The Unifying Role of the Single Currency

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Unifying Role of the Single Currency A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Andor, László Article The Unifying Role of the Single Currency Intereconomics Suggested Citation: Andor, László (2018) : The Unifying Role of the Single Currency, Intereconomics, ISSN 1613-964X, Springer, Heidelberg, Vol. 53, Iss. 4, pp. 215-220, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10272-018-0752-5 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/191191 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu DOI: 10.1007/s10272-018-0752-5 Euro László Andor The Unifying Role of the Single Currency Perhaps the single most tangible symbol of the European Union is its single currency, the euro. Within the European Economic and Monetary Union, it was seen as a tool to ensure that European integration would be truly irreversible. However, the euro has also contributed to cleavages and asymmetries. This article reviews whether the euro can fulfi l the unifying role envisioned for it, examing the importance of the euro in four crucial European relationships. The European Union was designed with the goal of over- tively, and they enjoyed a honeymoon period without ma- coming the various forces of nationalism that had divided jor challenges to the euro. However, under their succes- the continent for centuries. As a programme of peace, it sors Angela Merkel and Nicolas Sarkozy, the cohesion and includes certain economic tools, one of which over the last sustainability of the currency union were called into ques- three decades has been the common currency. Launching tion as fundamentally new challenges arose: the Great Re- an Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) in the early 1990s cession of 2008-09 and the subsequent eurozone crisis. was explained by the need to fully exploit the potential of the Single Market, but it was also seen as a tool to ensure The Franco-German tandem did not collapse with either that European integration would be truly irreversible. It is, Merkel-Sarkozy or with Merkel-Hollande, yet the enduring however, unclear to what extent the single currency can crisis did manage to deepen the intellectual and political fulfi l its unifying mission. Based upon the development of divide between the two countries, making it harder to de- the recent fi nancial crisis and reform period, it is important sign and implement the reforms needed for the long-term to examine this question at four levels: the German-French sustainability of the euro. axis, the North-South polarisation, the divide between the UK and the Continent, and the East-West asymmetry. Brunnermeier, Landau and James explored this intellec- tual divide.1 The trio of German, French and British econo- German-French partnership mists explained that Germany regards the Economic and Monetary Union as primarily a rule-based stability union, Monetary integration in Europe, like economic integra- while France on the other hand considers growth and sta- tion in general, has always relied primarily upon Franco- bility to be of equal importance, allowing for the discre- German cooperation. This cooperation has itself always tionary use of common policy instruments in the case of relied upon a certain personal connection between the crisis. countries’ leaders. This is why it was very important in the 1970s to initiate a meeting of minds between Valéry Gis- While it can be said that the eurozone has recovered from card d’Estaing and Helmut Schmidt. These two leaders, its deep crisis, it is unclear whether it is prepared to han- fi rst as fi nance ministers and then as President and Chan- dle another one. Emmanuel Macron knows this well, and it cellor, worked together to develop the European Monetary was no coincidence that his fi rst foreign trip after assum- System (EMS). Another outstanding couple: Francois Mit- ing offi ce was to Berlin. Macron is Merkel’s fourth counter- terrand and Helmut Kohl, who facilitated the 1992 Maas- part in Paris, and he launched his campaign knowing that tricht Treaty together. he had only a brief window of opportunity to convince the German leadership of the importance of substantial euro- When the euro was introduced, Gerhard Schröder and zone reform. Jacques Chirac were Chancellor and President, respec- Following the 2017 federal elections in Germany, in which both major parties lost portions of their support, the fi rst attempt to form a coalition government occurred between László Andor, Corvinus University, Budapest, Hun- the CDU-CSU, the FDP and the Greens. This attempt gary; and Foundation for European Progressive Studies, Brussels, Belgium. 