INTER-PARTY MOBILITY AMONG PARLIAMENTARY CANDIDATES in POST- COMMUNIST EAST CENTRAL EUROPE Goldie Shabad and Kazimierz M

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

INTER-PARTY MOBILITY AMONG PARLIAMENTARY CANDIDATES in POST- COMMUNIST EAST CENTRAL EUROPE Goldie Shabad and Kazimierz M PARTY POLITICS VOL 10. No.2 pp. 151–176 Copyright © 2004 SAGE Publications London Thousand Oaks New Delhi www.sagepublications.com INTER-PARTY MOBILITY AMONG PARLIAMENTARY CANDIDATES IN POST- COMMUNIST EAST CENTRAL EUROPE Goldie Shabad and Kazimierz M. Slomczynski ABSTRACT The development of stable partisan commitments among political elites is crucial for party-system institutionalization in the new democracies of post-communist Europe. Little is known, however, about the partisan behavior of those who compete for national office. This study begins to fill this gap through an analysis of inter-party mobility among all candi- dates who ran for the lower house of parliament in two pairs of consec- utive elections in Poland (1991–3 and 1993–7) and in three pairs of consecutive elections in the Czech Republic (1990–2, 1992–6 and 1996–8). We consider the overall extent of inter-party mobility, struc- tural versus voluntary components of mobility, patterns of movement between types of parties and electoral payoffs of stable and shifting partisan affiliations. Although the overall rate of party-switching has declined substantially in the Czech Republic but not in Poland, changes in other characteristics of inter-party mobility indicate that party-system institutionalization is taking place in both countries. KEY WORDS elite party-switching party-system institutionalization political mobility The continual formations of entirely new parties, some of which acquire ‘overnight’ success, and the ongoing disappearance, schisms and mergers of established parties, together with high rates of electoral volatility, attest to the under-institutionalization of the party systems of new democracies in East Central Europe. Such party-system fluidity reflects a still ‘open’ and uncertain political market in which the partisan commitments of politicians and voters alike are not yet stable and the costs of shifting allegiances are relatively low (Bielasiak, 1997; Lewis, 2000; Mair, 1996). Yet, it would be inaccurate to characterize the party systems of East Central Europe as being in a perpetual state of disarray. On the contrary, there is a growing body of 1354-0688[DOI: 10.1177/1354068804040498] PARTY POLITICS 10(2) research demonstrating that party-system institutionalization is taking place, albeit more so in some countries than in others (Baylis, 1998; Bielasiak, 1999; Ilonszki, 2000; Kitschelt et al., 1999; Lewis, 2000; Miller and White, 1998; Shabad and Slomczynski, 1999, 2002; Slomczynski and Shabad, 2002; Toka, 1997; Tworzecki, 1996). One important aspect of party-system institutionalization in these new democracies that has received little systematic attention, however, is the development of partisan attachments among politicians. News reports, as well as studies of legislators, document the high frequency with which parliamentarians abandon their political clubs and switch to other party groups, form new ones or become independent (e.g. Bowler et al., 1999; Brokl and Mansfeldova, 1996; Filippov, 2000; Klima, 1998; Olson, 1998; Szarvas, 1995). Such turmoil among top politicians has led some academic observers to argue that politicians in the region tend to be ‘institutional nomads’ or ‘political tourists’ who readily shift allegiances from one party to another if they believe that their self-interests will be better served and the costs of switching are low (Herron, 2001; Jackiewicz, 1994; Kaminski and Kurczewska, 1994; Klima, 1998; Kreuzer and Pettai, 2002; Olson, 1998). As important as parliamentarians and other top party officials are, however, they constitute only a small fraction of politicians in the world of national-level electoral politics. Thus, the question remains: how wide- spread is such political tourism among politicians as a whole? Moreover, when party-switching occurs, to what can it be attributed? Is it the case, as many have argued, that politicians switch parties voluntarily for reasons of self-interest and/or weak political identities (Herron, 2001; Jackiewicz, 1994; Kaminski and Kurczewska, 1994; Klima, 1998; Kreuzer and Pettai, 2002)? Or, rather, are they forced to shift their partisan affiliation by struc- tural changes of the party system itself due to party dissolutions, splits and mergers? Regardless of the extent and sources of inter-party mobility, do politicians shift partisan allegiances in patterns that are indicative of party- system structuring? For example, do party switchers tend to move to estab- lished or to new parties, to parties that are ideologically proximate or distant, to winning or to losing parties? And, finally, what are the costs of party-switching for the individual politician? Does his or her chance of elec- toral success differ from that of a party loyalist? One cannot expect the extent, patterns and consequences of inter-party mobility to remain static. Presumably, as time passes and as political elites engage in multiple iterations of the electoral game, a learning process should take place and contribute to the stabilization of the party system (Bielasiak, 1997). Put simply, party-switching should become less ‘normal’, the patterns of movement more structured and the consequences of political tourism more costly. Has this, in fact, occurred during the first decade of competitive politics in East Central Europe? We address these questions through a comparative and dynamic analysis 152 SHABAD & SLOMCZYNSKI: INTER-PARTY MOBILITY of the degree, types, patterns and consequences of inter-party mobility in Poland and the Czech Republic. Specifically, we track the partisan affilia- tions of all candidates who ran for the lower house