A History of Community Asset Ownership

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A History of Community Asset Ownership A history of community asset ownership by Steve Wyler I would like to thank the Development Trusts Association Board for allowing me to take a research sabbatical in 2007 and the Joseph Rowntree Foundation for financial assistance and encouragement. Steve Wyler Steve has been Director of the Development Trusts Association since 2000. The Development Trusts Association is a fast growing UK-wide movement, bringing together over 450 community-led organisations, which use self-help, social enterprise, and community asset ownership to bring about long-term social, economic and environmental renewal, and transform their communities for good. Over the last twenty years Steve has worked for voluntary and community agencies as well as independent grant-makers, including working with homeless agencies during the 1990s; running the Homeless Network, co-ordinating the Rough Sleepers Initiative and setting up Off the Streets and into Work. Recently Steve has been a member of various government advisory groups on social enterprise, community assets, and the third sector. Steve is vice-Chair of the Coalition for Social Enterprise, Board member of the Adventure Capital Fund, and Board member of The Glass House community design service. © Steve Wyler, Development Trusts Association August 2009 with Joseph Rowntree Foundation. Introduction In the last few years community ownership of land and buildings has become, alongside social enterprise, a hot topic across the political spectrum, evidenced by manifesto promises, government reports and White Papers, enabling legislation, regulation and guidance, new investment funds, community right to buy legislation in Scotland, a review by the Welsh Assembly and an Asset Transfer Unit for England. Despite continuing resistance from state municipalists and free-market fanatics alike, practice has kept pace with the promise. Within the expanding development trusts movement there now exists nearly £500m of assets in community ownership – empty and derelict buildings transformed into busy workspace, training rooms, conference centres, community run shops and restaurants, affordable housing, wasteland reclaimed for parks, community woodland, farms and allotments. An idea whose time has come? If so, it has been a long time coming. For hundreds of years the idea of community owned assets has run like a golden thread though our social history. Generation after generation, people have called for a different way of doing things, where land and buildings would belong neither to private landowners nor to the state, but would be held instead in trust and controlled by local communities, to provide amenities and create prosperity for the common good. If we go back far enough, communities really did own their assets – indeed there was a time when community ownership of land in particular was not the exception, but rather the rule. A history of community asset ownership 3 Free born Englishmen Once land belonged to ‘free-born Englishmen’, but after 1066 the Norman invaders took the best of it for themselves. Even then, the peasants retained access to the unfenced commons, and remained in some respects a self governing community. In the wake of the Black Death, in which a third of the entire population of England perished, came the social upheavals that culminated in the Peasants’ Revolt of 1381, bringing with it new and radical ideas. Before 1066 land in England was return for providing relief from hardship, owned not by wealthy landlords, nor and were paid in labour instead of by the state, nor even by the monarchy, food rent. But extensive common lands but rather by free peasant proprietors, remained, and all the people of a or ‘coerls’. Each family cultivated its own district or village shared the right to smallholding and undertook communal these lands. activities within their own village. The ceorl was an independent ‘free born Englishman’, subject only to the king, The Norman yoke to whom he had to provide military The Norman occupation changed all this. service when required, and the only tax After his victory William the Conqueror was an annual food rent, a quantity of handed out the land of England as spoils provision sufficient to maintain the king of war to his mercenaries, and as a and his retinue for a day. result, ownership of land was no longer absolute, but rested on permission This system was beginning to break of the king, the ultimate owner. Parts down even before the Norman conquest. of the kingdom were kept by William The Saxon kings rewarded supporters for himself ‘in demesne’, and the rest by making them ‘thegns’ or territorial was divided among about 180 barons, lords, and bestowed charters transferring on the understanding they would to the thegns the rights of claiming provide knights for battle when the need military service and food rent from the arose. In turn the barons retained peasants. In some places, when harvests a portion of the land allotted to them failed, thegns would take over land in as their own demesne and divided the 4 Development Trusts Association rest among knights, each of whom rural England. There were no hedges was under a military obligation to or fences; the cultivated land was the barons (and thus to the king). a single large open field, and every The churches and monasteries also year a communal gathering of villagers retained demesne lands and sub-let at the manor-court or court-leet would the rest of their holdings. allot to each man several narrow strips, taking care to share out the good and As for the conquered Saxons, they bad land equally, and on these narrow became serfs: survival in exchange strips each villager tried to grow enough for servitude. Where the population food to feed himself and his family. resisted they were annihilated, and their villages burnt, and for