Elasticity Pessimism: Economic Consequences of Black Wednesday

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Elasticity Pessimism: Economic Consequences of Black Wednesday Elasticity Pessimism: Economic Consequences of Black Wednesday Sebastian Bustos and Martin Rotemberg∗ October 2018 Abstract We document the ramifications of a large devaluation episode: the U.K.’s “Black Wednes- day” in 1992. Relative to synthetic counterfactuals, U.K. export and import prices in pounds increased by roughly 20 percent, a similar magnitude to the nominal devaluation. Inflation de- clined after the devaluation, although the prices of fuels increased. Contrary to the conventional belief that the UK experienced an export led boom after the devaluation, we find no evidence that exports or nominal GDP increased. We also find no evidence of a “J-curve:” imports declined immediately after the devaluation, and stayed persistently below their counterfactual value. We test a wide variety of theories of elasticity pessimism, and find that none do well at explaining patterns in the data. ∗Bustos: Harvard University, 79 JFK Street, Cambridge, MA 02138; [email protected]. Rotemberg: New York University, 19 West 4th St., New York NY 10012; [email protected]. We are grateful to Alex Segura, who started the project with us, as well as Alberto Abadie, Jonathan Eaton, Raquel Fernandez, Gita Gopinath, Ri- cardo Hausmann, Jeff Frankel, Mark Gertler, Rachel Glennerster, Robert Lawrence, Virgiliu Midrigan, Lant Pritchett, Dani Rodrik, Julio Rotemberg, Larry Summers and Rodrigo Wagner for helpful comments. On September 16, 1992, the British Pound devalued in nominal terms by around 20 percent after speculators successfully pushed the U.K. out of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism.1 The conventional wisdom is that the devaluation caused a “boom,” since it was followed by increased growth.2 However, we show that the economies of similar countries who did not devalue experienced similar growth rates. This result is consistent with a growing body of empirical studies of exchange rate movements that find muted responses on exports (Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2000; Ruhl, 2008; Leigh et al., 2017). We use Black Wednesday as a laboratory to test a variety of leading theories which have been developed to explain this empirical regularity, but find that none do well at explaining the patterns in the data. First, we show how the devaluation affected real prices. The local prices of imports and exports at the dock increased after the devaluation, by almost as much as the nominal price of dollars (Burstein et al., 2005). While British ministers explicitly maintained the peg in order to avoid inflation (Bonefeld and Burnham, 1996), the British CPI decreased relative to its counterpart in comparable countries, with energy the only sector with a significant increase.3 We argue that the surprising decrease in inflation may be due to the (ex-post successful) implementation of an inflation target following the devaluation. Having documented the effect of the devaluation on real exchange rates and prices, we turn to trade flows. The existing empirical literature on the topic tends to either (a) fail to reject the null that real devaluations do not affect the trade balance (Rose and Yellen, 1989), or (b) find that devaluations are followed by a J-curve (or a “horizontal-S” curve), with an immediate decline in the trade balance followed by its gradual improvement (Branson, 1972; Junz and Rhomberg, 1973; Backus et al., 1994; Alessandria et al., 2015). In contrast, we find that imports (in dollars) immediately declined after the devaluation and stayed persistently lower for several years, while both export quantities and values did not increase relative to comparable countries. Devaluations (and exchange rate movements more broadly) have underlying causes, which them- selves may affect the local economy. In this setting, the proximate cause of Black Wednesday is well understood: speculators correctly predicted that the Bank of England would be unwilling to maintain its (relatively nascent) obligations to the exchange rate mechanism (ERM), leading to a “self-fulfilling” currency crisis (Eichengreen and Wyplosz, 1993; Eichengreen et al., 1995). The 1All nominal exchange rates in this paper are in local currency units per dollar. 2For instance, a 2005 statement by Lord Norman Lamont, who was Chancellor of the Exchequer in 1992, high- lighted the “enormous gains the economy experienced” after the devaluation, a view shared by the financial and local press (including the Economist, the Financial Times, the Guardian, and the Telegraph), and the Office of National Statistics. Furthermore, at the time the devaluation was expected to have a beneficial effect for the British economy, hence the well-known (if probably apocryphal) “story of the British Chancellor of the Exchequer ‘singing in the bath’ (Frankel, 2004). Much of the the academic research we’ve found on the topic (Hughes-Hallett and Wren-Lewis, 1995) has also argued that the devaluation was associated with economic benefits, which Gordon (2000) describes as the “conventional view.” Furthermore, it is well-known that nominal GDP for the U.K. did increase (Sumner, 2016) after the devaluation. There were no corresponding financial or political crises in the U.K.