of parliament in two pairs of consecutive elections in Poland (1991–3 and 1993–7) and in three pairs of consecutive elections in the Czech Republic (1990–2, 1992–6 and 1996–8). Assuming that a learning process is taking place among politicians as the electoral game is repeated and becomes more familiar, we expect, by the time of the last parliamentary elections held in the 1990s in both Poland and the Czech Republic: (1) aggregate levels of inter-party mobility and of structurally induced movement to have declined from those of earlier years; (2) candidates’ movements from one party to another to reflect a growing structuring of the party system indicated by an increase of (a) flows to old rather than to new political parties, (b) switching within rather than across political party families, and (c) shifts to winning rather than to losing parties; and (3) the electoral costs to the individual candidate of party- switching to have increased. However, we also anticipate that our comparative analysis will tend to support findings that by the end of the 1990s the Czech party system was more consolidated than Poland’s. The greater fluidity of the Polish party system with respect to entries of new parties into and departures of winning parties from the parliamentary arena is likely to encourage and be reflected in higher rates of party-switching by politicians. Differences in consti- tutional arrangements may also contribute to higher levels of inter-party mobility in Poland. Direct election of the president, as in Poland but not in the Czech Republic, is typically associated with less cohesive parties, both as electoral organizations and as parliamentary groups (Powell, 1982). Perhaps of even greater importance are the differential effects of the two countries’ electoral systems. In Poland’s open list system, voters must select a single candidate from a party list in order to cast a valid vote. Candidates can and frequently do benefit from personal reputation apart from their party affiliation. In the Czech Republic, citizens can engage in approval voting of ranked candidates on a party list. If one-tenth of the total voters who cast a valid ballot for a party in an electoral district use this option, candidates who are chosen by at least 10 percent of such voters are moved to the top of the party list in the order given by the number of approval votes (Turnovec, 1997). Thus, the Polish electoral system provides fewer disincentives for politicians to switch parties (Carey and Shugart, 1995). Data Our analysis is based on data from Poland and the Czech Republic on all candidates who competed in elections to the lower house of parliament in the 1990s.1 Specifically, for Poland we include candidates who ran in the 1991 (N = 6980), 1993 (N = 8787) and 1997 (N = 6433) elections to the 153 PARTY POLITICS 10(2) Sejm. In the case of the Czech Republic, we include candidates who competed in the 1990 (N = 3947) and 1992 (N = 5708) elections in the Czech lands to the Narodni Rada (Chamber of People), as well as the 1996 (N = 4525) and 1998 (N = 3726) elections to Poslanecka Snimovna (the lower house of the parliament of the Czech Republic). Our data were obtained from state agencies responsible for collecting and maintaining election archives. For each country, the data for all elections are pooled so that the unit of observation is the candidate and all characteristics of his or her participation in consecutive elections are values of variables. This arrangement of data allows us to track the political experience of candidates, including their partisan affiliation, across consecutive elections. (Details about the process of matching candidates across elections are available from the authors upon request.) Extent and Types of Inter-Party Mobility All else being equal, institutionalizing party systems should exhibit decreas- ing electoral volatility and elite-level inter-party mobility, thus
Recommended publications
  • Politician Overboard: Jumping the Party Ship
    INFORMATION, ANALYSIS AND ADVICE FOR THE PARLIAMENT INFORMATION AND RESEARCH SERVICES Research Paper No. 4 2002–03 Politician Overboard: Jumping the Party Ship DEPARTMENT OF THE PARLIAMENTARY LIBRARY ISSN 1328-7478 Copyright Commonwealth of Australia 2003 Except to the extent of the uses permitted under the Copyright Act 1968, no part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means including information storage and retrieval systems, without the prior written consent of the Department of the Parliamentary Library, other than by Senators and Members of the Australian Parliament in the course of their official duties. This paper has been prepared for general distribution to Senators and Members of the Australian Parliament. While great care is taken to ensure that the paper is accurate and balanced, the paper is written using information publicly available at the time of production. The views expressed are those of the author and should not be attributed to the Information and Research Services (IRS). Advice on legislation or legal policy issues contained in this paper is provided for use in parliamentary debate and for related parliamentary purposes. This paper is not professional legal opinion. Readers are reminded that the paper is not an official parliamentary or Australian government document. IRS staff are available to discuss the paper's contents with Senators and Members and their staff but not with members of the public. Published by the Department of the Parliamentary Library, 2003 I NFORMATION AND R ESEARCH S ERVICES Research Paper No. 4 2002–03 Politician Overboard: Jumping the Party Ship Sarah Miskin Politics and Public Administration Group 24 March 2003 Acknowledgments I would like to thank Martin Lumb and Janet Wilson for their help with the research into party defections in Australia and Cathy Madden, Scott Bennett, David Farrell and Ben Miskin for reading and commenting on early drafts.