decades after The nobility were expected to provide 1066 great swathes of England especially basic assistance in cases where the in the North remained depopulated. poor became ill, or a man died and The nobility, naturally, kept the best land left a widow and children. Anyone who themselves. Villagers were required to did not work or who committed a give up a set number of days to work transgression was punished, or outlawed the lord’s demesne land, and to serve and left to starve to death in the woods as foot soldiers if there was war. There or wastelands. A rudimentary legal were many other rights and obligations, system did provide some limited varying from place to place, more safeguards for the common people, often preserved by custom than written and above all ‘habeas corpus’ ensured into formal statute. The village peasants that no man could be held in prison were obliged to grind their corn at the without being charged and put on trial lord’s mill, and if they wanted to marry, by a jury of his peers. But the lord they would first have to beg the lord’s held power in his manor, and was, permission, and pay a tribute. in practice, judge, jury and executioner. Moreover, there was also the church, But though in relation to the lord of which claimed its tithes from the poor, the manor they were serfs, in relation to made its own laws and held its own each other the peasants were in many courts, made certain that the common respects a self-governing community. people remained illiterate, controlled In most places, the landscape they public and private morality, and built worked was very unlike that of modern splendid cathedrals. A history of community asset ownership 5 The commons economies. Only the monasteries grew Beyond the open field was unenclosed rich, and were hated for it. common land where the villagers had rights, granted not by statute but by immemorial custom, to cut the long The Black Death grass to make hay, to gather fuel from The Black Death changed everything. the woodland, or to graze their cattle It arrived in England in 1348, landing if they had any. There were also vast at Melcombe in Weymouth bay and forests, but these belonged to the spreading rapidly across the country. king and only the king and his nobility A third or more of the population were allowed to hunt the deer, wild perished, causing immense distress boar, rabbits, and other game. Poaching and social upheaval However, because was a national sport, but punishable of labour shortages, the working by death. people who survived found themselves everywhere in a stronger economic This system was, to a degree, position than before. A class of free sustainable. The villagers were allowed yeoman farmers emerged, who paid rent to gather wood for fuel, but only twigs on land and cattle, and in turn offered and branches they could reach with employment to farm labourers. There was a shepherd’s crook or a haymaker’s rapid transition towards a wage economy, hook, and therefore the woodlands were and bonds which for centuries had tied not destroyed and would continue, peasant workers to the villages in which winter after winter, providing fuel for the they were born were broken. Itinerant poor. It was nevertheless a subsistence workers and their families moved from economy. The villagers on their narrow village to village selling their labour, with strips, with rudimentary implements and neither the restraints nor protections of limited farming methods, could barely the feudal system. grow enough to feed themselves. There was little travel or trade between Wages were driven ever higher. communities, let alone nations. What Inevitably there were attempts to restore wealth the king and barons gathered control, and laws were passed to limit to themselves was more often the pillage wage levels. Suddenly the economy of war (the main purpose of the later was booming.
Recommended publications
  • Towards a New Form of Economic Development
    Towards a New Form of Economic Development: Why the Need for an Ownership Revolution Has Never Been Greater Jerome Birolini Schumacher College MA Economics for Transition SCH504 Schumacher College Dissertation August 2014 1 ABSTRACT The following paper is rooted in what is now globally recognized as one of the main threats for the future of our civilization, namely social and economic inequality. After initially looking at the causes and consequences of inequality, we will focus our attention to the economic thinking which came out of highly unequal times. The mutualist and cooperative principles which were at the heart of their practices remain a great source of inspiration for today's activists and have been informing some of the most promising social experiments which are currently taking place around the Globe. In the second part of the paper, we will look into more details at the community land trust, the social enterprise and the co-operative, three different types of community wealth-building strategies. By vesting ownership in community stakeholders and therefore preventing capital to leak out from the locality, these types of approaches have proved that can help improve the ability of communities and their residents to own assets, anchor jobs, expand public services, and ensure local economic stability while contributing to environmental sustainability and social justice. Yet a key lesson learned from the case study analysis is that a core element of their success is the support of local civic leaders and the establishment of multi-stakeholder partnerships. As economic decline, government austerity, privatization and wealth inequality continue to squeeze ordinary citizens and lead to the rapid expansion of a new precariat, we will argue that this type of collaborative, locally-rooted and community-owned approaches should now be embraced by the public sector if we are to advance the building blocks for a fairer, more sustainable and more resilient society.
