Aspirations and the Persistence of Poverty and Inequalities

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Aspirations and the Persistence of Poverty and Inequalities DISSERTATION zur Erlangung des Doktorgrades der Wirtschaftswissenschaften (Dr. rer. pol.) Aspirations and the persistence of poverty and inequalities vorgelegt von Svenja Flechtner am 22.06.2016 an der Europa-Universität Flensburg Internationales Institut für Management und ökonomische Bildung Erster Gutachter: Zweiter Gutachter: Prof. Dr. Stephan Panther Prof. Dr. Carlo D’Ippoliti Europa-Universität Flensburg Sapienza University of Rome Contents Page Acknowledgements . .7 List of Figures . .9 List of Tables . 12 Introduction 13 I Aspirations: contouring a concept 23 1 Understanding human development: what can aspirations contribute? 25 1.1 Why does poverty persist? . 27 1.2 What can aspirations contribute? . 31 2 Models 39 2.1 Reference point models . 41 2.2 Debraj Ray: aspiration windows and aspiration gaps . 43 2.3 Aspirations, inequality and growth in a formal model . 48 2.4 Psychological aspiration traps . 55 2.5 Other models with applications to specific contexts . 60 3 How do aspirations develop? Insights from behavioural economics 65 3.1 Aspirations and ‘non-standard’ preferences . 66 3.1.1 Social learning and cultural transmission . 67 3.1.2 Adaptive processes . 72 3.2 Aspirations and ‘non-standard’ beliefs . 76 3.2.1 Cognitive dissonance . 79 3 3.2.2 Self-views, self-biases and attribution errors . 83 3.2.3 Selective awareness and mental short-cuts . 85 3.2.4 Mental models and cognitive frames . 88 4 Broadening the view: aspirations and different notions of rationality 93 4.1 The approach of mainstream behavioural economics . 94 4.2 Aspirations and alternative conceptions of rationality . 98 4.3 Rational aspirations in the light of identities . 103 5 What drives aspirations? Selected lessons from other disciplines 111 5.1 Arjun Appadurai: The capacity to aspire . 112 5.2 Albert Bandura: Social cognitive theory . 115 5.3 Pierre Bourdieu: Milieu and habitus . 120 6 Putting the pieces together: An integrative framework 127 6.1 Recapitulation: determinants and drivers of aspirations . 128 6.2 An integrative framework . 130 II Empirical evidence 135 7 Empirical evidence about aspirations and aspiration traps 137 7.1 Are aspirations really an important determinant of behaviour? . 140 7.2 Are aspirations really biased along socio-economic lines? . 147 7.3 What do we know about specific drivers of aspirations? . 151 7.3.1 Cultural transmission, social learning and habitus . 151 7.3.2 Aspiration windows, role models, and peer effects . 153 7.3.3 Social cognitive theory . 156 7.4 Are aspirations really influenced by macro-level developments? . 158 7.5 Summary and open questions . 159 8 Locus of control, inequality and growth: a cross-country perspective with data from the World Values Survey 163 8.1 Theory and relevant literature . 164 8.2 Data and model . 165 8.2.1 Measuring locus of control with World Values Survey data . 165 8.2.2 Model specification . 167 8.2.3 Descriptive statistics . 169 8.3 Results . 170 8.3.1 Wealth, growth, and inequality . 170 8.3.2 Growth and inequality dynamics in context . 174 8.4 Discussion and conclusion . 178 9 Do aspirations impact behaviour? Evidence from structural equation modelling 181 9.1 Brief summary: The identification problem . 183 9.2 Method: Structural Equation Modelling . 185 9.3 Model specification . 186 9.3.1 The structural model . 187 9.3.2 The measurement model . 189 9.3.3 Software choice: SEM Modelling and estimation in R . 191 9.4 Data Set: The Young Lives Study of Childhood Poverty . 193 9.5 Results . 200 9.6 Discussion and conclusion . 204 III Normative considerations 211 10 Should aspirations be a matter of policy concern? 213 10.1 Policy interventions in the aspirations literature . 216 10.2 Contrasting five normative perspectives . 218 10.2.1 Desire-fulfilment and welfarism . 219 10.2.2 Hedonistic approaches . 224 10.2.3 Sugden’s opportunity criterion . 226 10.2.4 Roemer’s equality of opportunity . 229 10.2.5 Sen’s capability approach . 232 10.3 Discussion and conclusion . 236 Conclusion 241 Bibliography 249 6 Contents Appendix 293 A Appendix to chapter 8 293 A.1 Additional specifications . 294 A.2 Residual diagnostics . 297 B Appendix to chapter 9 303 B.1 Additional descriptive statistics . 304 B.2 Additional reporting of results . 308 B.3 SEM: R Code . 