(Cooper, 1971; Frankel, 2004) nor was the devaluation part of a package of policy reforms aimed at boosting the economy. 3Campa and Goldberg (2005) find that increases in consumer prices tend to be smaller in magnitude than changes in the exchange rate. Burstein et al. (2007); Alessandria et al. (2010); Forbes et al. (2016) develop theories of why prices move slowly in the direction of exchange rates, by respectively appealing to stickiness, inventory behavior, and the underlying cause of the price change, but all of the theories predict relative price increases after a devaluation. 2 very fact that the U.K. abandoning its peg led to a large devaluation implies that the currency was overvalued. To account for this potential bias, we we compare the U.K. to countries with ex-ante similar levels (and trends) of currency mismatch or exchange rate movements, and find similar results on trade flows. A depreciation is a relative change: for the UK’s currency to depreciate (in real terms), the currencies of at least some of its trading partners must have appreciated (in real terms). This type of spillover makes it difficult to use the standard tools of the treatment effects literature (Rubin, 1974). We alleviate this concern by studying the effects of the U.K.’s devaluation within markets, and find that the results are robust to focusing on within destination, within-sector, and within-destination-within-1-digit-sector flows. Comparing outcomes within markets also avoids bias coming from contemporaneous shocks to other countries or sectors to which the U.K. was relatively exposed, such as the establishment of the European Single Market in January 1993 and the liberalization of Eastern European countries over the period. Many explanations for limited effects of exchange rate movements appeal to the relatively transitory nature of price shocks (Hooper et al., 2000; Ruhl, 2008; Drozd et al., 2014; Fitzgerald and Haller, 2014). An advantage of this setting is that, the U.K. devaluation was large, unexpected, and persistent and its effects stay relatively similar over the next five years. Figure 2 shows that the 12-month forward price of the pound fell at the devaluation (it had been increasing in the summer of 1992), and then stayed persistently lower. Since imports responded quickly to the devaluation, models whose predictions include “nominal prices should not affect trade flows” are generically unable to rationalize our results. In order to evaluate theories of the effects of exchange rate movements, we implement tests in the spirit of Rajan and Zingales (1998). The theories we study all have empirically testable predictions about how the effects of the devaluation will vary across sectors. For instance, exchange rates may not affect trade flows if prices are sticky in a foreign currency (such as the trading partners’ or in dollars), since foreign consumers would not change their consumption if the prices they faced did not change.4 If sticky foreign prices were the underlying friction preventing exchange rate movements from affecting trade flows, then the U.K.’s devaluation would have increased exports relatively more in sectors that are known to not have sticky foreign prices, such as sectors with a world price, prices in pounds, or with high exchange rate pass-throughs. We test each of these theories in turn, and find no increases in the dollar value of exports for commodities traded on exchanges nor tourism expenditure, and find no significant evidence that trade flows in sectors with higher measured pass-throughs (Gopinath and Rigobon, 2008) responded more to the devaluation. We estimate the U.K.’s counterfactual no-devaluation outcomes using a weighted average of countries who did not devalue, with the weights chosen to most closely match the pre-devaluation characteristics of the U.K., a method known as synthetic controls (Abadie and Gardeazabal, 2003; Abadie et al., 2015).5 4See, for instance, Krugman (1986); Burstein and Jaimovich (2012); Burstein and Gopinath (2014); Asprilla et al. (2015); Casas et al. (2016). 5Firpo and Possebom (2016) provides a thorough bibliography of papers using the method. Several papers generate 3 The synthetic control method is appropriate given the event-study nature of our setting, and in Appendix Section 8.1, we describe a parsimonious model that describes both potential mechanisms for how a devaluation can affect outcomes and why a synthetic control-type approach is useful for generating counterfactuals. Synthetic controls require weaker identification assumptions than time-series or panel regressions, since as Abadie et al. (2015) discuss, they are unbiased even in the presence of time-varying unobservable confounders. For comparison, the identifying assumption for difference-in-differences regressions is that had the devaluation not happened the U.K.’s outcomes would have followed a parallel path to the observed average of the control units.