    [Show full text]
  • Enlightenment and Dissent No.29 Sept
    ENLIGHTENMENT AND DISSENT No.29 CONTENTS Articles 1 Lesser British Jacobin and Anti-Jacobin Writers during the French Revolution H T Dickinson 42 Concepts of modesty and humility: the eighteenth-century British discourses William Stafford 79 The Invention of Female Biography Gina Luria Walker Reviews 137 Scott Mandelbrote and Michael Ledger-Lomas eds., Dissent and the Bible in Britain, c. 1650-1950 David Bebbington 140 W A Speck, A Political Biography of Thomas Paine H T Dickinson 143 H B Nisbet, Gottfried Ephraim Lessing: His Life, Works & Thought J C Lees 147 Lisa Curtis-Wendlandt, Paul Gibbard and Karen Green eds., Political Ideas of Enlightenment Women Emma Macleod 150 Jon Parkin and Timothy Stanton eds., Natural Law and Toleration in the Early Enlightenment Alan P F Sell 155 Alan P F Sell, The Theological Education of the Ministry: Soundings in the British Reformed and Dissenting Traditions Leonard Smith 158 David Sekers, A Lady of Cotton. Hannah Greg, Mistress of Quarry Bank Mill Ruth Watts Short Notice 161 William Godwin. An Enquiry Concerning Political Justice ed. with intro. Mark Philp Martin Fitzpatrick Documents 163 The Diary of Hannah Lightbody: errata and addenda David Sekers Lesser British Jacobin and Anti-Jacobin Writers during the French Revolution H T Dickinson In the late eighteenth century Britain possessed the freest, most wide-ranging and best circulating press in Europe. 1 A high proportion of the products of the press were concerned with domestic and foreign politics and with wars which directly involved Britain and affected her economy. Not surprisingly therefore the French Revolution and the French Revolutionary War, impacting as they did on British domestic politics, had a huge influence on what the British press produced in the years between 1789 and 1802.
    [Show full text]
  • All Shall Be Happy by Land and by Sea: Thomas Spence As an Atlantic Thinker
    Atlantic Studies Global Currents ISSN: 1478-8810 (Print) 1740-4649 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rjas20 “All shall be happy by land and by sea”: Thomas Spence as an Atlantic thinker Matilde Cazzola To cite this article: Matilde Cazzola (2017): “All shall be happy by land and by sea”: Thomas Spence as an Atlantic thinker, Atlantic Studies, DOI: 10.1080/14788810.2017.1372927 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14788810.2017.1372927 Published online: 12 Sep 2017. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 39 View related articles View Crossmark data Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rjas20 Download by: [80.189.30.139] Date: 18 September 2017, At: 11:45 ATLANTIC STUDIES, 2017 https://doi.org/10.1080/14788810.2017.1372927 “All shall be happy by land and by sea”: Thomas Spence as an Atlantic thinker Matilde Cazzola Department of History, Cultures, and Civilizations, University of Bologna, Bologna, Italy ABSTRACT KEYWORDS English radical thinker and activist Thomas Spence (1750–1814) has Thomas Spence; English traditionally been considered a minor figure in the history of radicalism; multitude; sea political thought. Spence was renowned for his “Plan,” the and land; maritime struggles; proposal to abolish the private property of the land and promote Atlantic; revolution; decolonization; slavery; a common management of it. His claims for the commons as Caribbean England underwent industrialization sounded anachronistic at home, but made him relevant from an Atlantic perspective. By insisting on the connection between privatization of land and oppression, Spence linked his agrarian radicalism to the struggles against slavery and the dispossession of the natives in colonial contexts.