316 Eidesstattliche Erklärung 319 Acknowledgements This thesis is the result of several years of doctoral research, and was accompanied by the valuable support of many people along the way. On the academic side, I am thankful to my supervisor Stephan Panther, who encouraged me from the first day to explore and follow my academic interests and gave me time and space to truly do so. He was a respectful and motivating superior, supervisor, and scientific mentor. His trust in my commitment to my research allowed me to move freely, explore hidden corners of our discipline, travel a lot, meet many people and have time for many different projects. All of these aspects shaped this thesis in important ways. Carlo D’Ippoliti, my second supervisor, accepted to get involved in a project that was already shaped in many regards. Nevertheless and all the more, he provided invaluable guidance with regards to all parts of this thesis, and engaged much more than I could have reasonably expected. His broad and deep understanding of many different literatures and empirical methods was of great help. I am very thankful for this support. Many parts of this thesis hugely benefited from comments by colleagues and friends. Sara El-Madani read large parts of the manuscript and pointed me towards a whole bunch of minor and major problems. Katharina Pohl was an extremely helpful, critical discussant of my topic as such and its normative implications in particular, both over the years and when the draft was finished. Her last-minute support is warmly acknowledged. My overall perspective on the topic was enhanced in important ways through my joint work with Claudius Gräbner on a related topic. His helpful attitude, from which I benefited many times, is much appreciated. Jonathan Mole helped me to revise my academic writing. My understanding of the models in chapter2 and, in fact, of the whole field benefited greatly from the 4th World Bank Equity Conference on Aspirations, Poverty and Inequality in 2014. I am thankful to Pedro Olinto for inviting me. 7 8 Acknowledgements Chapter8 as well as earlier versions of it have come a particularly long way. It was my first empirical exercise and took me to my first conferences. I am thankful for helpful comments and suggestions to François Bourguignon, Francisco H.G. Ferreira, Martin Förster, Alan Piper, Pasquale Tridico, and participants of the IBGE-IARIW Special Conference on ”Income, Wealth and Well-being in Latin America” (Rio de Janeiro, 2013), the EAEPE Summer School (Rome, 2013) and the 25th EAEPE Annual Conference (Paris, 2013). Pia Förster provided helpful research assistance. The Flensburg Tea Meeting provided helpful reflections on chapter9. Chapter 10 received lots of insightful comments at the XII. Buchenbach workshop 2015. I would like to thank Mark Kirstein, Marco Lehmann-Waffenschmidt, and Thomas Göllinger. Chapter 10 moreover benefited from helpful comments by anonymous reviewers. On the personal side of university life, I wish to thank Sara El-Madani, Maike Simon and Marlene Langholz-Kaiser for their friendship and support, in particular during the last months. Sara was the best colleague I could have hoped for, and sharing office with her will truly be missed. Marlene, Mika and their family shared their home with me many times. Maike’s friendship over the years and notably during the last days and hours cannot be emphasised enough. My parents, Monika and Thomas, deserve my gratitude for their continuous support of whatever aspirations I came up with. I learned from them that many aspirations can be achieved if one tries, that some aspirations deserve being revised, and that the highest aspirations are not always the best. My take on aspiration traps and what causes them has benefited from conversations with my mother, who is not only the best mother, but also a great social worker. Finally, I am thankful to Marc, for years of patient and impatient support. He found a fair balance between pushing my motivation and reminding me that there is more in life than aspirations. His critical real-world perspectives shaped this thesis in many ways. On a practical note, sitting in front of a computer would have been much less comfortable without his technical support and equipment. Practical and small things in our day-to-day lives often tend to be forgotten or overlooked. In particular over the last months, Marc took care of many little and not so little things. Many of them I am not even aware of, because my mind was elsewhere. But I know. List of Figures 2.1 Kahneman and Tversky’s value function . 42 2.2 The benefit from future wealth . 50 2.3 Satisfaction and frustration from aspirations at a given level of initial wealth . 51 2.4 Satisfaction and frustration at a given aspiration level and different growth rates of wealth . 52 5.1 Combinations of perceived self-efficacy and locus of control beliefs according to Bandura . 117 6.1 How do aspirations develop? An integrative framework . 131 7.1 Model estimating a mediation effect . 150 8.1 Response scores of group means by income groups, waves 1-6 . 169 8.2 Average response score over all observations per wave . 170 8.3 Variation of perceived control between income groups and GDP per capita . 172 9.1 Structural model . 188 9.2 Distribution of educational aspirations . 195 9.3 Grades attended, 1999-2009 . 196 9.4 Changes of individual aspirations between rounds 2 and 3 .
