Editor's Introduction

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Editor's Introduction FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST.LOUIS overnight interbank rate does not necessarily ensure Editor’s Introduction a restrictive monetary policy.” The high nominal rates in the 1960s and 1970s did not indicate a Daniel L. Thornton restrictive policy because, as Jordan notes, “the infla- tion premium in interest rates was rising faster than IN HONOR OF DARRYL FRANCIS the Committee was raising the overnight policy rate.” Jordan then suggests that, “in the 1999-2000 environ- erry Jordan and Allan Meltzer honor Darryl ment, raising the overnight policy rate did not indi- Francis by chronicling his tenure as president cate that the stance of policy had become more Jof the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, espe- restrictive” because the return to capital was rising cially his role as a member of the Federal Open faster than the policy rate. Real interest rates, Jordan Market Committee (FOMC). Both articles are valu- notes, are often the manifestation of economic able, not only as assessments of past policy errors forces that are independent of Fed policy. If market and what might have occurred had the FOMC forces move real interest rates, and consequently chosen the path that Darryl outlined, but also as a nominal interest rates, faster than policymakers warning for current policy. move the target, Jordan notes that the result will be Jerry Jordan recalls that Darryl Francis was faster money growth and quite likely higher inflation. frank, clear minded, and resolute. He referred to The third parallel is the vital role that “the Francis as a maverick—“an independent individual maverick, the dissenter, the sometimes lonely voice who refuses to conform with his group.” Jordan in the crowd” plays in the continuing evolution of argues that Francis played a key role in the evolu- policythinking and policymaking. And so Jordan tion of monetary policymaking within the Federal reminds us of Darryl Francis’s exceptional courage Reserve. In particular, Jordan notes that Francis was and foresight as he filled this role during a very instrumental in the FOMC’s decision to (i) adopt a important and challenging period of Federal Reserve more strategic operating directive and (ii) include history. monetary aggregates in its operating procedure. Allan Meltzer also praises Darryl Francis’s role He notes, however, that the strategic objectives— in the evolution of monetary policymaking in the reducing inflation and encouraging sustainable late 1960s and early 1970s. During the 1960s and economic growth and balance of payments equi- 1970s, as Meltzer notes, Keynesian economics was librium—sounded a lot like “motherhood and apple the reigning orthodoxy. Fiscal policy was the prin- pie,” and the FOMC’s apparent greater reliance on cipal tool of economic stabilization. Monetary policy monetary aggregates seems now to have been just and, more importantly, money growth were ineffec- a facade. Despite Francis’s courage and leadership, tive in reducing inflation—a policy choice between it was not until 1979, three years after Darryl left the full employment and price stability along a stable Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, that the FOMC Phillips curve. finally was “persuaded that inflation was a monetary Meltzer recalls that a furious debate arose phenomenon,” correctable only by slow money over Friedman and Meiselman’s (1963) finding growth. that the money multiplier was more stable that the Jordan suggests that there are three parallels Keynesian investment multiplier and Andersen between Darryl Francis’s FOMC experience and the and Jordan’s (1968) demonstration that changes in FOMC experience today. First is the importance of the money stock had larger and more predictable “maintaining an overriding strategic objective for effects on nominal gross national product than did price stability.” Jordan notes that, in spite of the fact changes in government expenditures. He notes that that the FOMC has made it clear that “the ultimate “at the height of the controversy in the late 1960s objective of monetary policy is to maximize long- and early 1970s, Darryl Francis was the principal, run growth by preserving a stable purchasing power and usually only, spokesman who challenged this of money,” there is a common perception that there orthodoxy at meetings of the Federal Open Market is a trade-off between growth and inflation. Committee.” The second parallel is that “raising a nominal Noting the tendency to associate high and rising interest rates with restrictive monetary policy, Daniel Thornton is a vice president and economist at the Federal Meltzer notes that Darryl Francis stood alone in Reserve Bank of St. Louis. recommending slower money growth to reduce JULY/AUGUST 2001 7 R EVIEW inflation in the late 1960s. Believing that a more for a better understanding of monetary policy and restrictive fiscal policy, not a slower rate of money its effectiveness. Questions