    [Show full text]
  • Universal Basic Income: Some Theoretical Aspects
    EC11CH33_Ghatak ARjats.cls July 30, 2019 10:58 Annual Review of Economics Universal Basic Income: Some Theoretical Aspects Maitreesh Ghatak1 and François Maniquet2 1Department of Economics, London School of Economics, London WC2A 2AE, United Kingdom; email: [email protected] 2CORE, Université Catholique de Louvain, 1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium; email: [email protected] Annu. Rev. Econ. 2019. 11:895–928 Keywords The Annual Review of Economics is online at universal basic income, unconditional cash transfers, welfare policies, labor economics.annualreviews.org supply https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics- by [email protected] on 09/05/19. For personal use only. 080218-030220 Annu. Rev. Econ. 2019.11:895-928. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org Abstract Copyright © 2019 by Annual Reviews. In this article, we review the desirability and feasibility of a universal basic All rights reserved income (UBI) scheme from the theoretical point of view. We first discuss the JEL codes: D31, D63, H24, H31, I38 possible theoretical justifications of UBI, contrasting the unconditionality This article is part of a symposium on Universal of UBI with the many conditions that typically accompany other welfare Basic Income. For a list of other articles in this policies. These justifications range from pure normative reasons to practical symposium, see http://www.annualreviews.org/ doi/full/10.1146/annurev-ec-11. reasons due to the problem of screening beneficiaries and imperfections in institutions in charge of implementing tax and welfare policies. Next, we explore the conditions that determine the feasibility and size of a UBI. The broad picture that emerges from our review is that both normative and practical considerations make UBI easier to defend as a tool of poverty alleviation in developing countries than as a tool to achieve social justice in developed ones.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Spence and the Current Debate on Common Property
    Miranda Revue pluridisciplinaire du monde anglophone / Multidisciplinary peer-reviewed journal on the English- speaking world 13 | 2016 Thomas Spence and his Legacy: Bicentennial Perspectives Beyond the Public and the Private : Thomas Spence and the Current Debate on Common Property Matilde Cazzola Electronic version URL: http://journals.openedition.org/miranda/9220 DOI: 10.4000/miranda.9220 ISSN: 2108-6559 Publisher Université Toulouse - Jean Jaurès Electronic reference Matilde Cazzola, “Beyond the Public and the Private : Thomas Spence and the Current Debate on Common Property”, Miranda [Online], 13 | 2016, Online since 17 November 2016, connection on 16 February 2021. URL: http://journals.openedition.org/miranda/9220 ; DOI: https://doi.org/10.4000/ miranda.9220 This text was automatically generated on 16 February 2021. Miranda is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License. Beyond the Public and the Private : Thomas Spence and the Current Debate on C... 1 Beyond the Public and the Private : Thomas Spence and the Current Debate on Common Property Matilde Cazzola The return of the commons 1 From the perspective of the History of Political Thought, Modernity is the age characterized by the theorization of modern State, which is intimately linked with the defence of private property. In Chapter V “On Property” of Second Treatise of Government (1690), John Locke, the founding father of Liberalism, justified the individual exclusive right to use a natural resource on the basis of the property in one’s person and in the labour performed by one’s body. Locke also legitimized the right of appropriation and accumulation beyond immediate enjoyment, introducing the use of money (Locke, 285-302).