1 M.K. Brunnermeier, J.-P. Landau, H. James: The Euro and the Battle of Ideas, Princeton 2016, Princeton University Press. ZBW – Leibniz Information Centre for Economics 215 Euro failed, and one of the primary reasons was disagreements tive of this crisis focuses on overspending by the Southern regarding the need for and direction of eurozone reform. European governments. It is claimed that they violated the The renewed Grand Coalition between the CDU-CSU and EMU rules, in particular the defi cit threshold of three per the Social Democrats emphasised its openness to dis- cent of GDP. In reality, Spain and Ireland complied with all cussing eurozone reforms, though without committing to existing rules, and the violation of the Maastricht criteria a specifi c package of measures. was not a major problem in Italy or Portugal either. Cer- tainly, all affected countries committed some mistakes, The Franco-German understanding in the area of eco- and the public budget of Greece violated all of the EMU’s nomic policy and more specifi cally eurozone reform has rules. However, the imbalances were caused primarily by been cultivated by the cooperation between two groups of capital fl ows from the eurozone centre towards the periph- economists: the Eiffel Group and the Glienicker Group. An ery, together with the fact that the EU was unprepared to important outcome of this cooperation was the publica- handle the consequences of these fl ows. tion of a paper by 14 French and German economists in early 2018 which generated a wider debate on the immedi- The incomplete design of the EMU has been particularly ate tasks of EMU reform.2 disadvantageous for the eurozone periphery.3 During the eurozone crisis period, major divergences developed be- However, intellectual convergence between the two sides tween the North and the South. With or without assistance has been made harder to achieve due to mutual mistrust, from the troika, countries in the periphery took a much including misconceptions about each other’s objectives. bigger dive into the “double-dip recession” in 2010-11 than Stereotypes about the weakness of the French economy the countries in the eurozone core. Financial fragmenta- are widespread in Germany. In reality, the performance of tion and capital fl ight caused longer and deeper reces- the French economy remains only moderately weaker than sions in the periphery, which pushed unemployment to the German one, and French public debt is just moderate- record high levels and increased poverty levels, too. Po- ly higher than it is in Germany. These gaps do exist, but litical structures were shaken. Legacy problems continue they appear to be minor, especially if one takes into ac- to linger well after the acute phase of the crisis, for exam- count better demographic trends on the French side and ple in the form of unsustainable public debt in Greece and complex defence functions fulfi lled by the French state. banking sector uncertainty in Italy. France does not need a check from Germany. That is not These developments can be explained by the fact that the the reason why it tends to challenge German ordoliber- designers of the Maastricht system (the members of the alism and its views on the monetary union. What France so-called Delors Committee) underestimated the impor- does need is a political victory for the euro, one based up- tance of fl exible and adjustable exchange rates, and over- on two policy shifts. First, Germany would need to boost estimated the capacity of the EU’s political mechanisms investment and wages in order to reduce its huge current to introduce the missing elements of the EMU (common account surplus and consequently generate greater de- banking regulation, economic governance, fi scal risk-shar- mand at home and inside the entire eurozone. Second, ing, etc.) without a major crisis, i.e. in a preventive fashion. Germany and other surplus countries would have to ap- prove some new fi scal tools which are needed not primar- Undoubtedly, the pre-crisis currency union was far more ily by France but rather by countries in the eurozone pe- developed than its predecessor, the European Monetary riphery, i.e. Ireland, the Baltic States and Southern Europe. System (EMS) that existed in the 1980s, since the national currencies had all been abolished and the European Central North-South polarisation Bank had been established.
