Chapter Ten Friedrich Hayek and the Ideological Dispositif of Neoliberalism

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Chapter Ten Friedrich Hayek and the Ideological Dispositif of Neoliberalism Chapter Ten Friedrich Hayek and the Ideological Dispositif of Neoliberalism ‘If money, according to Augier, “comes into the world with a congenital blood-stain on one cheek”, capital comes dripping from head to toe, from every pore, with blood and dirt’, wrote Marx in the chapter of Cap- ital entitled ‘so-called primitive accumulation’.1 It is no exaggeration to apply this statement to the emergence of neoliberalism as well, whose economic doctrine was first put into practice within the framework of Chile’s military dictatorship under Pinochet. Shortly after the putsch in 1973, the neoliberal economists around Milton Friedman and Arnold Harberger, the so-called ‘Chicago boys’, sent the generals their proposals for new economic policies, which were then realised in shock-therapy from 1975 onwards. After around 1978, another neoliberal tendency, the ‘Virginia School’ or ‘Public-Choice-School’ around James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock became predominant – a school which was mainly concerned with the ‘marketisation’ of the state.2 From 1975 onwards, Friedrich A. Hayek was in regular contact with Chilean government- circles. Personally welcomed by Pinochet in 1977, he had a significant influence on the Chilean dictator- ship’s new constitution in 1980, whose title ‘Constitu- tion of Liberty’ was allegedly adopted from Hayek’s 1960 book of the same name.3 1. Marx 1976, pp. 925–6. 2. Cf. Walpen and Plehwe 2001, pp. 45 et sqq., 56–7. 3. Walpen and Plehwe 2001, pp. 60–1. Hayek declared in a 1981 interview that he did not ‘know of any totalitarian governments in Latin America. The only one was Chile 272 • Chapter Ten 10.1. The formation of neoliberal hegemony Neoliberalism has become the general designation for economic policies that claim to realise a market-order that is ‘free’ from government-interference, espe- cially from any attempt to redistribute wealth to the benefit of the lower classes or marginalised groups. Its proponents advocate the dismantling of the welfare- state, the deregulation of labour-relations and the weakening of trade-unions’ bargaining power, all in the name of a ‘free-market society’ and its entrepre- neurial spirit, both of which are in danger of being stifled by a patronising state- bureaucracy. Proclaiming ‘individual freedom’, neoliberalism proposes to bring all human actions and desires into the domain of the market, since it considers market-exchange to be an ‘ethic in itself’, capable of substituting for all previ- ously held ethical beliefs.4 The term ‘neoliberalism’ goes back to an international conference of liberal economists in 1938 in Paris on the occasion of the French translation of the book The Good Society (1937), written by the philosopher and New Deal critic Walter Lippmann. Among other things, the discussions dealt with the question of how to wage an ‘international crusade for a constructive liberalism’, which would be clearly distinguished from the failed ‘Manchester liberalism’.5 A slight majority finally decided to choose the term ‘néo-liberalisme’ for the intended new forma- tion, over against competing terms like ‘néo-capitalisme’, ‘libéralisme positif ’ and even ‘libéralisme social’ or ‘libéralisme de gauche’.6 Notwithstanding the different tendencies, two commonalities could be identified from the outset, namely a rejection of any ‘collectivism’, which comprised not only communism and social- ism, but also Keynesianism and the class-compromise of the Fordist welfare-state, and secondly, against the ‘narrow economic conception’ of classical liberalism, a stronger emphasis on the state, which, according to Hayek, had the task of establishing and securing market-competition as the organising principle of the economy.7 The goal was a ‘liberal interventionism’, which does not intervene ‘against market-laws, but in the direction of market-laws’.8 As Otto Graf Lambs- dorff highlighted in his introduction to the new German edition of Hayek’s Road to Serfdom, the neoliberal doctrine is not about competition alone, but about a ‘competition order to be set up by the state’.9 This self-definition provides a first under Allende. Chile is now a great success. The world shall come to regard the recovery of Chile as one of the great economic miracles of our time’. (Quoted in Ebenstein 2003, p. 300) 4. Cf. Harvey 2005, p. 3. 5. Cf. Walpen 2004, pp. 56–7. 6. Walpen 2004, p. 60. 7. Cf. Walpen 2004, pp. 58, 64. 8. Röpke, quoted in Walpen 2004, p. 70. 9. In Hayek 1994b, p. 12. .
