of Law for research support for this project. Special thanks to John Necci and his staff at the Temple University Law Library and to Pegeen Bassett of the Northwestern University Law Library for locating material on Illinois corporation law. © 2008 Harwell Wells. 1. See Gregory Mark, The Court and the Corporation: Jurisprudence, Localism, and Federalism, 1997 SUP. CT. REV. 403 (providing a historical account of the development of corporate law federalism); Brett H. McDonnell, Two Cheers for Corporate Law Federalism, 30 J. CORP.
    [Show full text]
  • Legal Significance of "Capital Stock"
    Washington Law Review Volume 32 Number 1 3-1-1957 Legal Significance of "Capital Stock" J. Gordon Gose University of Washington School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.uw.edu/wlr Digital Par t of the Business Organizations Law Commons Commons Network Recommended Citation Logo J. G. Gose, Legal Significance of "Capital Stock", 32 Wash. L. Rev. & St. B.J. 1 (1957). Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.uw.edu/wlr/vol32/iss1/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Reviews and Journals at UW Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Washington Law Review by an authorized editor of UW Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. WASHINGTON LAW REVIEW AND STATE BAR JOURNAL VOLUME 32 SPRING, 1957 NUMBER 1 LEGAL SIGNIFICANCE OF "CAPITAL STOCK" J. GORDON GOSE* "The capital stock of banks," said the celebrated early American jurist, Judge Story, in a case decided in 1824, "is to be deemed a pledge or a trust fund for the payment of the debts contracted by the bank. The public, as well as the legislature, has always supposed this to be a fund appropriated for such purpose. The charter relieves [the shareholders] of personal responsibility and substitutes the capital stock in its stead. Credit is universally given to this fund by the public, as the only means of repayment. During the existence of the corpora- tion it is the sole property of the corporation, and can be applied only according to its charter, that is as a fund for the payment of its debts..."' It is exceedingly doubtful that any portion of this classic statement was accurate in law or in fact when made, if taken literally.
    [Show full text]