addressed include the growth, would reduce inflation, Francis’s counter- following: How does the Fed move the federal funds parts on the FOMC favored what Meltzer terms rate? Is the effect of monetary policy completely “a fiscal solution to a monetary problem.” Specifi- reflected in the behavior of the overnight federal cally, they recommended a policy of reducing inter- funds rate, or does money have separate effects est rates to offset the effect of the then proposed on economic activity and inflation? Is systematic temporary 10 percent surtax on incomes. monetary policy effective, or must the monetary Noting that history suggests the neglect of authority surprise the market to have an effect? money was a “major mistake,” Meltzer uses the Could the practice of monetary policy be improved FOMC meeting transcripts at the time to offer this by having the central bank commit to a time path prediction: “If Darryl’s advice had been taken, we for the interbank rate? would have avoided the great inflation.” According Each paper or discussant comment is interesting to Meltzer, the failure to heed Darryl’s advice had in its own right. Nevertheless, I found reading them wide-ranging implications. He argues that, together a rewarding experience. Despite their very If the FOMC had acted on Francis’s recom- different themes, the papers overlap and interact mendations, the U.S. and much of the rest in a variety of interesting and, occasionally, unex- of the world would have avoided the worst pected ways. I highlight some of the most important of the Great Inflation. The Bretton Woods discussions and findings here. I encourage the System may not have survived, but it would reader to read all of the papers. My short summary have lasted longer. The relative price of oil does none of them justice. would not have fallen precipitately after the U.S. devaluation, so the oil shock might have The Central Bank’s Influence on been avoided, with positive consequences Interest Rates for productivity growth in the developed The first two conference papers deal with the countries. With greater certainty, inflation, issue of how the Fed influences the federal funds disinflation, and regulation would not have rate. According to convention, the Fed controls the destroyed the thrift industry. Perhaps, also, there would have been fewer petrodollars to funds rate through open market operations. Specif- recycle, less bank lending to Latin America, ically, the Trading Desk of the Federal Reserve Bank and no debt crisis in the 1980s. of New York (Desk) sells securities when the Fed desires to raise the funds rate and purchases securi- The important lesson to be learned from ties to reduce the rate. In recent years, however, the Darryl Francis and the period of monetary history Desk acknowledges doing nothing different when over which he served is that it is a mistake to the FOMC changes the funds rate target. ignore money growth when conducting monetary John Taylor begins his analysis with a detailed policy. Meltzer agues that this period and others discussion of the federal funds market and two serve as reminders that “it is impossible to have important changes that affect the demand for high and sustained inflation without monetary reserves—the virtual elimination of reserve require- accommodation.” ments as a consequence of banks “sweeping” reserv- He concludes that economic theory and expe- able deposits and the 1998 move to lagged reserve rience have shown that there have been times accounting. In addition, Taylor notes that, since when interest rates mislead policymakers when 1994, target changes have been announced imme- money growth did not: “Darryl Francis’s tenure diately upon making the decision, but after the Fed was one of those times. Fortunately, he recognized has carried out that day’s open market operations. the error. Unfortunately for us, and much of the Consequently, since 1994 it has been impossible rest of the world, his colleagues did not.” for the Fed to implement open market operations MONETARY POLICY IN THEORY AND to change the funds rate until the day following the PRACTICE announcement. After discussing these changes, Taylor presents The conference papers and discussants’ com- a simple model of the reserve market to illustrate ments cover a wide range of issues that are important how the funds rate can move when the FOMC 8 JULY/AUGUST 2001 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST.LOUIS announces a target change without the Desk carrying in advance of the announcement and others occur- out open market operations. Given the declining ring with a delay. importance of reserve requirements as a reason for Taylor also notes that the theoretical response holding deposit balances at the Fed, Taylor’s specifi- of the funds rate to a simulated shock to the demand cation for the demand for balances at the Fed is for balances at the Fed exhibits persistence that is motivated by Furfine’s (2000) model of a typical very similar to that of actual deviations of the funds optimizing bank.