Recommended publications
  • The Future of Europe the Eurozone and the Next Recession Content
    April 2019 Chief Investment Office GWM Investment Research The future of Europe The Eurozone and the next recession Content 03 Editorial Publication details This report has been prepared by UBS AG and UBS Switzerland AG. Chapter 1: Business cycle Please see important disclaimer and 05 Cyclical position disclosures at the end of the document. 08 Imbalances This report was published on April 9 2019 10 Emerging markets Authors Ricardo Garcia (Editor in chief) Chapter 2: Policy space Jens Anderson Michael Bolliger 14 Institutional framework Kiran Ganesh Matteo Ramenghi 16 Fiscal space Roberto Scholtes Fabio Trussardi 19 Monetary space Dean Turner Thomas Veraguth Thomas Wacker Chapter 3: Impact Contributors Paul Donovan 23 Bond markets Elisabetta Ferrara Tom Flury 26 Banks Bert Jansen Claudia Panseri 29 Euro Achim Peijan Louis Pfau Giovanni Staunovo Themis Themistocleous Appendix Desktop Publishing 32 The evolution of the EU: A timeline Margrit Oppliger 33 Europe in numbers Cover photo 34 2020–2025 stress-test scenario assumptions Gettyimages Printer Neidhart + Schön, Zurich Languages English, German and Italian Contact [email protected] Order or subscribe UBS clients can subscribe to the print version of The future of Europe via their client advisor or the Printed & Branded Products Mailbox: [email protected] Electronic subscription is also available via the Investment Views on the UBS e-banking platform. 2 April 2019 – The future of Europe Editorial “Whatever it takes.” These words of Mario Draghi’s marked the inflection point in the last recession and paved the way to the present economic recovery. But as the euro celebrates its 20th birthday, the world and investors are beset again by recessionary fears, with risks mounting and likely to continue doing so in the coming years.
    [Show full text]
  • Anatomy of a Crisis
    Page 7 Chapter 2 Munich: Anatomy of A Crisis eptember 28, 1938, “Black Wednesday,” dawned on a frightened Europe. Since the spring Adolf Hitler had spoken often about the Sudetenland, the western part of Czechoslovakia. Many of the 3 Smillion German-speaking people who lived there had complained that they were being badly mistreated by the Czechs and Slovaks. Cooperating closely with Sudeten Nazis, Hitler at first simply demanded that the Czechs give the German-speakers within their borders self-government. Then, he upped the ante. If the Czechs did not hand the Sudetenland to him by October 1, 1938, he would order his well-armed and trained soldiers to attack Czechoslovakia, destroy its army, and seize the Sudetenland. The Strategic Location of the Sudetenland Germany’s demand quickly reverberated throughout the European continent. Many countries, tied down by various commitments and alliances, pondered whether—and how—to respond to Hitler’s latest threat. France had signed a treaty to defend the Czechs and Britain had a treaty with France; the USSR had promised to defend Czechoslovakia against a German attack. Britain, in particular, found itself in an awkward position. To back the French and their Czech allies would almost guarantee the outbreak of an unpredictable and potentially ruinous continental war; yet to refrain from confronting Hitler over the Sudetenland would mean victory for the Germans. In an effort to avert the frightening possibilities, a group of European leaders converged at Munich Background to the Crisis The clash between Germany and Czechoslovakia over the Sudetenland had its origins in the Versailles Treaty of 1919.
    [Show full text]
  • 'The Birth of the Euro' from <I>EUROPE</I> (December 2001
    'The birth of the euro' from EUROPE (December 2001-January 2002) Caption: On the eve of the entry into circulation of euro notes and coins on January 1, 2002, the author of the article relates the history of the single currency's birth. Source: EUROPE. Magazine of the European Union. Dir. of publ. Hélin, Willy ; REditor Guttman, Robert J. December 2001/January 2002, No 412. Washington DC: Delegation of the European Commission to the United States. ISSN 0191- 4545. Copyright: (c) EUROPE Magazine, all rights reserved The magazine encourages reproduction of its contents, but any such reproduction without permission is prohibited. URL: http://www.cvce.eu/obj/the_birth_of_the_euro_from_europe_december_2001_january_2002-en-fe85d070-dd8b- 4985-bb6f-d64a39f653ba.html Publication date: 01/10/2012 1 / 5 01/10/2012 The birth of the euro By Lionel Barber On January 1, 2002, more than 300 million European citizens will see the euro turn from a virtual currency into reality. The entry into circulation of euro notes and coins means that European Monetary Union (EMU), a project devised by Europe’s political elite over more than a generation, has finally come down to the street. The psychological and economic consequences of the launch of Europe’s single currency will be far- reaching. It will mark the final break from national currencies, promising a cultural revolution built on stable prices, enduring fiscal discipline, and lower interest rates. The origins of the euro go back to the late 1960s, when the Europeans were searching for a response to the upheaval in the Bretton Woods system, in which the US dollar was the dominant currency.