    [Show full text]
  • Party System in South and Southeast Asia
    PARTY SYSTEM IN SOUTH AND SOUTHEAST ASIA A THEMATIC REPORT BASED ON DATA 1900-2012 Authors: Julio Teehankee, Medet Tiulegenov, Yi-ting Wang, Vlad Ciobanu, and Staffan I. Lindberg V-Dem Thematic Report Series, No. 2, October 2013. Prepared for The European Union, represented by the European Commission under Service Contract No. EIDHR 2012/298/903 2 About V-Dem Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) is a new approach to conceptualization and measurement of democracy. It is a collaboration between some 50+ scholars across the world hosted by the Department of Political Science at the University of Gothenburg, Sweden; and the Kellogg Institute at the University of Notre Dame, USA. With four Principal Investigators (PIs), three Project Coordinators (PCs), fifteen Project Managers (PMs) with special responsibility for issue areas, more than thirty Regional Managers (RMs), almost 200 Country Coordinators (CCs), a set of Research Assistants (RAs), and approximately 3,000 Country Experts (CEs), the V-Dem project is one of the largest ever social science research-oriented data collection programs. V-Dem is collecting data on 329 indicators of various aspects democracy tied to the core of electoral democracy as well as six varying properties: liberal, majoritarian, consensual, participatory, deliberative and egalitarian dimensions of democracy. A pilot study in 2011 tested the preliminary set of indicators and the data collection interfaces and procedures. Twelve countries from six regions of the world were covered, generating 462,000 data points. In the main phase, all countries of the world will be covered from 1900 to the present, generating some 22 million data across the 329 indicators, as well as several indices of varying forms of democracy.
    [Show full text]
  • Party Formation in Parliamentary Democracies
    Party Formation in Parliamentary Democracies Selcen C¸akır∗ May, 2018 Abstract The political power of elected representatives is determined by politicians' member- ship negotiations with parties. In parliamentary systems, party control over govern- ment functions generates club goods, which increases the value of party membership. Moreover, in party-centered parliamentary systems, getting influential positions re- quires party leader's approval, which gives the leader monopsonistic recruiting power. As a result, politicians may relegate their political power to leaders when membership is more rewarding than acting independently. I develop an equilibrium model of party formation in a parliamentary democracy that incorporates parties' provision of club goods, rent sharing between politicians and party leaders, as well as politicians' outside options. Politicians' rankings of parties critically depend on the size of the party as well as on their own political assets. Through their control of government functions, bigger parties can provide greater club goods but tax politicians' rents more upon entry. Because of this, politicians with more assets tend to prefer smaller parties. I structurally estimate my model for Turkey with a unique dataset of 33 parties, 2,000 politicians who gained seats in parliament, and 35,000 politicians who were on party ballot lists between 1995 and 2014. My model matches the high level of party switch- ing (28.5%) that is characteristic of many party-centered systems. I find that Turkish parties accumulate club goods more easily than they produce rents, which leads to ever stronger party control. I also find that politicians with good labor market options are not productive in the political arena.