Recommended publications
  • Open Mouth Operations: a Swiss Case Study Michael J
    Economic SYNOPSES short essays and reports on the economic issues of the day 2005 I Number 1 Open Mouth Operations: A Swiss Case Study Michael J. Dueker and Andreas Fischer early all central banks, other than those that peg Bank sought to implement the smallest initial rise in the an exchange rate, now explicitly communicate repo rate that would achieve their new target for the LIBOR. Npolicy changes through an announced target level The fact that the 3-month Swiss LIBOR rate immediately for a short-term interest rate. Notably, in 1999, the Swiss rose by the full 25 basis points, while the repo rate rose by National Bank replaced its monetary base target with an only about 15 basis points, suggests that the Swiss National operating target for the 3-month Swiss franc interbank Bank used open mouth operations to increase the rate lending (LIBOR) rate that the central bank adjusts as part spread above its usual level of 15 basis points. By the time of its strategy to maintain price stability. One question that of the second target change in September 2004, however, has arisen with interest rate targets is whether a central bank the Swiss National Bank did not achieve its objective of can cause the interest rate to move simply by expressing its raising the Swiss LIBOR rate by 25 basis points (to a level intention to establish a new target level—so-called open of 75 basis points) until it had raised the repo rate to a level mouth operations—or whether transactions of securities in of approximately 60 basis points—that is, not until the the central bank’s portfolio—open market operations—are typical rate spread of about 15 basis points was restored.
    [Show full text]
  • Explaining the Appearance of Open-Mouth Operations in the 1990S U.S
    Explaining the Appearance of Open-Mouth Operations in the 1990s U.S. Christopher Hanes [email protected] Department of Economics SUNY-Binghamton P.O. Box 6000 Binghamton, NY 13902 July 2018 Abstract: In the 1990s it became apparent that changes in the FOMC’s target rate could be implemented through announcements alone - “open mouth operations” - without adjustments to reserve supply or the discount rate. This cannot be explained by standard models of the Fed’s system of policy implementation at the time. It differed from experience in the 1970s, the earlier era of interest-rate targeting, though the structure of implementation appeared essentially similar. I explain the appearance of open-mouth operations as a consequence of longstanding Fed discount-window lending practices, interacting with a decrease after the 1970s in the relative importance of discount borrowing by small banks. Data on discount borrowing by large versus small banks in the 1980s-1990s and the 1970s support my explanation. JEL codes E43, E51, E52, G21. Thanks to James Clouse, Selva Demiralp, Cheryl Edwards, William English, Marvin Goodfried, Kenneth Kuttner and William Whitesell. - 1 - In the 1990s Federal Reserve staff found that market overnight rates changed when the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) signalled it had changed its target fed funds rate, even if the staff made no adjustment to the quantity of reserves supplied through open-market operations. Eventually the volume of bank deposits responded to interest rates through the usual “money demand” channels, and the Fed had to accommodate resulting changes in the quantity of reserves needed to satisfy fractional reserve requirements or clear payments.
    [Show full text]
  • Divorcing Money from Monetary Policy
    Todd Keister, Antoine Martin, and James McAndrews Divorcing Money from Monetary Policy • Many central banks operate in a way that 1.Introduction creates a tight link between money and monetary policy, as the supply of reserves onetary policy has traditionally been viewed as the must be set precisely in order to implement M process by which a central bank uses its influence over the target interest rate. the supply of money to promote its economic objectives. For example, Milton Friedman (1959, p. 24) defined the tools of • Because reserves play other key roles in the monetary policy to be those “powers that enable the [Federal economy, this link can generate tensions with Reserve] System to determine the total amount of money in central banks’ other objectives, particularly existence or to alter that amount.” In fact, the very term in periods of acute market stress. monetary policy suggests a central bank’s policy toward the supply of money or the level of some monetary aggregate. • An alternative approach to monetary policy In recent decades, however, central banks have moved away implementation can eliminate the tension from a direct focus on measures of the money supply. The between money and monetary policy primary focus of monetary policy has instead become the value by “divorcing” the quantity of reserves of a short-term interest rate. In the United States, for example, from the interest rate target. the Federal Reserve’s Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) announces a rate that it wishes to prevail in the federal funds market, where overnight loans are made among • By paying interest on reserve balances at commercial banks.