Recommended publications
  • LIBOR Transition - Legislative Solutions
    LIBOR Transition - Legislative Solutions FIA Conference LIBOR: Where Are We and Where Are We Going? April 28-29, 2021 Authors Deborah North, Partner David Wakeling, Partner James Bryson Leland Smith Tough legacy proposals Overview of Proposed Legislative Measures Targeting “tough legacy” contracts Potential legislative solutions in UK and US, as well as published legislation in the EU and NY ‒ UK proposals remain moving targets ‒ NY solution is law; US federal solution likely ‒ UK goes to source ‒ US and EU change contract terms ‒ Mapping the differences ‒ Safe harbors Others? © Allen & Overy LLP | LIBOR Transition – Legislative Solutions 1 Tough legacy proposals Mapping Differences Based on Current Proposals EU (Regulation (EU) 2021/168 of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Regulation (EU) 2016/1011(EU BMR), Proposal US (NY) dated February10, 2021 (and effective from February 13, 2021) UK (Financial Services Bill) Scope USD LIBOR only. Potentially all LIBORs. Currently expected to be certain tenors of GBP, JPY, and All NY law contracts with no Contracts USD LIBOR (subject to further consultation). fallbacks or fallbacks to LIBOR- a) without fallbacks All contracts which reference the relevant LIBOR. FCA based rates (e.g. last quoted b) no suitable fallbacks (fallbacks deemed unsuitable if: (i) don't cover discretion to effect LIBOR methodology changes as it LIBOR/dealer polls). appears on screen page. Widest extra-territorial impact (but permanent cessation; (ii) their application requires further consent Fallbacks to a non-LIBOR from third parties that has been denied; or (iii) its application no may be trumped by the contractual fallbacks or the US/EU legislation to the extent of their territorial reach).
    [Show full text]
  • The Future of Europe the Eurozone and the Next Recession Content
    April 2019 Chief Investment Office GWM Investment Research The future of Europe The Eurozone and the next recession Content 03 Editorial Publication details This report has been prepared by UBS AG and UBS Switzerland AG. Chapter 1: Business cycle Please see important disclaimer and 05 Cyclical position disclosures at the end of the document. 08 Imbalances This report was published on April 9 2019 10 Emerging markets Authors Ricardo Garcia (Editor in chief) Chapter 2: Policy space Jens Anderson Michael Bolliger 14 Institutional framework Kiran Ganesh Matteo Ramenghi 16 Fiscal space Roberto Scholtes Fabio Trussardi 19 Monetary space Dean Turner Thomas Veraguth Thomas Wacker Chapter 3: Impact Contributors Paul Donovan 23 Bond markets Elisabetta Ferrara Tom Flury 26 Banks Bert Jansen Claudia Panseri 29 Euro Achim Peijan Louis Pfau Giovanni Staunovo Themis Themistocleous Appendix Desktop Publishing 32 The evolution of the EU: A timeline Margrit Oppliger 33 Europe in numbers Cover photo 34 2020–2025 stress-test scenario assumptions Gettyimages Printer Neidhart + Schön, Zurich Languages English, German and Italian Contact [email protected] Order or subscribe UBS clients can subscribe to the print version of The future of Europe via their client advisor or the Printed & Branded Products Mailbox: [email protected] Electronic subscription is also available via the Investment Views on the UBS e-banking platform. 2 April 2019 – The future of Europe Editorial “Whatever it takes.” These words of Mario Draghi’s marked the inflection point in the last recession and paved the way to the present economic recovery. But as the euro celebrates its 20th birthday, the world and investors are beset again by recessionary fears, with risks mounting and likely to continue doing so in the coming years.
    [Show full text]
  • Anatomy of a Crisis
    Page 7 Chapter 2 Munich: Anatomy of A Crisis eptember 28, 1938, “Black Wednesday,” dawned on a frightened Europe. Since the spring Adolf Hitler had spoken often about the Sudetenland, the western part of Czechoslovakia. Many of the 3 Smillion German-speaking people who lived there had complained that they were being badly mistreated by the Czechs and Slovaks. Cooperating closely with Sudeten Nazis, Hitler at first simply demanded that the Czechs give the German-speakers within their borders self-government. Then, he upped the ante. If the Czechs did not hand the Sudetenland to him by October 1, 1938, he would order his well-armed and trained soldiers to attack Czechoslovakia, destroy its army, and seize the Sudetenland. The Strategic Location of the Sudetenland Germany’s demand quickly reverberated throughout the European continent. Many countries, tied down by various commitments and alliances, pondered whether—and how—to respond to Hitler’s latest threat. France had signed a treaty to defend the Czechs and Britain had a treaty with France; the USSR had promised to defend Czechoslovakia against a German attack. Britain, in particular, found itself in an awkward position. To back the French and their Czech allies would almost guarantee the outbreak of an unpredictable and potentially ruinous continental war; yet to refrain from confronting Hitler over the Sudetenland would mean victory for the Germans. In an effort to avert the frightening possibilities, a group of European leaders converged at Munich Background to the Crisis The clash between Germany and Czechoslovakia over the Sudetenland had its origins in the Versailles Treaty of 1919.