    [Show full text]
  • Towards a Unified Theory Analysing Workplace Ideologies: Marxism And
    Marxism and Racial Oppression: Towards a Unified Theory Charles Post (City University of New York) Half a century ago, the revival of the womens movementsecond wave feminismforced the revolutionary left and Marxist theory to revisit the Womens Question. As historical materialists in the 1960s and 1970s grappled with the relationship between capitalism, class and gender, two fundamental positions emerged. The dominant response was dual systems theory. Beginning with the historically correct observation that male domination predates the emergence of the capitalist mode of production, these theorists argued that contemporary gender oppression could only be comprehended as the result of the interaction of two separate systemsa patriarchal system of gender domination and the capitalist mode of production. The alternative approach emerged from the debates on domestic labor and the predominantly privatized character of the social reproduction of labor-power under capitalism. In 1979, Lise Vogel synthesized an alternative unitary approach that rooted gender oppression in the tensions between the increasingly socialized character of (most) commodity production and the essentially privatized character of the social reproduction of labor-power. Today, dual-systems theory has morphed into intersectionality where distinct systems of class, gender, sexuality and race interact to shape oppression, exploitation and identity. This paper attempts to begin the construction of an outline of a unified theory of race and capitalism. The paper begins by critically examining two Marxian approaches. On one side are those like Ellen Meiksins Wood who argued that capitalism is essentially color-blind and can reproduce itself without racial or gender oppression. On the other are those like David Roediger and Elizabeth Esch who argue that only an intersectional analysis can allow historical materialists to grasp the relationship of capitalism and racial oppression.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Spence on Women's Rights: a Vindication
    Miranda Revue pluridisciplinaire du monde anglophone / Multidisciplinary peer-reviewed journal on the English- speaking world 13 | 2016 Thomas Spence and his Legacy: Bicentennial Perspectives Thomas Spence on Women’s Rights: A Vindication Rémy Duthille Electronic version URL: http://journals.openedition.org/miranda/9022 DOI: 10.4000/miranda.9022 ISSN: 2108-6559 Publisher Université Toulouse - Jean Jaurès Electronic reference Rémy Duthille, “Thomas Spence on Women’s Rights: A Vindication”, Miranda [Online], 13 | 2016, Online since 17 November 2016, connection on 16 February 2021. URL: http://journals.openedition.org/ miranda/9022 ; DOI: https://doi.org/10.4000/miranda.9022 This text was automatically generated on 16 February 2021. Miranda is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License. Thomas Spence on Women’s Rights: A Vindication 1 Thomas Spence on Women’s Rights: A Vindication Rémy Duthille 1 Thomas Spence has long been recognized as one of the very few late-eighteenth- century champions of women’s rights. E. P. Thompson noted that he “was one of the only Jacobin propagandists to address his writing to working women themselves” in a 1797 pamphlet whose significant title he gave in full: The Rights of Infants, or the Imprescriptable Right of Mothers to Such Share of the Elements as Are Sufficient to Enable Them to Suckle and Bring Up Their Young (Thompson 1963, 178). As H. T. Dickinson pointed out, Spence was one of the very few who advocated women’s suffrage in the 1790s (Dickinson 1982, xiv; Dickinson 1994, 184‑185). The extent and sincerity of Spence’s feminism, however, was questioned by several historians in the following decade, a process that culminated in 1992 with David Worrall’s otherwise excellent Radical Culture: Discourse, Resistance, and Surveillance, 1790-1820.
    [Show full text]
  • 'The Five Year Experiment': the Incumbered Estates Court
    ‘THE FIVE YEAR EXPERIMENT’: THE INCUMBERED ESTATES COURT, 1849-54. by JACQUELINE ANN CROWLEY THESIS FOR THE DEGREE OF PHD DEPARTMENT OF HISTORY MAYNOOTH UNIVERSITY, NATIONAL UNIVERISTY OF IRELAND, MAYNOOTH HEAD OF DEPARTMENT: DR JACINTA PRUNTY SUPERVISORS OF RESEARCH: PROFESSOR TERENCE DOOLEY PROFESSOR RAYMOND GILLESPIE FEBRUARY 2017. CONTENTS PAGE Acknowledgements i Abbreviations iii List of figures iv Introduction 1 Chapter 1 Legislation and revolution 23 Chapter 2 Law and advances 78 Chapter 3 Business of revolution 105 Chapter 4 Problems of revolution 149 Chapter 5 Unintended revolution 190 Chapter 6 Exporting the revolution 230 Conclusion 269 Appendix 278 Bibliography 296 Acknowledgements This work is the result of the extraordinary support and kindness of a great number of people. Firstly, I would like to thank Dr Jacinta Prunty, head of the Department of History at Maynooth University for her encouragement in the later stages of this study. I would also like to thank Professor Marian Lyons, former head of Department, for her encouragement at the beginning and her continued support throughout. I owe the greatest debt of gratitude to my supervisors, Professor Raymond Gillespie and Professor Terence Dooley. It has been a privilege to have the guidance and critique of two such extraordinary historians. I would like to thank the following people for their assistance and support in writing this thesis: Catherine Bergin, Pamela Coleman, Phil Condron, Fearghal Duffy, Ann Donoghue, Fergal Donoghue, Eugene Dunne, Richard Fitzpatrick, Darren Fox, Colin Harte, Catherine Heslin, Aoife Holohan, Anthony Hughes, Graham Kay, Frank Kenny, Adrian Kirwan, Paula & Ger Lalor, Niall Mulvihille, Catherine Murphy, Julia O’Brien, Larry O’Brien and my colleagues at JPII library.