    [Show full text]
  • Expectations, Open Market Operations, and Changes in the Federal Funds
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST.LOUIS computation period. This has probably led to better Expectations, Open estimates of reserve requirements by the Trading Desk and the banks, but it has also eliminated the Market Operations, possibility of any contemporaneous response of required reserves to the interest rate. and Changes in the Another significant change made possible by computer technology is the ability of financial Federal Funds Rate institutions to efficiently “sweep” their consumers’ accounts from those with reserve requirements into John B. Taylor those without reserve requirements. These sweeps have allowed required reserve balances to decline he process through which Federal Reserve sharply from about $30 billion in 1990, to $15 bil- decisions about monetary policy are transmit- lion in 1996, to only about $5 to 6 billion today. As Tted to the federal funds market has changed a result, holding Fed balances to facilitate interbank significantly in recent years. In 1994 the Federal payments is of greater importance for many banks Open Market Committee (FOMC) began to issue than holding reserves for legal requirements. At the a public statement whenever it increased or de- same time, technology has improved the speed and creased its target for the federal funds rate. This accuracy with which banks can keep track of their target is now the focus of activities at the Trading payment inflows and outflows and thereby may Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. In have reduced the demand for Fed balances.3 particular, the FOMC directs the Trading Desk to In December 1999 the FOMC further expanded buy and sell securities so that conditions in the and clarified its public announcement policy.
    [Show full text]
  • New Tools for Central Bankers?
    A SYMPOSIUM OF VIEWS New Tools For Central Bankers? entral banks worldwide face criticism for the inability of their policies to restore the global economy to historic levels of economic activity. CCentral bank bond buying, it is often charged, has distorted financial markets. Negative real interest rates have weakened many banking sectors. At this summer’s Jackson Hole meeting, Federal Reserve Chair Janet Yellen proclaimed: “New policy tools, which helped the Federal Reserve respond to the financial crisis and Great Recession, are likely to remain useful in dealing with future downturns. Additional tools may be needed.” What new tools should the central bank community consider? Or has monetary policy been perceived too much as some kind of magical pill? Should fiscal and regulatory reforms come into play? THE MAGAZINE OF INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICY 220 I Street, N.E., Suite 200 Washington, D.C. 20002 More than forty noted experts share their views. Phone: 202-861-0791 Fax: 202-861-0790 www.international-economy.com [email protected] 6 THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY FALL 2016 The answer is not to transition … from the lead role in what essentially has been the equivalent of a “one-person show,” to playing a push central banks supporting role to politicians that finally step up to their economic governance responsibility and lift the con- even deeper into straints to a more comprehensive policy response. Absent such a pivot, the quest for new tools for cen- what has become an tral banks may be associated with a much more disturbing and durable development—that of seeing central banks increasingly “lose- shift from being part of the solution to becoming part of the problem.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy Implementation: Misconceptions and Their Consequences by Piti Disyatat
    BIS Working Papers No 269 Monetary policy implementation: Misconceptions and their consequences by Piti Disyatat Monetary and Economic Department December 2008 JEL codes: E40, E41, E51, E52, E58 Keywords: Monetary policy implementation, transmission mechanism, interest rates, money, liquidity effect, bank lending channel, sterilized intervention BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. Copies of publications are available from: Bank for International Settlements Press & Communications CH-4002 Basel, Switzerland E-mail: [email protected] Fax: +41 61 280 9100 and +41 61 280 8100 This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2008. All rights reserved. Limited extracts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISSN 1682-7678 (online) Abstract Despite constituting the very heart of the monetary transmission mechanism, widespread misconceptions still exist regarding how monetary policy is implemented. This paper highlights the key misconceptions in this regard and shows how they have compromised the understanding of important aspects of the monetary transmission mechanism. In particular, the misplaced emphasis on open market operations as the means through which monetary policy is implemented can give rise to inappropriate characterizations of monetary policy, as well as to ill-defined discussions of liquidity effects, the bank lending channel, and sterilized exchange rate intervention. JEL Classification: E40, E41, E51, E52, E58 Keywords: Monetary policy implementation, transmission mechanism, interest rates, money, liquidity effect, bank lending channel, sterilized intervention Monetary policy implementation: Misconceptions and their consequences iii Table of contents 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Do Central Banks Control the Price Level?”