    [Show full text]
  • Emu and the Adjustment to Asymmetric Shocks the Case of Italy 1
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 1128 / DECEMBER 2009 EMU AND THE ADJUSTMENT TO ASYMMETRIC SHOCK S THE CASE OF ITALY by Gianni Amisano Nicola Giammarioli and Livio Stracca WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 1128 / DECEMBER 2009 EMU AND THE ADJUSTMENT TO ASYMMETRIC SHOCKS THE CASE OF ITALY 1 by Gianni Amisano 2, Nicola Giammarioli 3 and Livio Stracca 4 In 2009 all ECB publications This paper can be downloaded without charge from feature a motif http://www.ecb.europa.eu or from the Social Science Research Network taken from the €200 banknote. electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=1517107. 1 We thank an anonymous referee and participants in the 50th meeting of the Italian Economic Association. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF and the ECB, their Executive Board or management. 2 European Central Bank, DG Research, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany; e-mail: [email protected] 3 International Monetary Fund, 700 19th Street, N. W., Washington, D. C. 20431, United States; e-mail: [email protected] 4 Corresponding author: European Central Bank, DG International and European Relations, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany; e-mail: [email protected] © European Central Bank, 2009 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Website http://www.ecb.europa.eu Fax +49 69 1344 6000 All rights reserved.
    [Show full text]
  • The Bulgarian Financial Crisis of 1996/1997
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Berlemann, Michael; Nenovsky, Nikolay Working Paper Lending of first versus lending of last resort: The Bulgarian financial crisis of 1996/1997 Dresden Discussion Paper Series in Economics, No. 11/03 Provided in Cooperation with: Technische Universität Dresden, Faculty of Business and Economics Suggested Citation: Berlemann, Michael; Nenovsky, Nikolay (2003) : Lending of first versus lending of last resort: The Bulgarian financial crisis of 1996/1997, Dresden Discussion Paper Series in Economics, No. 11/03, Technische Universität Dresden, Fakultät Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Dresden This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/48137 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten,
    [Show full text]
  • The Pound Sterling
    ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE No. 13, February 1952 THE POUND STERLING ROY F. HARROD INTERNATIONAL FINANCE SECTION DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND SOCIAL INSTITUTIONS PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Princeton, New Jersey The present essay is the thirteenth in the series ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE published by the International Finance Section of the Department of Economics and Social Institutions in Princeton University. The author, R. F. Harrod, is joint editor of the ECONOMIC JOURNAL, Lecturer in economics at Christ Church, Oxford, Fellow of the British Academy, and• Member of the Council of the Royal Economic So- ciety. He served in the Prime Minister's Office dur- ing most of World War II and from 1947 to 1950 was a member of the United Nations Sub-Committee on Employment and Economic Stability. While the Section sponsors the essays in this series, it takes no further responsibility for the opinions therein expressed. The writer's are free to develop their topics as they will and their ideas may or may - • v not be shared by the editorial committee of the Sec- tion or the members of the Department. The Section welcomes the submission of manu- scripts for this series and will assume responsibility for a careful reading of them and for returning to the authors those found unacceptable for publication. GARDNER PATTERSON, Director International Finance Section THE POUND STERLING ROY F. HARROD Christ Church, Oxford I. PRESUPPOSITIONS OF EARLY POLICY S' TERLING was at its heyday before 1914. It was. something ' more than the British currency; it was universally accepted as the most satisfactory medium for international transactions and might be regarded as a world currency, even indeed as the world cur- rency: Its special position waS,no doubt connected with the widespread ramifications of Britain's foreign trade and investment.