Recommended publications
  • A Quantitative Theory of Political Transitions∗
    A Quantitative Theory of Political Transitions∗ Lukas Buchheimy Robert Ulbrichtz August 28, 2019 Abstract We develop a quantitative theory of repeated political transitions driven by revolts and reforms. In the model, the beliefs of disenfranchised citizens play a key role in determining revolutionary pressure, which in interaction with preemptive reforms determine regime dynamics. We study the quantitative implications of the model by fitting it to data on the universe of political regimes existing between 1946 and 2010. The estimated model generates a process of political transitions that looks remarkably close to the data, replicating the empirical shape of transition hazards, the frequency of revolts relative to reforms, the distribution of newly established regime types after revolts and reforms, and the unconditional distribution over regime types. Keywords: Democratic reforms, quantitative political economy, regime dynamics, revolts, transition hazards. JEL Classification: D74, D78, P16. ∗This paper supersedes an earlier working paper titled \Dynamics of Political Systems." We would like to thank the managing editor, Mich`eleTertilt, four anonymous referees, Daron Acemoglu, Toke Aidt, Matthias Doepke, Christian Hellwig, Johannes Maier, Uwe Sunde, and various seminar and conference participants for valuable comments and suggestions. yLMU Munich, Schackstr 4/IV, 80539 Munich, Germany. E-mail: [email protected]. zBoston College, 140 Commonwealth Avenue, Chestnut Hill, MA 02467. E-mail: [email protected]. 1 Introduction This paper develops a quantitative theory of political transitions based on the evolution of beliefs regarding the regime's strength. Traditionally, the literature has focused on explaining specific patterns of regime changes, focusing on isolated transition episodes.1 In this paper, we shift the focus to a macro perspective, aiming to account for a number of stylized facts in a unified framework.
    [Show full text]
  • Patience and Comparative Development*
    Patience and Comparative Development* Thomas Dohmen Benjamin Enke Armin Falk David Huffman Uwe Sunde May 29, 2018 Abstract This paper studies the role of heterogeneity in patience for comparative devel- opment. The empirical analysis is based on a simple OLG model in which patience drives the accumulation of physical capital, human capital, productivity improve- ments, and hence income. Based on a globally representative dataset on patience in 76 countries, we study the implications of the model through a combination of reduced-form estimations and simulations. In the data, patience is strongly corre- lated with income levels, income growth, and the accumulation of physical capital, human capital, and productivity. These relationships hold across countries, sub- national regions, and individuals. In the reduced-form analyses, the quantitative magnitude of the relationship between patience and income strongly increases in the level of aggregation. A simple parameterized version of the model generates comparable aggregation effects as a result of production complementarities and equilibrium effects, and illustrates that variation in preference endowments can account for a considerable part of the observed variation in per capita income. JEL classification: D03, D90, O10, O30, O40. Keywords: Patience; comparative development; factor accumulation. *Armin Falk acknowledges financial support from the European Research Council through ERC # 209214. Dohmen, Falk: University of Bonn, Department of Economics; [email protected], [email protected]. Enke: Harvard University, Department of Economics; [email protected]. Huffman: University of Pittsburgh, Department of Economics; huff[email protected]. Sunde: University of Munich, Department of Economics; [email protected]. 1 Introduction A long stream of research in development accounting has documented that both pro- duction factors and productivity play an important role in explaining cross-country income differences (Hall and Jones, 1999; Caselli, 2005; Hsieh and Klenow, 2010).