    Some Thoughts on \Do Central Banks Control the Price Level?" Karl Whelan Presentation at FMM Conference School of Economics, University College Dublin October 28, 2020 Karl Whelan (UCD) Do Central Banks Control the Price Level? October 28, 2020 1 / 19 Do Central Banks Control the Price Level? An interesting question. For most of the past 40 years, the answer from most people would be \Yes ... of course". And there are loads of examples of situations where macroeconomic policy has produced (and ended) high inflation. But in recent years, central banks have failed to reach their inflation targets despite new \unconventional" monetary policies. Have central banks got the ammunition to get inflation back to their desired levels? My (two handed ...) answer: 1 Yes but current conventions (and current conditions) constrain them from taking the necessary actions. 2 But this doesn't matter because we can use fiscal policy instead. Karl Whelan (UCD) Do Central Banks Control the Price Level? October 28, 2020 2 / 19 Roadmap for the Talk 1 Micro price theory versus macro price theory 2 Why central banks? I Monetarism I The Phillips curve I Central bank independence 3 The current situation I Low equilibrium real interest rates and unconventional policies. I Helicopter drops? I Fiscal policy options Karl Whelan (UCD) Do Central Banks Control the Price Level? October 28, 2020 3 / 19 Micro Pricing Evidence versus Macro Confusion The price level is just an aggregation of loads of individual prices. Empirical microeconomics is an extremely successful discipline and is very good at explaining prices. Study after study confirms that prices are a function of 1 Demand 2 Supply 3 Market structure Changing market structures may play some role in determining the aggregate price level but for the economy of the whole, it is reasonable to asset that the dominant factor driving prices is the demand for goods and services and the capacity to supply them.
    [Show full text]
  • Nber Working Paper Series Monetary Policy in the Information Economy
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY IN THE INFORMATION ECONOMY Michael Woodford Working Paper 8674 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8674 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2001 Prepared for the “Symposium on Economic Policy for the Information Economy,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 30-September 1, 2001. I am especially grateful to Andy Brookes (RBNZ), Chuck Freedman (Bank of Canada), and Chris Ryan (RBA) for their unstinting efforts to educate me about the implementation of monetary policy at their respective central banks. Of course, none of them should be held responsible for the interpretations offered here. I would also like to thank David Archer, Alan Blinder, Kevin Clinton, Ben Friedman, David Gruen, Bob Hall, Spence Hilton, Mervyn King, Ken Kuttner, Larry Meyer, Hermann Remsperger, Lars Svensson, Bruce White and Julian Wright for helpful discussions, Gauti Eggertsson and Hong Li for research assistance, and the National Science Foundation for research support through a grant to the National Bureau of Economic Research. The views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2001 by Michael Woodford. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Monetary Policy in the Information Economy Michael Woodford NBER Working Paper No. 8674 December 2001 JEL No. E58 ABSTRACT This paper considers two challenges that improvements in private-sector information-processing capabilities may pose for the effectiveness of monetary policy.
    [Show full text]
  • Odyssean Forward Guidance in Monetary Policy: a Primer
    Odyssean forward guidance in monetary policy: A primer Jeffrey R. Campbell Introduction and summary with making its internal decision-making process The Federal Open Market Committee’s (FOMC) more transparent and therefore more forecastable. In monetary policy statement from its September 2013 this, they followed several foreign central banks that meeting reads in part: had already adopted explicit inflation targets. (See Bernanke and Woodford, 2005, for a review of inflation In particular, the Committee decided to keep targeting and its implementation outside the United the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to States.) The financial crisis dramatically accelerated 1/4 percent and currently anticipates that this ex- the transition to greater openness, and the FOMC’s ceptionally low range for the federal funds rate will be appropriate at least as long as the unem- ployment rate remains above 6-1/2 percent, infla- Jeffrey R. Campbell is a senior economist and research advisor tion between one and two years ahead is projected in the Economic Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and an external fellow at CentER, Tilburg to be no more than a half percentage point above University. The author is grateful to Marco Bassetto, Charlie the Committee’s 2 percent longer-run goal, and Evans, Jonas Fisher, Alejandro Justiniano, and Spencer Krane for many stimulating discussions on forward guidance and to longer-term inflation expectations continue to be Wouter den Haan, Alejandro Justiniano, and Dick Porter for well anchored.1 helpful editorial feedback. This article is being concurrently published in Wouter den Haan (ed.), 2013, Forward Guidance— This extended reference to the conditions deter- Perspectives from Central Bankers, Scholars and Market mining the FOMC’s future interest rate decisions is Participants, Centre for Economic Policy Research, VoxEU.org.