    [Show full text]
  • Causes, Solutions and References for the Subprime Lending Crisis
    Vol. 1, No. 2 International Journal of Economics and Finance Causes, Solutions and References for the Subprime Lending Crisis Caiying Tian School of Accounting, Shandong Economic University Ji’nan 250014, China E-mail: [email protected] Abstract The subprime lending crisis and a series of relative problems have aroused wide concerns by various governments, especially by financial institutions, which have begun to suspect the easy money policy, the risk regulation of financial institution, and the rating agency. Based on the analysis of the cause of the subprime lending crisis, using foreign solutions for references, some advices were proposed in the article for China to face the financial crisis, i.e. guiding by the Basel agreement, disposing the relationship between financial innovation and risk regulation, establishing the independent currency policy frame, and recovering the market liquidity and confidence. Keywords: Subprime lending crisis, Currency policy, Financial regulation 1. Cause of formation of US subprime lending crisis 1.1 Too easy-money policy The current fluctuation of financial market has been induced by the global easy monetary management since the beginning of the year of 2002. Easy currency policy, increasingly progressive financial technology, continually ascending risk burden and financial lever boosted the current mess together. Especially, when the prices of various assets rise, the international credit can be gained freely by a cheap price. These too easy global credit conditions reflect the mutual function among the currency policy, the exchange rate system selected by some countries (especially by the developing countries with abundant labor forces), and the important change of the global financial system.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future
    CASE Reports The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future Marek Dabrowski No. 497 (2019) This article is based on a policy contribution prepared for the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs of the European Parliament (ECON) as an input for the Monetary Dialogue of 28 January 2019 between ECON and the President of the ECB (http://www.europarl.europa.eu/committees/en/econ/monetary-dialogue.html). Copyright remains with the European Parliament at all times. “CASE Reports” is a continuation of “CASE Network Studies & Analyses” series. Keywords: European Union, Economic and Monetary Union, common currency area, monetary policy, fiscal policy JEL codes: E58, E62, E63, F33, F45, H62, H63 © CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw, 2019 DTP: Tandem Studio EAN: 9788371786808 Publisher: CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research al. Jana Pawła II 61, office 212, 01-031 Warsaw, Poland tel.: (+48) 22 206 29 00, fax: (+48) 22 206 29 01 e-mail: [email protected] http://www.case-researc.eu Contents List of Figures 4 List of Tables 5 List of Abbreviations 6 Author 7 Abstract 8 Executive Summary 9 1. Introduction 11 2. History of the common currency project and its implementation 13 2.1. Historical and theoretic background 13 2.2. From the Werner Report to the Maastricht Treaty (1969–1992) 15 2.3. Preparation phase (1993–1998) 16 2.4. The first decade (1999–2008) 17 2.5. The second decade (2009–2018) 19 3. EA performance in its first twenty years 22 3.1. Inflation, exchange rate and the share in global official reserves 22 3.2.
    [Show full text]
  • Sudden Stops and Currency Drops: a Historical Look
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Decline of Latin American Economies: Growth, Institutions, and Crises Volume Author/Editor: Sebastian Edwards, Gerardo Esquivel and Graciela Márquez, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-18500-1 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/edwa04-1 Conference Date: December 2-4, 2004 Publication Date: July 2007 Title: Sudden Stops and Currency Drops: A Historical Look Author: Luis A. V. Catão URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10658 7 Sudden Stops and Currency Drops A Historical Look Luis A. V. Catão 7.1 Introduction A prominent strand of international macroeconomics literature has re- cently devoted considerable attention to what has been dubbed “sudden stops”; that is, sharp reversals in aggregate foreign capital inflows. While there seems to be insufficient consensus on what triggers such reversals, two consequences have been amply documented—namely, exchange rate drops and downturns in economic activity, effectively constricting domes- tic consumption smoothing. This literature also notes, however, that not all countries respond similarly to sudden stops: whereas ensuing devaluations and output contractions are often dramatic among emerging markets, fi- nancially advanced countries tend to be far more impervious to those dis- ruptive effects.1 These stylized facts about sudden stops have been based entirely on post-1970 evidence. Yet, periodical sharp reversals in international capital flows are not new phenomena. Leaving aside the period between the 1930s Depression and the breakdown of the Bretton-Woods system in 1971 (when stringent controls on cross-border capital flows prevailed around Luis A.