    [Show full text]
  • Codebook CPDS I 1960-2013
    1 Codebook: Comparative Political Data Set, 1960-2013 Codebook: COMPARATIVE POLITICAL DATA SET 1960-2013 Klaus Armingeon, Christian Isler, Laura Knöpfel, David Weisstanner and Sarah Engler The Comparative Political Data Set 1960-2013 (CPDS) is a collection of political and institu- tional data which have been assembled in the context of the research projects “Die Hand- lungsspielräume des Nationalstaates” and “Critical junctures. An international comparison” directed by Klaus Armingeon and funded by the Swiss National Science Foundation. This data set consists of (mostly) annual data for 36 democratic OECD and/or EU-member coun- tries for the period of 1960 to 2013. In all countries, political data were collected only for the democratic periods.1 The data set is suited for cross-national, longitudinal and pooled time- series analyses. The present data set combines and replaces the earlier versions “Comparative Political Data Set I” (data for 23 OECD countries from 1960 onwards) and the “Comparative Political Data Set III” (data for 36 OECD and/or EU member states from 1990 onwards). A variable has been added to identify former CPDS I countries. For additional detailed information on the composition of government in the 36 countries, please consult the “Supplement to the Comparative Political Data Set – Government Com- position 1960-2013”, available on the CPDS website. The Comparative Political Data Set contains some additional demographic, socio- and eco- nomic variables. However, these variables are not the major concern of the project and are thus limited in scope. For more in-depth sources of these data, see the online databases of the OECD, Eurostat or AMECO.
    [Show full text]
  • A Delayed Return to Historical Norms: Congressional Party Polarization After the Second World War* Hahrie Han Wellesley College
    A Delayed Return to Historical Norms: Congressional Party Polarization After the Second World War* Hahrie Han Wellesley College David W. Brady Stanford University Forthcoming, British Journal of Political Science ABSTRACT: Although a rich body of research has explored the sources of party polarization in the U.S. House of Representatives, it has focused only on the House since the late 1970s. Drawing on a dataset of historical election outcomes, legislative voting, and survey data, we take an alternative approach that examines both the U.S. Senate and the House in their broader historical contexts. We argue that the unusually bi-partisan era of the 1950s created a set of circumstances that enabled congressional parties to remain relatively un-polarized throughout the 1960s and early 1970s. Although the national parties became more ideologically distinct in the mid-1960s, congressional parties lagged behind. As a result, a group of moderate legislators emerged who were cross-pressured between their national parties and their constituencies. Only when natural patterns of electoral loss and retirement replaced these legislators did congressional party polarization re-emerge. Introduction The question of why congressional parties in the U.S. have polarized so much since the late 1970s has been a topic of rich scholarly debate in recent years. Existing explanations range from endogenous institutional changes that increased partisanship in Congress, to exogenous political changes that altered the configuration of congressional parties. Research
    [Show full text]
  • New Political Entrepreneurs in Poland
    ARTICLES 137 New Political Entrepreneurs in Poland Beata KosowsKa-Gąstoł and Katarzyna soBolewsKa-MyśliK* Abstract Parties launched by political entrepreneurs are usually newcomers into more or less established party systems. Their ‘founding fathers’ act without specific external group support and the literature on new parties predicts that there is a low survival rate for entrepreneurial parties. In the case of Po- land, the party system had been relatively stable from the 2001 until the 2011 parliamentary elec- tions and subsequently some new parties entered into politics, tried to gain electoral support as well as political relevance. The most recent groupings in the Polish political system which are closest to the theoretical concept of entrepreneurial parties are the Palikot’s Movement (Ruch Palikota), Kukiz’15 and the Modern Party (Nowoczesna). The aim of the paper is to examine to what extent the leaders of these parties can be seen as political entrepreneurs and the parties as ‘entrepreneurial parties’. Another point we discuss is in which aspects the leaders of the parties examined are similar in their role of political entrepreneurs and in which they differ. In order to answer these questions, the previous careers of the leaders, the ways they entered politics and the strategies they used to achieve their goals will also be analyzed. Keywords: political entrepreneurs; entrepreneurial issue parties; Polish parties; new parties DOI: 10.5817/PC2017-2-137 1. Introduction While in the 1990s the main division line in Poland was between post-communist and post-Solidarity parties, that changed from the 2005 elections on as two post-Solidarity par- ties, Law and Justice (PiS – Prawo i Sprawiedliwość) and Civic Platform (PO – Platforma Obywatelska), became electoral rivals.