    [Show full text]
  • Did We Overestimate the Role of Social Preferences? the Case of Self-Selected Student Samples
    Did we overestimate the role of social preferences? The case of self-selected student samples Armin Falk,∗ Stephan Meier,y and Christian Zehnderz July 13, 2010 Abstract Social preference research has fundamentally changed the way economists think about many important economic and social phenomena. However, the em- pirical foundation of social preferences is largely based on laboratory experiments with self-selected students as participants. This is potentially problematic as students participating in experiments may behave systematically different than non-participating students or non-students. In this paper we empirically inves- tigate whether laboratory experiments with student samples misrepresent the importance of social preferences. Our first study shows that students who ex- hibit stronger prosocial inclinations in an unrelated field donation are not more likely to participate in experiments. This suggests that self-selection of more prosocial students into experiments is not a major issue. Our second study com- pares behavior of students and the general population in a trust experiment. We find very similar behavioral patterns for the two groups. If anything, the level of reciprocation seems higher among non-students implying an even greater importance of social preferences than assumed from student samples. Keywords: methodology, selection, experiments, prosocial behavior JEL: C90, D03 ∗University of Bonn, Department of Economics, Adenauerallee 24-42, D-53113 Bonn; [email protected]. yColumbia University, Graduate School of Business, 710 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway, New York, NY 10027; [email protected]. zUniversity of Lausanne, Faculty of Business and Economics, Quartier UNIL-Dorigny, Internef 612, CH-1015 Lausanne; [email protected]. 1 1 Introduction Social preferences such as trust and reciprocity play an increasingly important role in economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 0040: Behavioural Economics Fall 2020
    Econ 0040: Behavioural Economics Fall 2020 Lecturer information Dr. Zeynep Gurguc E-mail: [email protected] Student feedback hours (online): Thursdays 13:15-14:15 during first term or by appointment & later by appointment. What will you learn about? The purpose of this course is to provide students an overview of research in Behavioural Economics, a field of economics that draws on knowledge in psychology to capture important aspects of human behaviour and social interactions that standard economic models cannot explain. The topics we will cover include: Heuristics and Biases, Decision Making under Uncertainty, Prospect Theory, Reference Dependence, Intertemporal Choice, Social Preferences, Bounded Rationality, Nudge as well as Heterogeneity and Malleability of Preferences. Throughout this course, we will link theory to practice and discuss empirical applications in areas and topics such as consumer choice, saving behaviour, procrastination, education, labour supply, finance and policy making. How will you learn? We will use a mixture of online asynchronous and synchronous content. Each Monday by 11:45 am you will get access to the core materials for the week as well as the tasks. In addition, both your lecturer and your teaching assistant will have regular student support and feedback hours where you can drop in to discuss any issues around this module. Weekly Live Sessions with Dr Gurguc: Wednesdays 11AM-12:30PM. The lectures will be on zoom except for weeks 6, 7, 12 and 14 (i.e. October 7, October 14, November 18 and December 2) when the live lecture will be held face-to-face (F2F). F2F lectures will take place in Wilkins Building (main building), Jeremy Bentham Room.