    [Show full text]
  • Equilibrium Uniqueness and Forward Guidance with Inconsistent Optimal Plans
    Discretion Rather than Rules: Equilibrium Uniqueness and Forward Guidance with Inconsistent Optimal Plans Jeffrey R. Campbell and Jacob P. Weber REVISED January 31, 2019 WP 2018-14 https://doi.org/10.21033/wp-2018-14 *Working papers are not edited, and all opinions and errors are the responsibility of the author(s). The views expressed do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Reserve Federal Reserve System. Discretion Rather than Rules: Equilibrium Uniqueness and Forward Guidance with Inconsistent Optimal Plans Jeffrey R. Campbell∗ Jacob P. Webery January 31, 2019 Abstract New Keynesian economies with active interest rate rules gain equilibrium deter- minacy from the central bank's incredible off-equilibrium-path promises (Cochrane, 2011). We suppose instead that the central bank sets interest rate paths and occa- sionally has the discretion to change them. With empirically-reasonable frequencies of central bank reoptimization, the monetary policy game has a unique Markov-perfect equilibrium wherein forward guidance influences current outcomes without displaying a forward guidance puzzle. ∗Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and CentER, Tilburg University. Jeff[email protected] yDepartment of Economics, University of California at Berkeley. jacob [email protected] We thank Roc Armenter, Gadi Barlevy, Bob Barsky, Marco Bassetto, Gauti Eggertsson, Jordi Gal´ı, Si- mon Gilchrist, the late Alejandro Justiniano, Assaf Patir, Stephanie Schmitt-Groh´e,Johannes Wieland and Michael Yang for insightful comments and discussion. Any errors that remain are our own. The views expressed herein are those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Federal Reserve System, or its Board of Governors.
    [Show full text]
  • The Grammar of Money an Analytical Account of Money As a Discursive Institution in Light of the Practice of Complementary Currencies
    The Grammar of Money An Analytical Account of Money as a Discursive Institution in Light of the Practice of Complementary Currencies Leander Bindewald, MSc. (Diplombiologe), M.A. Thesis submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Graduate School University of Cumbria and Lancaster University Lancaster, September 2018 Wordcount: 79,970 Abstract Since the global financial crisis in 2008, complementary currencies - from local initiatives like the Brixton Pound to timebanks, business-to-business currencies and, of course, Bitcoin - have received unprecedented attention by academics, policy makers, the media and the general public. However, at close theoretic inspection money itself remains as elusive a phenomenon as water must be to fish. Economic and business disciplines commonly only describe the use and functionality of money rather than its nature. Sociology and philosophy have a more fundamental set of approaches, but remain largely unintegrated in financial policy and common perception. At the same time, new forms of currency challenge predominant definitions of money and their implementation in the law and financial regulation. Unless our understanding of money and currencies is questioned and extended to consistently reflect theory and practice, its current misalignment threatens to impede much needed reform and innovation of the financial systems towards equity, democratic participation and sustainability. After reviewing current monetary theories and their epistemological underpinning, this thesis proposes a new theoretic framework of money as a ‘discursive institution’ that can be applied coherently to all monetary phenomena, conventional and unconventional. It also allows for the empirical analysis of currencies with the methodologies of neo-institutionalism, practice theory and critical discourse analysis.
    [Show full text]
  • Ben Bernanke,” Real Time Economics (Blog), November 15Th 2010
    MONETARY POLICY IN A NEW ERA Ben S. Bernanke Brookings Institution October 2, 2017 Prepared for conference on Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy, Peterson Institute, Washington DC, October 12-13, 2017. The author is a Distinguished Fellow at the Brookings Institution and the Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy. I thank Olivier Blanchard, Donald Kohn, and David Wessel for comments and Michael Ng for excellent research assistance. In 2017, the flagship research conferences of the European Central Bank and the Federal Reserve—held in Sintra, Portugal, and Jackson Hole, Wyoming, respectively—had something in common: Both had official themes unrelated to monetary policy, or even central banking. The ECB conference (theme: Investment and Growth in Advanced Economies) did include an opening speech by President Mario Draghi on monetary policy and the outlook, before turning to issues like the prospective effects of technological advances on employment. However, the Fed’s meeting (theme: Fostering a Dynamic Global Economy), which included papers on topics ranging from fiscal policy to trade to income distribution, made almost no mention of monetary policy. Whether intended or not, the signal, I think, was clear. After ten years of concerted effort first to restore financial stability, then to achieve economic recovery through dramatic monetary interventions, central bankers in Europe and the United States believe that they see the light at the end of the tunnel. They are looking forward to an era of relative financial and economic stability in which the pressing economic issues will relate to growth, globalization, and distribution—issues that are the responsibility of other policymakers and not primarily the province of central bankers.
    [Show full text]