    [Show full text]
  • Black Wednesday’
    Salmond currency plan threatens a Scottish ‘Black Wednesday’ Alex Salmond has five plans for the currency of an independent Scotland according to his list in the STV debate on 25th August (and then there is the latent plan F). They were presented as a range of equally attractive options. This makes light of the issue. One of the options – using “a currency like the Danish krone” - means entering the ERM (the Exchange Rate Mechanism) that the UK was so disastrously a part of and which the UK wasted a meaningful portion of its foreign exchange reserves (£48 billion in today’s money) trying to stay within just on 16th September 1992. That was Black Wednesday, when the Bank of England base rate went up to 15%. Notably Alex Salmond omitted to mention the Norwegian krone: Scotland, with high public spending, too little oil&gas left in the North Sea, and an all-in national debt of £131 billion equivalent on a GDP of £146 billion, will need its oil&gas tax revenues to either defend its currency or manage its debt, and will not have enough left over for a Sovereign Wealth Fund. Scotland has the attributes of a lax fiscal policy now: a current deficit of taxes versus spending (called a primary fiscal deficit) of 5% of GDP, with extra spending promised by the SNP that could expand an already high debt as a proportion of GDP. The debt is likely to start out at above 70% in cash, plus another 20% in contingent liabilities like PFI, backing for Bank of Scotland and RBS, and Scotland’s share of the Euro bailout of Ireland and Portugal.
    [Show full text]
  • Why the Euro Will Collapse
    Why the Euro will collapse Whither Europe ?’ CIBAM Global Business Symposium 21 June 2013 Michael Kitson University of Cambridge www.michaelkitson.org https://twitter.com/MichaelKitson Europe is not working Source: Eurostat: 2013 Unemployment in Europe (April 2013) Source: Eurostat, 2013 Youth unemployment rates in Europe, Jan 2000 - April 2013 (%) Source: Eurostat, 2013 Source: Eurostat Explaining the crisis • A debt crisis austerity is the solution • A ‘structural’ or ‘competitiveness’ problem reducing the role of the state and more ‘competition’ • A Euro problem the single currency is structurally flawed The Euro problem • Combined countries together with different structures and different business cycles • Lack of policy flexibility • Lack of market flexibility • Why has the Euro problem not emerged before? • Masked by the twin deficits: – fiscal – balance of payments Source: Eurostat database Source: Eurostat database Balance of payments on current account, selected countries (% of GDP) Source: Simon Wren-Lewis: http://mainlymacro.blogspot.co.uk/2012/03/other-eurozone-crisis.html The lack of policy flexibility • Exchange rates • Monetary policy • Fiscal policy • Resource transfers Eurozone: long-term interest rates, 1993-2013 Author: Spitzl, available on a creative commons license, (GNU Free Documentation License) Data Source: http://sdw.ecb.europa.eu European Fiscal Compact • A debt-to-GDP ratio below 60% • A general budget deficit less than 3.0% of the GDP • A structural deficit of less than 1.0% of GDP if the debt-to-GDP ratio
    [Show full text]
  • Brexit: the End of the Beginning