    [Show full text]
  • Democracy, Interests and Corporatism in Poland
    THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN RESEARCH TITLE : Democracy, Interests and Corporatism i n Poland AUTHOR : Ireneusz Bialeck i Polish Academy of Scienc e Barbara Heyns New York University CONTRACTOR : University of Michigan PRINCIPAL INVESTIGATOR : Michael Kennedy COUNCIL CONTRACT NUMBER : 806-02 DATE : June 10, 1992 The work leading to this report was supported by contract funds provided by the National Council for Soviet and East European Research. The analysis and interpretations contained in the report are those of the author . COPYRIGHT INFORMATION Individual researchers retain the copyright on work products derived from research funded by Council Contract . The Council and the U.S. Government have the right to duplicate written reports and other materials submitte d under Council Contract and to distribute such copies within the Council and U.S. Government for their own use , and to draw upon such reports and materials for their own studies,- but the Council and U.S. Government do no t have the right to distribute, or make such reports and materials available, outside the Council or U .S. Government without the written consent of the authors, except as may be required under the provisions of th e Freedom of Information Act 5 U.S.C. 552, or other applicable law. Executive Summary : Democracy, Interests and Corporatism in Polan d by Ireneusz Bialecki and Barbara Heyn s summarized by Michael Kenned y Democracy is more than elections and the publi c interest requires more than the free for all of pluralisti c politics . Both require the development of new forms of rul e and representation .
    [Show full text]
  • Comparing Organizational Structures of Political Parties in Central and Eastern European Countries
    Beata Kosowska-Gąstoł Jagiellonian University Piotr Borowiec Jagiellonian University Katarzyna Sobolewska-Myślik Pedagogical University of Cracow Comparing Organizational Structures of Political Parties in Central and Eastern European Countries Some Determinants of Political Party Development in Emerging Democracies of CEE Democratic political parties have developed in the emerging democracies of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) since the beginning of the 1990s, when political parties in well-established democracies were undergoing organizational transformation. The latter weakened their ties with society and strengthened their relations with the state using its resources. This influenced the development of parties in CEE countries, as they followed Western patterns to a certain degree. But whereas parties in developed democracies were usually well-rooted in society, represent­ ed social cleavages, had mass membership, were financed by membership fees, and changed only subsequently; parties in CEE did not manage to create strong relations with society before they took part in elections. There was a lack of clear social cleavages, and parties were created by political elites rather than social groups or movements, thus they often became a part of the state institutions even before they tried to establish roots in society.1 While in Western Europe mass po­ litical mobilization preceded the building of party structures and participation in Post-communist parties can be regarded as exceptional in this matter. 466 Beata Kosowska-Gąstoł, Piotr Borowiec, Katarzyna Sobolewska-Myślik elections, “party formation in newly established democracies generally followed a different trajectory, as parties engaged in mass electoral competition before developing their party organization” (van Biezen 2003: 30). Consequently, such parties gained representation in parliament, and sometimes even executive power, before creating extra-parliamentary organizations.
    [Show full text]
  • When Do Partisans Cross the Party Line?
    When Do Partisans Cross the Party Line? George Kwaku Ofosu∗ March 30, 2021 Abstract When will partisans cross party lines to elect a potentially better-performing opposition politician? Individuals in developing countries vote for politicians in expectation of public goods. Partisan ge- ography influences voters’ beliefs about politicians’ ability to exclude them from such goods. Since voters believe they are better able to replace poorly performing incumbents in competitive districts, partisans in non-segregated, competitive constituencies are more likely to vote for opposition can- didates than those in other settings. Using a conjoint experiment administered to voters that ran- domized the characteristics of parliamentary candidates in Ghana, I find that voters in competitive, non-segregated districts are the most willing to cross party lines. Additional data on actual public goods distribution supports the mechanism. Data from Ghana’s 2020 parliamentary elections con- firm the external validity of the findings: party switching is highest in this type of district. My results demonstrate the influence of constituency characteristics on electoral accountability. ∗Assistant Professor, London School of Economics and Political Science. Email: [email protected]. Web: www. georgeofosu.com/. Samuel Kweku Yamoah and Mahmouda Ainoo provided excellent field research assistance. I am grateful to Kojo Asante, Sarah Brierley, Danny Choi, Florian Foos, Adam Harris, Eric Kramon, Evan Morier, Galen Mur- ray, Noah Nathan, Franklin Oduro, Daniel Posner, Andrea Vilán, Michael Wahman, Josef Woldense, and Stephane Wolton for their helpful comments and suggestions. I also thank participants of the Midwest Workshop in Empirical Political Sci- ence and Comparative Politics Seminars at UCLA, UCL, Oxford’s Nuffield College, the Institutions and Political Inequality research unit at Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin (WZB), and UW-Madison for helpful feedback and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Codebook CPDS III 1990-2012