Recommended publications
  • Michael Polanyi and Early Neoliberalism
    MICHAEL POLANYI AND EARLY NEOLIBERALISM Martin Beddeleem Keywords: Friedrich Hayek, Louis Rougier, Michael Polanyi, Mont-Pèlerin Society, neoliberalism, planning, Walter Lippmann ABSTRACT1 Between the late 1930s and the 1950s, Michael Polanyi came in close contact with a diverse cast of intellectuals seeking a renewal of the liberal doctrine. The elaboration of this “neoliberalism” happened through a transnational collaboration between economists, philosophers, and social theorists, united in their rejection of central planning. Defining a common agenda for this “early neoliberalism” offered an opportunity to discard the old laissez-faire doctrine and restore a supervisory role of the state. Ultimately, post-war dissensions regarding the direction of these efforts led Polanyi away from the neoliberal core. Between the publication of his pamphlet on the failures of economic planning in the Soviet Union in 1936 (CF, 61-95) and that of The Logic of Liberty in 1951, Michael Polanyi progressively lost interest in chemistry and started to investigate the political and sociological conditions necessary to scientific freedom and the pursuit of truth. During that time, he became involved with a group of scholars who, equally, perceived the democratic collapse of Europe as a wake-up call for a restatement of its liberal tradition. Whereas the values of individual dignity and social progress that liber- alism carried were needed then more than ever, they agreed that the method to achieve these ideals had become obsolete. Therefore, they focused their efforts on revamping a science of liberalism, which could answer the scientific claims of plannism and totalitar- ian ideologies. Tradition & Discovery: The Journal of the Polanyi Society 45:3 © 2019 by the Polanyi Society 31 For two decades, Michael Polanyi took part in the inception and the consolida- tion of “early neoliberalism” (Schulz-Forberg 2018; Beddeleem 2019), a period that predates the later development of neoliberalism from the 1960s onwards.
    [Show full text]
  • “Bad” Greed from the Enlightenment to Thorstein Veblen (1857-1929)1 Erik S
    real-world economics review, issue no. 63 subscribe for free Civilizing capitalism: “good” and “bad” greed from the enlightenment to Thorstein Veblen (1857-1929)1 Erik S. Reinert [Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia and Norway] Copyright: Erik S. Reinert, 2013 You may post comments on this paper at http://rwer.wordpress.com/2013/03/25/rwer-issue-63/ As we look over the country today we see two classes of people. The excessively rich and the abject poor, and between them is a gulf ever deepening, ever widening, and the ranks of the poor are continually being recruited from a third class, the well-to-do, which class is rapidly disappearing and being absorbed by the very poor. Milford Wriarson Howard (1862-1937), in The American Plutocracy, 1895. This paper argues for important similarities between today’s economic situation and the picture painted above by Milford Howard, a member of the US Senate at the time he wrote The American Plutocracy. This was the time, the 1880s and 1890s, when a combination of Manchester Liberalism – a logical extension of Ricardian economics – and Social Darwinism – promoted by the exceedingly influential UK philosopher Herbert Spencer – threatened completely to take over economic thought and policy on both sides of the Atlantic. At the same time, the latter half of the 19th century was marred by financial crises and social unrest. The national cycles of boom and bust were not as globally synchronized as they later became, but they were frequent both in Europe and in the United States. Activist reformer Ida Tarbell probably exaggerated when she recalled that in the US “the eighties dripped with blood”, but a growing gulf between a small and opulent group of bankers and industrialists produced social unrest and bloody labour struggles.
    [Show full text]
  • Eugen Richter and Late German Manchester Liberalism: a Reevaluation
    Eugen Richter and Late German Manchester Liberalism: A Reevaluation Ralph ~aico* or several generations now there has existed an overarching interpretation of modern history conditioning and shaping the views held by nearly all educated people on the issue of F - - socialism and the market economy. This interpretation goes roughly as follows: once there was a "class"-"the" bourgeoisie-that came into being with the colossal economic and social changes of early modern history, and strove for recognition and domination. Liberal- ism, which admittedly helped to achieve a limited degree of human liberation, was the ideological expression of the bourgeoisie's self-in- terested struggle.' Meanwhile, however, another, much larger class came into being, "the" working class, victims of the triumphant bourgeoisie. This class strove in its turn for recognition and domina- tion, and, accordingly, developed its own ideology, socialism, which aimed, through revolution, at the transition to a higher, broader level of human liberation. The natural and inevitable conflict of interests of these two classes- basically, of the exploiters and the exploited- fills modern history, and has led in the end, in the welfare state of our own time, to a kind of accommodation and compromise. With this historical paradigm I think we are all quite familiar. Recently, however, a different interpretation has begun to gain ground. The outstanding historian Ernst Nolte, of the Free Univer- sity of Berlin, has expressed its central point: *Ralph Raico is professor of history at the State University College at Buffalo, New York. This paper is based on a lecture given at Professor Christian Watrin's Wirtschaftspolitisches Seminar at the University of Cologne, June, 1988.