    [Show full text]
  • David Huffman 416 N
    DAVID HUFFMAN 416 N. Chester Rd., Apt. 2 Swarthmore, PA 19081 E-mail: [email protected] Webpage: http://www.swarthmore.edu/x28019.xml PERSONAL Birth Date: April 4th, 1974 Citizenship: USA EMPLOYMENT SINCE PH.D. Associate Professor (with tenure), Swarthmore College February 2012 – Present Assistant Professor, Swarthmore College January 2008 – February 2013 IZA Senior Research Associate 2006 – 2007 Deputy Director, Behavioral and Personnel Economics Program Area IZA Laboratory Coordinator IZA Research Associate 2003 – 2006 EDITORIAL POSITIONS Associate Editor for Management Science January 2013 – present EDUCATION University of California, Berkeley Ph.D. Economics 2003 Primary Fields: Behavioral economics, labor economics, applied microeconomics. Dissertation Advisor: Professor George Akerlof Oberlin College, Oberlin Ohio B.A., magna cum laude in Economics 1996 PUBLICATIONS “Implicit Contracts, Unemployment, and Market Segmentation” IZA Discussion Paper, No. 5001 (with Steffen Altmann, Armin Falk, and Andreas Grunewald), forthcoming in Review of Economic Studies. “When a Nudge isn’t Enough: A Field Test of the Power of Defaults to Influence Savings of Low- Income Tax Filers”, NBER Working Paper, No. 16887 (with Erin Bronchetti, Thomas Dee, and Ellen Magenheim), forthcoming in National Tax Journal. “Validating an Ultra-Short Survey Measure of Impatience”, forthcoming in Economics Letters (with Thomas Dohment, Armin Falk, Jürgen Schupp, Uwe Sunde, Thomas Vischer, and Gert Wagner). “Competition Between Organizational Groups: Its Impact on Altruistic and Antisocial Motivations”, Management Science, 2012, 58(5), 948–960 (with Lorenz Goette, Stephan Meier, and Matthias Sutter). “The Impact of Social Ties on Group Interactions: Evidence from Minimal Groups and Randomly Assigned Real Groups”, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2012, 4(1), 101–115 (with Lorenz Goette and Stephan Meier).
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Property Rights and Economic Development: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead. Carmine Guerriero University of Bologna* Abstract
    Property Rights and Economic Development: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead. Carmine Guerriero University of Bologna ∗ Abstract: Although property rights are crucial to economic development, our understanding of their origins remains limited. A recent strand of research, however, has made a major advance by documenting that the ex post misallocation—driven by the mix of strongly protected property rights and large transaction costs—explains the distribution of property rights significantly better than does the disincentive effect of predation by the state and powerful elites. This conclusion leads to several key questions on the impact of the protection of property rights on the extent of private expropriation, the scope of firms, the size of markets and, ultimately, economic development. In this essay, I illustrate the challenges involved in answering these questions, and I highlight potential policy implications. Keywords: Property Rights; Transaction Costs; Contracts; Markets; Economic Development. JEL classification: D23; D40; D82; K11; L11; P14; Z10. ∗ Department of Economics, University of Bologna, Strada Maggiore 45, 40125 Bologna, Italy. E- mail: [email protected]. I would like to thank Raffaella Paduano, Claude Menard, and Mary Shirley for insightful comments on how to present more incisively the material covered by this essay. 1 “The New Institutional Economics [NIE] is the little engine that could. Its best days lie ahead” [Williamson 2001, p. 611]. 1. Introduction The Coase theorem, the cornerstone of the New Institutional Economics [Williamson 2001, p. 598], claims that alternative property rights assignments internalize conflicts and externalities in equivalently efficient manners when the obstacles to bargaining are limited.1 Poorly defined property rights and large transaction costs, however, prevent contracting,2 and thus the initial legal entitlements shape the efficiency of the final allocation (Coase, 1960).
    [Show full text]
  • Why Do Business Losses Cause Conflict?