    ACCESS A BROADER MARKET PERSPECTIVE BREXIT: THE END OF THE BEGINNING BY PETER MADIGAN LONG DIVISION The defining moments that led up to the current deadlock over Brexit JANUARY 1, 1973 The United Kingdom accedes to the European Economic Community, a free trade and customs union JUNE 5, 1975 In a referendum on continued EEC membership, the UK votes 67.2% in favor of remaining part of the bloc SEPTEMBER 16, 1992 Black Wednesday—GBP is forced to leave the ERM NOVEMBER 1, 1993 The EEC becomes the European Union, evolving from an economic union into a political union JANUARY 1, 1999 Launch of the euro, the EU’s official currency MAY 1, 2004 Ten new Eastern European and Mediterranean nations accede to EU membership OCTOBER 4, 2009 New Greek government elected, revealing scale of Greece’s public sector deficit. European sovereign debt crisis begins JUNE 23, 2016 UK referendum on whether to withdraw from the EU. Nation votes 51.9% in favor of leaving the bloc OCTOBER 17, 2019 UK Prime Minister Boris Johnson negotiates amended departure agreement with EU leaders DECEMBER 12, 2019 UK general election. Johnson seeks Conservative majority to push his deal through UK Parliament JANUARY 31, 2020 Current deadline for the UK to leave the EU SOURCE: BNY MELLON COVER ILLUSTRATION: ROB DOBI WHATEVER THE EVENTUAL FATE OF THE UK’S STORIED RELATIONSHIP WITH THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE SEEDS OF THE TORTURED BREXIT SAGA WERE SOWN MORE THAN THREE DECADES AGO. YET, FAR FROM HERALDING A NEW ERA FOR UK-EU RELATIONS, THE REFERENDUM HAS ONLY SERVED TO DEEPEN PREEXISTING DIVISIONS WHILE DESTABILIZING BRITISH POLITICS.
    [Show full text]
  • Protecting Pegged Currency Markets from Speculative Investors Arxiv
    Protecting Pegged Currency Markets from Speculative Investors Eyal Neuman∗ Alexander Schied∗∗ February 16, 2020 Abstract We consider a stochastic game between a trader and a central bank in a target zone market with a lower currency peg. This currency peg is maintained by the central bank through the generation of permanent price impact, thereby aggregating an ever increasing risky position in foreign reserves. We describe this situation mathematically by means of two coupled singular control problems, where the common singularity arises from a local time along a random curve. Our first result identifies a certain local time as that central bank strategy for which this risk position is minimized. We then consider the worst-case situation the central bank may face by identifying that strategy of the strategic investor that maximizes the expected inventory of the central bank under a cost criterion, thus establishing a Stackelberg equilibrium in our model. Mathematics Subject Classification 2010: 93E20, 91G80, 60J55 Key words: currency peg, market impact, target zone models, singular stochastic control, local time, Stackelberg equilibrium 1 Introduction In September 16 of 1992, a day which is known as Black Wednesday, the British government was forced to step out of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM). Shortly before this arXiv:1801.07784v5 [q-fin.MF] 17 Feb 2021 crucial date, the British pound exchange rate was close to its lower limit, and currency market speculators were trying to take advantage of this opportunity to drive down the exchange rate by making immense short orders. Among the other speculators stood out George Soros who shorted 10 billion pounds within a single day.