    [Show full text]
  • Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism Daniel P
    State University of New York College at Buffalo - Buffalo State College Digital Commons at Buffalo State History Theses History and Social Studies Education 12-2012 Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism Daniel P. Stanford [email protected] Advisor Gary Marotta, Ph.D., Professor of History First Reader Gary Marotta, Ph.D., Professor of History Second Reader John D. Abromeit, Ph.D., Assistant Professor of History Department Chair Andrew D. Nicholls, Ph.D., Professor of History To learn more about the History and Social Studies Education Department and its educational programs, research, and resources, go to http://history.buffalostate.edu/. Recommended Citation Stanford, Daniel P., "Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism" (2012). History Theses. Paper 13. Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.buffalostate.edu/history_theses Part of the European History Commons, Intellectual History Commons, and the United States History Commons Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism by Daniel P. Stanford An Abstract of a Thesis in History Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Arts December 2012 College at Buffalo State University of New York Department of History 1 ABSTRACT OF THESIS Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism This paper explores the intellectual life and writings of Professor Emeritus in History at Buffalo State College, Ralph Raico. The central thesis seeks to portray Professor Raico as the great modern libertarian revisionist historian, and the great modern champion of historical, classical liberalism. More broadly, the work attempts to solidify Professor Raico’s reputation as a major figure in the modern American libertarian movement. Raico’s intellectual foundations are fully developed, beginning from grade school at Bronx High School of Science, to his attendance of Ludwig von Mises’s New York University seminar, to his P.h.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Ordoliberalism As a New Synthesis of Earlier German Economic Thought
    Ubi non est ordo, ibi est confusio. Kaspar Klock, 1651. Ordoliberalism as a new synthesis of earlier German economic thought Contribution to Oxford Handbook of Ordoliberalism Editors: Thomas Biebricher, Werner Bonefeld, Peter Nedergaard Bertram Schefold FB Wirtschaftswissenschaften Goethe-Universität, Campus Westend Theodor-W.-Adorno-Platz 4 60323 Frankfurt am Main [email protected] 1. Ordoliberalism: A departure from classical liberalism, conservative traditions and historicism Ordoliberalism was at the start an intellectual movement, simple in its principles of economic policy, but with a background in different disciplines. There were the 18th century liberal tradition and the modern neoclassical theory. There was the growth of a new methodology, based on the Austrian approach, refined by Max Weber and once more transformed by Walter Eucken himself (Lenel 1990). He had had a philosophical education - the Neokantianism of his father Rudolf Eucken - and an amazing historical erudition. Ordoliberalism arose in a German academic discourse, in which the humanities formed a second grand domain of scientific endeavour, which had claimed, since Dilthey, a standing not inferior to that of the natural sciences. Ordoliberalism was connected to this cultural tradition of the 19th and early 20th century, because the founding fathers, in particular Eucken, Röpke, Rüstow, and also Hayek and Müller-Armack, who represented separate strands of ordoliberalism, discussed their theories and policies with references to this past - glorious around the turn of the century, haunted by doubts and inspired by new ideas in the 1920ies and then perverted by Nazism. Ordoliberalism later had to keep up with the progress in economic theory and the techniques of applied work for economic policy and to argue with other economic schools so that these origins tended to fall into oblivion.