    Codebook: COMPARATIVE POLITICAL DATA SET III 1990-2012 Klaus Armingeon, Laura Knöpfel, David Weisstanner and Sarah Engler The Comparative Political Data Set III 1990-2012 is a collection of political and institutional data. This data set consists of (mostly) annual data for a group of 36 OECD and/or EU- member countries for the period 1990-20121. The data are primarily from the data set created at the University of Berne, Institute of Political Science and funded by the Swiss National Science Foundation: The Comparative Political Data Set I (CPDS I). However, the present data set differs in several aspects from the CPDS I dataset. Compared to CPDS I Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus (Greek part), Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Romania, Slovakia and Slovenia have been added. The present data set is suited for cross-national, longitudinal and pooled time series analyses. The data set contains some additional demographic, socio- and economic variables. However, these variables are not the major concern of the project and are thus limited in scope. For more in-depth sources of these data, see the online databases of the OECD. For trade union membership, excellent data for European trade unions is provided by Jelle Visser (2013). When using the data from this data set, please quote both the data set and, where appropriate, the original source. This data set is to be cited as: Klaus Armingeon, Laura Knöpfel, David Weisstanner and Sarah Engler. 2014. Comparative Political Data Set III 1990-2012. Bern: Institute of Political Science, University of Berne. Last updated: 2014-09-30 1 Data for former communist countries begin in 1990 for Bulgaria, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Hungary, Malta, Romania and Slovakia, in 1991 for Poland, in 1992 for Estonia and Lithuania, in 1993 for Lativa and Slovenia and in 2000 for Croatia.
    [Show full text]
  • Manifesto Project Dataset List of Political Parties
    Manifesto Project Dataset List of Political Parties [email protected] Website: https://manifesto-project.wzb.eu/ Version 2020a from July 22, 2020 Manifesto Project Dataset - List of Political Parties Version 2020a 1 Coverage of the Dataset including Party Splits and Merges The following list documents the parties that were coded at a specific election. The list includes the name of the party or alliance in the original language and in English, the party/alliance abbreviation as well as the corresponding party identification number. In the case of an alliance, it also documents the member parties it comprises. Within the list of alliance members, parties are represented only by their id and abbreviation if they are also part of the general party list. If the composition of an alliance has changed between elections this change is reported as well. Furthermore, the list records renames of parties and alliances. It shows whether a party has split from another party or a number of parties has merged and indicates the name (and if existing the id) of this split or merger parties. In the past there have been a few cases where an alliance manifesto was coded instead of a party manifesto but without assigning the alliance a new party id. Instead, the alliance manifesto appeared under the party id of the main party within that alliance. In such cases the list displays the information for which election an alliance manifesto was coded as well as the name and members of this alliance. 2 Albania ID Covering Abbrev Parties No. Elections
    [Show full text]
  • Laws Against Party Switching, Defecting, Or Floor-Crossing in National Parliaments
    Laws Against Party Switching, Defecting, or Floor-Crossing in National Parliaments Kenneth Janda Northwestern University [email protected] The Legal Regulation of Political Parties Working Paper 2 August 2009 © The author(s), 2009 This working paper series is supported by the Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC research grant RES- 061-25-0080) and the European Research Council (ERC starting grant 205660). This paper was prepared for delivery at the 2009 World Congress of the International Political Science Association held in Santiago, Chile July 12-16, 2009. Special Section 01.280 “Party Democracy and Party Law: The Legal Regulation of Political Parties in Modern Democracies” Work in progress . Please check with the author before citing or quoting. To link to this paper : http://www.partylaw.leidenuniv.nl/uploads/wp0209.pdf This paper may be used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. ISSN: 2211-1034 The Legal Regulation of Political Parties, working paper 02/09 Laws Against Party Switching, Defecting, or Floor Crossing in National Parliaments Kenneth Janda Abstract Many western scholars may be surprised to learn that parliamentary members who switch parties during the session may be expelled from parliament because they violate the law in their country. This paper studies such “anti-defection” laws. It investigates the extent of such legislation; why and how often legislators switch parties; how this phenomenon has been studied; why some scholars favor banning party switching; why politicians have legislated against party defections; and the consequences of such bans for political parties and party systems.
    [Show full text]