    November 18, 2019 Why do business losses cause conflict? Abstract Evidence suggests that conflicts between contracting parties are more prone to occur when a party has suffered a significant loss. It is argued that the phenomenon is difficult to understand within conventional contract theory, which assumes full rationality, while behavioral theories based on the concepts of motivated reasoning and reciprocity provide interesting explanations. Thus, losses can trigger motivated, self-serving perceptions and beliefs, which in turn are likely to induce negative reciprocity as well as counter-productive acts aimed at bolstering self-image. These explanations are demonstrated to be well supported by experiments. 1. Introduction Contract managers claim that parties are more likely to become involved in conflict, i.e. to enter into a period of less than efficient cooperation, after having suffered 1 economic losses. For example, in an interview concerning a large construction project1 an experienced contract manager2 claimed that contractors often ´attempt to recuperate losses by raising more unwarranted claims´. Unwarranted claims may then undermine the client’s trust and so lead to a deterioration of the relationship and sometimes to litigation. That losses can engender lack of cooperation and conflicts is an element of several case studies and surveys (e.g. Kadefors, (2005) and Zhang et. al (2019)), and has also been confirmed in experiments (e.g. Feldman, Schurr, & Teichman (2013), and Fehr, Hart and Zehnder (2011)). Hence, this article proceeds from the understanding that losses can indeed lead to conflict, and inquires what might explain this conflict-after- loss phenomenon. Specifically, the article inquires whether it can be explained within conventional contract theory or whether behavioral theories are needed.
    [Show full text]
  • Longevity and Patience
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Falk, Armin; Hermle, Johannes; Sunde, Uwe Working Paper Longevity and patience Discussion Paper, No. 201 Provided in Cooperation with: University of Munich (LMU) and Humboldt University Berlin, Collaborative Research Center Transregio 190: Rationality and Competition Suggested Citation: Falk, Armin; Hermle, Johannes; Sunde, Uwe (2019) : Longevity and patience, Discussion Paper, No. 201, Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität München und Humboldt- Universität zu Berlin, Collaborative Research Center Transregio 190 - Rationality and Competition, München und Berlin This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/222098 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Longevity and Patience Armin Falk (University of Bonn) Johannes Hermle (UC Berkley) Uwe Sunde (LMU Munich) Discussion Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • Screening, Competition, and Job Design:* Economic Origins of Good Jobs
    Screening, Competition, and Job Design:* Economic Origins of Good Jobs a) b) c) Björn Bartling , Ernst Fehr and Klaus M. Schmidt This version: November 17, 2009 Abstract: In recent decades many firms offered more discretion to their employees, which can increase the productivity of effort but also provides more shirking opportunities. This development is difficult to understand in terms of standard moral hazard models. Here we show experimentally that complementarities between high effort discretion, rent-sharing, screening opportunities, and competition may be important driving forces behind these new forms of work organization. We document, in particular, the endogenous emergence of two fundamentally distinct types of jobs. Employers either implement a control strategy, which consists of limited effort discretion, low wages, low effort requests, and little or no rent-sharing, or they implement a trust strategy, which stipulates high effort discretion, high wages, high effort requests, and substantial rent-sharing. If employers cannot screen employees the control strategy prevails. The possibility of screening causes a substantial increase in the prevalence of the trust strategy. The introduction of competition further fosters the trust strategy and induces a substantial increase in welfare such that both employers and employees are better off. Keywords: contract design, job characteristics, screening, reputation, competition, trust, control, high-performance work systems, social preferences, complementarities JEL: C91, D86 *) A previous
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Perspectives
    The Journal of The Journal of Economic Perspectives Economic Perspectives The Journal of Spring 2018, Volume 32, Number 2 Economic Perspectives Symposia Does the US Really Gain from Trade? Arnaud Costinot and Andrés Rodríguez-Clare, “The US Gains From Trade: Valuation Using the Demand for Foreign Factor Services” Robert C. Feenstra, “Alternative Sources of the Gains from International Trade: Variety, Creative Destruction, and Markups” Teresa C. Fort, Justin R. Pierce, and Peter K. Schott, “New Perspectives on the Decline of US Manufacturing Employment” Dani Rodrik, “What Do Trade Agreements Really Do?” A journal of the Risk in Economics and Psychology American Economic Association Ted O’Donoghue and Jason Somerville, “Modeling Risk Aversion in Economics” Thomas Dohmen, Armin Falk, David Huffman, and Uwe Sunde, “On the Relationship 32, Number 2 Spring 2018 Volume between Cognitive Ability and Risk Preference” Hannah Schildberg-Hörisch, “Are Risk Preferences Stable?” Rui Mata, Renato Frey, David Richter, Jürgen Schupp, and Ralph Hertwig, “Risk Preference: A View from Psychology” Articles Matthew Weinzierl, “Space, the Final Economic Frontier” Daron Acemoglu, “Dave Donaldson: Winner of the 2017 Clark Medal” Features Bruce Elmslie, “Retrospectives: Adam Smith’s Discovery of Trade Gravity” Recommendations for Further Reading Spring 2018 The American Economic Association The Journal of Correspondence relating to advertising, busi- Founded in 1885 ness matters, permission to quote, or change Economic Perspectives of address should be sent to the AEA business EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE office: [email protected]. Street ad- Elected Officers and Members dress: American Economic Association, 2014 A journal of the American Economic Association President Broadway, Suite 305, Nashville, TN 37203.