    [Show full text]
  • Policy Paper on Tax Reform (Pdf)
    CSI Policy Study Civil Society Institute • Santa Clara University 500 El Camino Real • Santa Clara, CA 95053 • [email protected] • 408/554-6931 January 2006 The Ultimate Tax Reform: Public Revenue from Land Rent by Fred E. Foldvary** The U.S. tax system is widely perceived as too complex, too intrusive, and too demanding of workers’ paychecks. Taxes today claim a greater share of the average family’s budget than food, clothing, housing, and transportation combined.1 In 2005, the average American had to work 107 days just to pay taxes, compared to 44 days in 1930.2 Tax reform proposals, not surprisingly, are popular among voters and the politicians who If land value is taxed, the land will not represent them. President George W. Bush flee, shrink, or hide. A tax on land created an advisory panel on tax reform. value has no deadweight loss. Some economists and institutes have proposed reforms to flatten and simplify the income tax, or to replace it entirely with a national sales or consumption tax or value-added tax. These would be an improvement, but if we seek to reform taxes, we should consider all the possibilities and choose, as Milton Friedman puts it, the “least bad” tax. Even a relatively flat income tax imposes what economists call a “deadweight loss” or “excess burden” on society. Taxes on productive activity increase the price of labor or goods beyond economic costs, and so reduce the quantity provided. This reduction in production, income, and * Fred Foldvary received his Ph.D. in economics from George Mason University in Virginia.
    [Show full text]
  • System Innovation and a New 'Great Transformation': Re-Embedding Economic Life in the Context of 'De-Growth'
    Journal of Social Entrepreneurship Vol. 00, No. 0, 1–24, Month 2012 System Innovation and a New ‘Great Transformation’: Re-embedding Economic Life in the Context of ‘De-Growth’ STEPHEN QUILLEY SPIRE, Keele University, Keele, UK ABSTRACT The political-economic limits to system innovation are explored through the Polanyian concepts of disembedding and the ‘double movement’. The Keynesian Welfare State (KWS) is examined as an aspect of the ‘counter movement for societal protection’ and the outcome of selection from a much broader array of institutional and cultural responses to crisis. With the KWS, the principles of reciprocity and autarchy (the re-embedding of subsistence and provisioning activity in a modern Gemeinschaft) give way to the establishment of new, top-down circuits of redistribution, designed to facilitate continuing processes of capitalist modernization. Where social innovation is directed at the broad dynamics of marketization and the commodification of goods and services, this growth imperative continues to present an insuperable obstacle to system-level change. But as ecological capital at the level of the biosphere becomes a critical focus for a new protective ‘counter-movement’ and ‘degrowth’ becomes the de facto context for social innovation, systemic transformation becomes more thinkable. Hodgson’s ‘evotopia’ is recommended as a heuristic for a provisional, experimental and incremental exploration of the ‘adjacent possible’. KEY WORDS: Social innovation, embeddedness, social capital, varieties of capitalism, Karl Polanyi, instituted economic process, system innovation, Gemeinschaft, degrowth, ‘evotopia’ Introduction In recent decades there has been a renewed interest in the social underpinning of economic life (Nee and Swedberg 2005) with debates focusing on phenomena such as embeddedness and the role of networks (Granovetter 1985) and the social-institutional dimensions of technical innovation Correspondence Address: Stephen Quilley, SPIRE, Keele University, Keele, ST5 5BG, UK.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Spence : Literary Networks and Connections. Daniel Isaac Eaton, Hannah More, and Ralph Beilby