    [Show full text]
  • APAC IBOR Transition Benchmarking Study
    R E P O R T APAC IBOR Transition Benchmarking Study. July 2020 Banking & Finance. 0 0 sia-partners.com 0 0 Content 6 • Executive summary 8 • Summary of APAC IBOR transitions 9 • APAC IBOR deep dives 10 Hong Kong 11 Singapore 13 Japan 15 Australia 16 New Zealand 17 Thailand 18 Philippines 19 Indonesia 20 Malaysia 21 South Korea 22 • Benchmarking study findings 23 • Planning the next 12 months 24 • How Sia Partners can help 0 0 Editorial team. Maximilien Bouchet Domitille Mozat Ernest Yuen Nikhilesh Pagrut Joyce Chan 0 0 Foreword. Financial benchmarks play a significant role in the global financial system. They are referenced in a multitude of financial contracts, from derivatives and securities to consumer and business loans. Many interest rate benchmarks such as the London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) are calculated based on submissions from a panel of banks. However, since the global financial crisis in 2008, there was a notable decline in the liquidity of the unsecured money markets combined with incidents of benchmark manipulation. In July 2013, IOSCO Principles for Financial Benchmarks have been published to improve their robustness and integrity. One year later, the Financial Stability Board Official Sector Steering Group released a report titled “Reforming Major Interest Rate Benchmarks”, recommending relevant authorities and market participants to develop and adopt appropriate alternative reference rates (ARRs), including risk- free rates (RFRs). In July 2017, the UK Financial Conduct Authority (FCA), announced that by the end of 2021 the FCA would no longer compel panel banks to submit quotes for LIBOR. And in March 2020, in response to the Covid-19 outbreak, the FCA stressed that the assumption of an end of the LIBOR publication after 2021 has not changed.
    [Show full text]
  • LIBOR Transition
    JUNE 2021 LIBOR Transition AT A GLANCE WHAT IS LIBOR? Following guidance from the Financial Stability Board (FSB), regulatory led public/private working groups Interbank Offered Rates (IBORs), commonly referred were established to identify and promote adoption to as the London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR), are of robust alternate risk free rates (ARFRs) that were systemically important interest rate benchmarks, aimed based on substantial underlying transactions to at providing an indication of the average rates at which replace the various LIBOR currency rates. Most RFRs banks can obtain unsecured funding from each other were created as a response to the end of LIBOR; while in various currencies. Various regulatory authorities SONIA, which was historically referenced on overnight have announced their support for a reduced reliance on transactions, was reformed. IBORs, with cessation dates starting at the end of 2021, detailed in Figure 1. LIBOR has often been used in the industry as an interest rate benchmark rate for various LIBOR VERSUS RFR financial products ranging from capital markets to lending products including mortgages. LIBOR RFR In addition to LIBOR cessation, other benchmarks Term Term rate An overnight rate such as EONIA (Euro Overnight Index Average) will be benchmark e.g. (with no existing ceasing publication on 3 January 2022 and there are 3M, 6M, 1Y term structure)1 a number of other benchmarks that reference LIBOR in their calculations, which will be reformed, including View Forward-looking Backward-looking SOR (Singapore Dollar Offer Rate) and THBFIX (Thai Baht Fix). Secured? Unsecured Some based on a secured overnight rate, others WHAT ARE RISK FREE RATES (RFRS)? unsecured RFRs are interest rate benchmarks that seek to Credit Risk Embedded credit Near to risk free, measure the overnight cost of borrowing cash by risk component as there is no bank banks, underpinned by actual transactions.
    [Show full text]
  • LIBOR Transition's Impact on the Derivatives Market
    White Paper IBOR Transition’s Impact on the Derivatives Market July 2021 Contents Preparing for a World Without LIBOR ................................................................................. 3 Recent Developments .......................................................................................................... 5 COVID Impact on Fallback Calculation ............................................................................... 6 Impact on LIBOR-based Business Transactions ............................................................... 7 Conclusion .......................................................................................................................... 10 How Evalueserve Can Support Your Transition from LIBOR ......................................... 10 Abbreviations ...................................................................................................................... 11 References ........................................................................................................................... 12 2 IBOR Transition’s Impact on the Derivatives Market evalueserve.com Preparing for a World Without LIBOR The London Inter-bank Offer Rate (LIBOR) is the most important rate globally, referencing nearly USD 370 trillion (as of 2018) equivalent of contracts that cover a myriad of products such as mortgages, bonds, and derivatives. As a result, the transition from LIBOR is accompanied by a high degree of complexity that involves negotiating existing contracts with clients, assessing the
    [Show full text]