    [Show full text]
  • Explaining the September 1992 ERM Crisis: the Maastricht Bargain and Domestic Politics in Germany, France, and Britain
    Explaining the September 1992 ERM Crisis: The Maastricht Bargain and Domestic Politics in Germany, France, and Britain Explaining the September 1992 ERM Crisis: The Maastricht Bargain and Domestic Politics in Germany, France, and Britain Christina R. Sevilla Harvard University Dept. of Government Cambridge, MA 02138 [email protected] Presented at the European Community Studies Association, Fourth Biennial International Conference, May 11-14, 1995, Charleston, SC. Comments welcome. In September of 1992, the seemingly inexorable movement of the European exchange rate mechanism from a system of quasi-fixed exchange rates towards monetary union and ultimately a common currency by the end of the decade was abruptly preempted, perhaps indefinitely. Massive speculative pressure on the eve of the French referendum precipitated the worst crisis in the thirteen- year history of the European Monetary System, resulting in the ejection of the sterling and the lira from the ERM, the devaluation of the peseta, the threat of forced devaluation of several other currencies, including the "hard-core" franc, and the abandonment or near-abandonment of unilateral currency pegs to the system by non-ERM countries. Together with political recriminations and blame-laying between Britain and Germany in the aftermath, the crisis represented a tremendous blow to the goals of political and economic integration recently affirmed by EC member governments in the Maastricht Treaty on European Union in December 1991. Nevertheless, conventional wisdom at the time dictated a more sanguine assessment of the prospects for EMU, in the belief that the strains within the ERM were due to the unfortunate confluence of exceptional circumstances -- the shock of German reunification, a debt-driven recession in Britain, and the uncertainties caused by the Danish and French referendums on Maastricht.
    [Show full text]
  • Shock Forced Paulson's Hand; a Black Wednesday on Credit Markets; 'Heaven Help Us All' Deborah Solomon, Liz Rappaport, Damian Paletta and Jon Hilsenrath
    Shock Forced Paulson's Hand; A Black Wednesday on Credit Markets; 'Heaven Help Us All' Deborah Solomon, Liz Rappaport, Damian Paletta and Jon Hilsenrath. Wall Street Journal. (Eastern edition). New York, N.Y.: Sep 20, 2008. pg. A.1 http://proquest.umi.com/pqdweb?index=312&did=1558019831&SrchMode=1&sid=5&Fmt=3& VInst=PROD&VType=PQD&RQT=309&VName=PQD&TS=1222181876&clientId=41143 When government officials surveyed the flailing American financial system this week, they didn't see only a collapsed investment bank or the surrender of a giant insurance firm. They saw the circulatory system of the U.S. economy -- credit markets -- starting to fail. Huddled in his office Wednesday with top advisers, Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson watched his financial-data terminal with alarm as one market after another began go haywire. Investors were fleeing money-market mutual funds, long considered ultra-safe. The market froze for the short-term loans that banks rely on to fund their day- to-day business. Without such mechanisms, the economy would grind to a halt. Companies would be unable to fund their daily operations. Soon, consumers would panic. For at least a month, Mr. Paulson and Treasury officials had discussed the option of jump-starting markets by having the government absorb the rotten assets -- mainly financial instruments tied to subprime mortgages -- at the heart of the crisis. The concept, dubbed Balance Sheet Relief, was seen at Treasury as a blunt instrument, something to be used in only the direst of circumstances. One day later, Mr. Paulson and Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke sped to Congress to seek approval for the biggest government intervention in financial markets since the 1930s.
    [Show full text]
  • Interpreting the Erm Crisis: Country-Specific and Systemic Issues
    PRINCETON STUDIES IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE No. 84, March 1998 INTERPRETING THE ERM CRISIS: COUNTRY-SPECIFIC AND SYSTEMIC ISSUES WILLEM H. BUITER GIANCARLO M. CORSETTI AND PAOLO A. PESENTI INTERNATIONAL FINANCE SECTION DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY PRINCETON STUDIES IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE PRINCETON STUDIES IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE are published by the International Finance Section of the Department of Economics of Princeton University. Al- though the Section sponsors the Studies, the authors are free to develop their topics as they wish. The Section welcomes the submission of manuscripts for publication in this and its other series. Please see the Notice to Contributors at the back of this Study. The authors of this Study are Willem H. Buiter, Giancarlo M. Corsetti, and Paolo A. Pesenti. Willem Buiter is Profes- sor of International Macroeconomics at the University of Cambridge and a member of the Monetary Policy Com- mittee of the Bank of England. He has previously served at Princeton and Bristol Universities, at the London School of Economics, and at Yale University, where he was Juan T. Trippe Professor of International Economics. Giancarlo Corsetti is Assistant Professor of Economics at the University of Rome III and has also taught at Yale and Columbia Universities. Paolo Pesenti is Assistant Professor of Economics and International Affairs at the Woodrow Wilson School at Princeton University. He is a research fellow of the National Bureau of Economic Research and has served as a consultant to the World Bank. The authors’ book Financial Markets and European Monetary Coop- eration: The Lessons of the 1992–93 Exchange Rate Mech- anism Crisis will be released this year by Cambridge University Press.