    Miranda Revue pluridisciplinaire du monde anglophone / Multidisciplinary peer-reviewed journal on the English- speaking world 13 | 2016 Thomas Spence and his Legacy: Bicentennial Perspectives Thomas Spence : Literary networks and connections. Daniel Isaac Eaton, Hannah More, and Ralph Beilby Edmund Downey Electronic version URL: http://journals.openedition.org/miranda/9235 DOI: 10.4000/miranda.9235 ISSN: 2108-6559 Publisher Université Toulouse - Jean Jaurès Electronic reference Edmund Downey, “Thomas Spence : Literary networks and connections. Daniel Isaac Eaton, Hannah More, and Ralph Beilby”, Miranda [Online], 13 | 2016, Online since 17 November 2016, connection on 16 February 2021. URL: http://journals.openedition.org/miranda/9235 ; DOI: https://doi.org/10.4000/ miranda.9235 This text was automatically generated on 16 February 2021. Miranda is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License. Thomas Spence : Literary networks and connections. Daniel Isaac Eaton, Hannah... 1 Thomas Spence : Literary networks and connections. Daniel Isaac Eaton, Hannah More, and Ralph Beilby Edmund Downey 1 Thomas Spence’s publications and political activities are currently the subject of renewed interest.1 His works are attracting fresh critical attention and, importantly, David Gardner-Medwin and Alistair Bonnett have recovered the original publication of Property in Land Every One’s Right (1775), which documents the origin of Spence’s plan for land reform.2 Alongside this recent reassessment of Spence’s work, I believe an examination of his connections can shed new light on the print networks that supported his career. This article examines Spence’s connections with contemporary authors and political activists. Specifically, it examines Spence’s relationship with the notable political reformer and fellow London Corresponding Society member Daniel Isaac Eaton (1753-1814) in the 1790s.
    [Show full text]
  • Kennington 1848: Another Look (PDF 2.45MB)
    Another Look Another Look The Kennington Chartist Project was initiated in 2018 by local residents, to celebrate the legacy of the 1848 Chartist rally on Kennington Common. The first volume of Kennington 1848 is called Our Story. In that book, we gave an introduction to what happened in Kennington in 1848, and an account of our project in 2018. This second volume of Kennington 1848 is called Another Look. Here, we explore in greater depth the people and place that contributed to this significant event. The Kennington Chartist Project is supported by the Friends of Kennington Park, the National Lottery Heritage Fund, and the Lipman-Miliband Trust. Contents Title: Kennington 1848: Another Look Author: Kennington Chartist Project How many were in the Crowd? page 10 Publication date: 2019 by Dave Steele Publisher: Independent Publishing Network 1 ISBN: 978-1-78972-278-9 Distributor: Friends of Kennington Park Please direct all enquiries to: [email protected] Who was there? 19 by Vic Clarke © Creative Commons 2 (Attribution-NonCommercial- ShareAlike 4.0 International) Supported by the Who was William Cuffay? 23 National Lottery Heritage Fund and the Lipman-Miliband Trust 3 by S I Martin Chartist Women and the Vote 29 4 by Marietta Crichton Stuart Kennington Common, Protest and Public Space 34 5 by Katrina Navickas Back to the Land 41 6 Findings of the Kennington Chartist Project research group by Marietta Crichton Stuart Further reading 46 Acknowledgements 47 How many were in the Crowd? figures are always contentious (there is no consensus about attendance How many were in the Crowd? at the 2003 Stop the War demonstration in London or the 2017 Trump by Dave Steele inauguration in Washington).
    [Show full text]