    [Show full text]
  • Before New Liberalism: the Continuity of Radical Dissent, 1867-1914
    Before New Liberalism: The Continuity of Radical Dissent, 1867-1914 A thesis submitted to the University of Manchester for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Faculty of Humanities 2019 Nicholas A. Loizou School of Arts, Languages and Cultures Table of Contents: List of Figures 4 Abstract 6 Introduction 10 Research Objectives: A Revision in Politico-Religious History 10 A Historiographical Review 13 Methodology and Approach 23 1. Radical Dissent, Social Gospels and the Community, 1860-1906 28 1. Introduction 28 2. Growing Communitarianism and Religious Theology 29 3. The Importance of Radical Dissent and the Community 37 4. Nonconformity and the Urban Working Class 41 5. Nonconformity and the Liberal Party 51 6. Conclusion 56 2. Nonconformity, Liberalism and Labour 58 1. Introduction 58 2. The Significance of Nonconformity in Co-operative Class Relations 62 3. The Reform League 69 4. Nonconformity, Class and Christian Brotherhood in the Age of Gladstone 77 5. ‘That Church and King Mob’: Nonconformity, Brotherhood and Anti-Tory Rhetoric 82 6. Liberal-Labour Politics and the Late Nineteenth Century Social Turn in Nonconformity 87 7. Conclusion 93 3. Birmingham and the Civic Gospel: 1860-1886 94 1. Introduction 94 2. The Civic Gospel: The Origins of a Civic Theology 98 3. The Civic Gospel and the Cohesion of the Birmingham Corporation: 1860 – 1886 102 4. The Civic Gospel and Municipal Socialism: 1867-1886 111 5. The National Liberal Federation 116 6. The Radical Programme 122 7. Conclusion: The Legacy of Birmingham Progressivism 128 4. From Provincial Liberalism to National Politics: Nonconformist Movements 1860-1906 130 2 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Post-Cold War Economics: Redefining International Trade Theory and Economic Development (Again)
    Post-Cold War Economics: Redefining International Trade Theory and Economic Development (again) The Yusuf Sayigh Development Lecture 2018 Prof. Erik S. Reinert Ramallah, November 28, 2018 Ibn-Khaldun (1332-1406) Created ‘a philosophy of history which is undoubtedly the greatest work of its kind that has ever yet been created by any mind in any time or place’ Arnold Toynbee, UK Historian (1899-1975) Ibn-Khaldun: Cyclicality of History. Desert tribe conquers a city. Once they solidify their control over the conquered society, however, they become attracted to its more refined aspects, such as literacy and arts, and either assimilate into or appropriate such cultural practices. Subsequently they decay militarily and politically and will eventually be conquered by a new set of desert tribes, who will repeat the process. Similar concept: Anacyclosis. Giambattista Vico (1668-1744): Progress With the spirit of the Enlightenment comes the idea of an infinite universe. With it comes also the idea that life on earth is not a zero-sum game; the idea of Progress. My talk today argues for a cyclical interpretation of the ideas of economists in the mode of Ibn-Khaldun. With progress, theory tends to get more and more abstract and decays into a lack of realism, then to collapse and be resurrected at a lower level of abstraction. These cycles repeat. Now is a time of ideological shifts. •US: The ideological extremes - Trump and Sanders – both agreed that free trade is no longer good for the US. •UK: Brexit. •The old EU periphery: sinking deeply into debt and getting poorer (Greece, Italy, Spain, Portugal).
    [Show full text]
  • Neoliberalism: the Genesis of a Political Swearword
    Neoliberalism: The Genesis of a Political Swearword Neoliberalism: The Genesis of a Political Swearword CIS Occasional Paper 114 2009 Published July 2009 by The Centre for Independent Studies Limited PO Box 92, St Leonards, NSW, 1590 Email: [email protected] Website: www.cis.org.au Views expressed in the publications of the Centre for Independent Studies are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Centre’s staff, advisers, directors, or officers. ©2009 The Centre for Independent Studies Typeset in Adobe Garamond and Frugal Sans Neoliberalism : the genesis of a political swearword / Oliver Marc Hartwich. ISBN: 9781864321852 (pbk.) Series: CIS occasional papers ; 114. 1. Neoliberalism 320.51 Contents Foreword ..................................................................................vii A ghost story .............................................................................1 Crisis and neoliberalism ..............................................................3 The pre-history of neoliberalism .................................................4 The birth of neoliberalism ........................................................13 Rüstow’s ‘Third Way’ ...............................................................16 The neoliberal program ...........................................................19 Neoliberalism and the Colloque Walter Lippmann ....................21 Whatever happened to neoliberalism? .....................................25 Rediscovering neoliberalism .....................................................28
    [Show full text]
  • “Neo-Liberalism and Its Prospects” by Milton Friedman Farmand, 17 February 1951, Pp. 89-93 © Farmand/Human Events in His Ma
    From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm. “Neo-Liberalism and its Prospects” by Milton Friedman Farmand, 17 February 1951, pp. 89-93 © Farmand/Human Events In his magnificent book, Law and Public Opinion, A. V. Dicey distinguished between the trend of legislation on the one hand and the trend of opinion on the other. Legislation, he argued, is dominated by the underlying current of opinion, but only after a considerable lag. Men legislate on the basis of the philosophy they imbibed in their youth, so some twenty years or more may elapse between a change in the underlying current of opinion and the resultant alteration in public policy. Dicey sets 1870 to 1890 as the period in which public opinion in England turned away from individualism (Manchester liberalism) and toward collectivism; yet he points out that economic legislation was not strongly affected by the new trend of opinion until after the turn of the century. In most of the world, legislation is still largely dominated by the trend of opinion toward collectivism that Dicey documented some forty odd years ago. True, there have recently been a whole series of elections in which the Right has gained at the expense of the Left—in Australia, England, the United States, and continental Europe. But even if a political trend to the right were to develop out of these small beginnings, which is by no means certain, it would probably mean simply collectivist legislation of a somewhat different kind to be administered by different people.