    [Show full text]
  • Elasticity Pessimism: Economic Consequences of Black Wednesday
    Elasticity Pessimism: Economic Consequences of Black Wednesday Sebastian Bustos and Martin Rotemberg∗ October 2018 Abstract We document the ramifications of a large devaluation episode: the U.K.’s “Black Wednes- day” in 1992. Relative to synthetic counterfactuals, U.K. export and import prices in pounds increased by roughly 20 percent, a similar magnitude to the nominal devaluation. Inflation de- clined after the devaluation, although the prices of fuels increased. Contrary to the conventional belief that the UK experienced an export led boom after the devaluation, we find no evidence that exports or nominal GDP increased. We also find no evidence of a “J-curve:” imports declined immediately after the devaluation, and stayed persistently below their counterfactual value. We test a wide variety of theories of elasticity pessimism, and find that none do well at explaining patterns in the data. ∗Bustos: Harvard University, 79 JFK Street, Cambridge, MA 02138; [email protected]. Rotemberg: New York University, 19 West 4th St., New York NY 10012; [email protected]. We are grateful to Alex Segura, who started the project with us, as well as Alberto Abadie, Jonathan Eaton, Raquel Fernandez, Gita Gopinath, Ri- cardo Hausmann, Jeff Frankel, Mark Gertler, Rachel Glennerster, Robert Lawrence, Virgiliu Midrigan, Lant Pritchett, Dani Rodrik, Julio Rotemberg, Larry Summers and Rodrigo Wagner for helpful comments. On September 16, 1992, the British Pound devalued in nominal terms by around 20 percent after speculators successfully pushed the U.K. out of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism.1 The conventional wisdom is that the devaluation caused a “boom,” since it was followed by increased growth.2 However, we show that the economies of similar countries who did not devalue experienced similar growth rates.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture #3 European Monetary Integrason: the Second Stage (1992
    Lecture #3 European monetary integraon: the second stage (1992‐2002) 欧州通貨統合の第二段階 基礎比較経済論 14 May 2012 From the previous class • The Breon‐Woods system: the internaonal monetary system that existed between 1944 and 1971 • Based on the USD, which was the only currency freely converble into gold • Collapsed in 1971 because the US gave higher priority to its own naonal interests (e.g. fiscal deficits and prinng of too many USD in the 1960s) アメリカ国益優先、財政拡大、ドル紙幣の増刷 • Since 1969, the EU countries started preparaons for a monetary union • I. The “snake” (1972‐1978) From the previous class • II. The European monetary system (EMS) 1979‐1998 欧州通貨制度 • (1) created the ECU, a basket currency • (2) fixed EU member currencies to each other via the ECU (official exchange rates) 公式為替レート • (3) tried to reduce the fluctuaons of market exchange rates within a band of ±2.25% 市場為替レート • (4) tried joint intervenons by central banks when market rates moved toward the “ceiling” or the “floor” of the band • The EMS was supposed to be “symmetric” but actually became dominated by the German mark (DM) The German mark’s (DM) dominance 欧州通貨制度=ドイツマルク圏 The main problem of the EMS ドイツの国益優先 • To keep their currencies aligned with the German mark, the other EMS member countries had to follow German monetary policy • If the German central bank (the Bundesbank) increased interest rates, all other EMS members had to do the same thing • But what happens if some did not raise interest rates due to fears of economic recession? these countries might have to leave the EMS • And what happens
    [Show full text]