    [Show full text]
  • Democracy Does Cause Growth∗
    Democracy Does Cause Growth∗ Daron Acemoglu Suresh Naidu Pascual Restrepo James A. Robinson MIT Columbia MIT Harvard November, 2016. Abstract We provide evidence that democracy has a significant and robust positive effect on GDP per capita. Our empirical strategy controls for country fixed effects and the rich dynamics of GDP, which otherwise confound the effect of democracy on economic growth. To reduce measurement error, we introduce a new dichotomous measure of democracy that consolidates the information from several sources. Our baseline results use a dynamic panel model for GDP, and show that democratizations increase GDP per capita by about 20% in the long run. We find similar effects of democratizations on annual GDP when we control for the estimated propensity of a country to democratize based on past GDP dynamics. We obtain comparable estimates when we instrument democracy using regional waves of democratizations and reversals. Our results suggest that democ- racy increases GDP by encouraging investment, increasing schooling, inducing economic reforms, improving the provision of public goods, and reducing social unrest. We find little support for the view that democracy is a constraint on economic growth for less developed economies. Keywords: Democracy, Growth, Political Development. JEL Classification: P16, O10. ∗ We thank Isaiah Andrews, Joshua Angrist, Jushan Bai, Harald Uhlig, two referees, and seminar participants at AEA 2015, NYU-Abu Dhabi, Boston University and Harvard for very useful comments. Acemoglu gratefully acknowledges support from the Bradley Foundation and ARO MURI Award No. W911NF-12-1-0509. 1 Introduction With the spectacular economic growth under nondemocracy in China, the eclipse of the Arab Spring, and the recent rise of populist politics in Europe and the United States, the view that democratic institutions are at best irrelevant and at worst a hindrance for economic growth has become increasingly popular both in academia and policy discourse.
    [Show full text]
  • Max-Planck-Gesellschaft
    Discussion Papers of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods 2020/23 Does the Fundamental Transformation Deter Trade? An Experiment Christoph Engel Eric Helland MAX PLANCK SOCIETY Discussion Papers of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods 2020/23 Does the Fundamental Transformation Deter Trade? An Experiment Christoph Engel / Eric Helland September 2020 Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods, Kurt-Schumacher-Str. 10, D-53113 Bonn https://www.coll.mpg.de Christoph Engel Eric Helland Does the Fundamental Transformation Deter Trade? An Experiment Abstract Oliver Williamson has coined the term “fundamental transformation”. It captures the following situation: before they strike a deal, buyer and seller are protected by competition. Yet thereafter they find themselves in a bilateral monopoly. With common knowledge of standard preferences, both sides conclude the contract regardless if its expected value exceeds their outside options. We run an experiment to test whether additional behavioral reasons deter mutually beneficial trade. If the risk materializes, another individual makes a windfall profit. She does so by intentionally exploiting the first individual. The first individual is let down, although she has knowingly exposed herself to this risk. Participants sell the opportunity to enter the contractual relationship at a price below its expected value. This effect is driven by risk aversion, and already present if the risk is stochastic. Behavioral effects are heterogeneous. About a quarter of participants exhibit the hypothesized additional deterrent effect. Keywords: fundamental transformation, bilateral monopoly, sunk cost, Oliver Williamson, windfall profit, exploitation, let down aversion JEL: B21, C91, D22, D43, K12, L12, L14 * Helpful comments by Sebastian Kube and Pascal Langenbach on an earlier version are gratefully acknowledged.
    [Show full text]