    [Show full text]
  • The Once and Future Liberalism We Need to Get Beyond the Dysfunctional and Outdated Ideas of 20Th-Century Liberalism
    The Once and Future Liberalism We need to get beyond the dysfunctional and outdated ideas of 20th-century liberalism. WALTER RUSSELL MEAD Writing about the onset of the Great Depression, John Kenneth Galbraith famously said that the end had come but was not yet in sight. The past was crumbling under their feet, but people could not imagine how the future would play out. Their social imagination had hit a wall. The same thing is happening today: The core institutions, ideas and expectations that shaped American life for the sixty years after the New Deal don’t work anymore. The gaps between the social system we inhabit and the one we now need are becoming so wide that we can no longer paper over them. But even as the failures of the old system become more inescapable and more damaging, our national discourse remains stuck in a bygone age. The end is here, but we can’t quite take it in. In the old system, most blue-collar and white-collar workers held stable, lifetime jobs with defined benefit pensions, and a career civil service administered a growing state as living standards for all social classes steadily rose. Gaps between the classes remained fairly consistent in an industrial economy characterized by strong unions in stable, government-brokered arrangements with large corporations— what Galbraith and others referred to as the Iron Triangle. High school graduates were pretty much guaranteed lifetime employment in a job that provided a comfortable lower middle-class lifestyle; college graduates could expect a better paid and equally secure future.
    [Show full text]
  • Core Concept “Political Compass”
    Journal of Social Science Education © JSSE 2010 Volume 9, Number 4, 2010, pp. 45–62 ISSN 1618-5293 Andreas Petrik Core Concept “Political Compass” How Kitschelt’s Model of Liberal, Socialist, Libertarian and Conservative Orientations Can Fill the Ideology Gap in Civic Education International value surveys and misconception studies reveal the crucial role of individual value orientations for political judgment abilities. But in Civic Education, political opinions are generally merely asked for or remain superficial, non-committal statements that don’t get analyzed to foster identity development, perspec- tive-taking and tolerance. Thus, this article discusses Kitschelt’s coordinate system of political preferences as an outstanding solution to fill the ideology gap in Civic Education and therefore to enhance political literacy. At first, I will explain and outline the landscape of the four political ideologies: market-liberalism, conservatism, democratic socialism and left-libertarianism. In addition, I will trace left-libertarianism to its merely known anarchist roots. After that, I will explain how our basic political values are shaped by economic and cultural developments and how they combine to become political ideologies, social milieus and party families. As a third point, I will outline possible applications of Kitschelt’s model for the subject of Civic Education. For that, I propose a map of fundamental controversial issues to help students to discover their own political position. Finally, I will introduce the “Found-a-Village-Project” as highly interactive and controversial scenario to foster political identity formation. Keywords: velop value systems as core concepts. Instead they political cleavages, ideologies, critical thinking skills, emphasize value-neutral, “objective” thinking and political judgment abilities, political compass, “Found- analytical skills.
    [Show full text]
  • Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism Daniel P
    State University of New York College at Buffalo - Buffalo State College Digital Commons at Buffalo State History Theses History and Social Studies Education 12-2012 Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism Daniel P. Stanford [email protected] Advisor Gary Marotta, Ph.D., Professor of History First Reader Gary Marotta, Ph.D., Professor of History Second Reader John D. Abromeit, Ph.D., Assistant Professor of History Department Chair Andrew D. Nicholls, Ph.D., Professor of History To learn more about the History and Social Studies Education Department and its educational programs, research, and resources, go to http://history.buffalostate.edu/. Recommended Citation Stanford, Daniel P., "Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism" (2012). History Theses. Paper 13. Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.buffalostate.edu/history_theses Part of the European History Commons, Intellectual History Commons, and the United States History Commons Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism by Daniel P. Stanford An Abstract of a Thesis in History Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Arts December 2012 College at Buffalo State University of New York Department of History 1 ABSTRACT OF THESIS Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism This paper explores the intellectual life and writings of Professor Emeritus in History at Buffalo State College, Ralph Raico. The central thesis seeks to portray Professor Raico as the great modern libertarian revisionist historian, and the great modern champion of historical, classical liberalism. More broadly, the work attempts to solidify Professor Raico’s reputation as a major figure in the modern American libertarian movement. Raico’s intellectual foundations are fully developed, beginning from grade school at Bronx High School of Science, to his attendance of Ludwig von Mises’s New York University seminar, to his P.h.D.
    [Show full text]