Walras in Spain( 1874-1936)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Walras in Spain( 1874-1936) Walras in Spain( 1874-1936) Jesús Astigarraga Juan Zabalza Abstract: This article focuses on the fate of Walras and Walrasian ideas in Spain, which should be contextualised within the coming of marginalism to Spain. Traditionally, it has been accepted that marginalism was almost forgotten by Spanish economists during the period of 1870 to 1936. This statement held on to the idea that Spanish econo- mists did not contribute in almost any way to the theoretical heritage at the time. However, this interpretation is misleading in that Spanish economists were well in- formed about the advances of economic theory and that they applied them to solve the problems of Spain’s economic backwardness. In particular, during the first third of the twentieth century, the main Spanish economists used a generic version of ‘na- tional equilibrium,’ which was merely a simplified adaptation of the Walrasian notion of equilibrium to the Spanish economy, for grappling with the problems of economic development. Three economists in particular, Antonio Flores de Lemus, Romà Per- piñá Grau and more specifically Manuel de Torres, used this version to support dif- ferent economic policies that were assumed to contend with economic backwardness. In doing so, they contributed to the introduction of marginalism, and in particular, Walrasian ideas into Spain. JEL Classification: B 13, B 31, D 50. The central decades of the nineteenth I The Reception of Marginalism century were characterised by the rule of the in Spain so-called ‘escuela economista’-economist In order to understand the low impact that school-whose members radically defended marginalism had in Spain, an analysis of the free trade and were highly influenced by gradual extinction of the classical political such French economists as Bastiat or Moli- economy and its gradual substitution by new nari. The group reached its pinnacle during approaches to economics is required. How- the 1860s and 1870s, when some members ever, this process of replacing the classical of the school served in government and in- political economy had certain peculiarities in fluenced economic policy. Theoretically, Spain, which will be briefly described below. however, the economist school was by no The History of Economic Thought, Vol. 51, No. 1, 2009. Ⓒ The Japanese Society for the History of Eco- nomic Thought. 2 経済学史研究 51 巻 1 号 means original-they strongly believed that pleaded for competition that operates within Bastiat’s works contained the answers to a legal framework organised by the State. most economic problems( Lluch and Alme- The State, however, also assumed social pol- nar 2000, 129-43). icy. Both Catholics and Krausists, however, Things worsened and the last quarter of did not entirely reject marginalism; they the nineteenth century has unanimously been were simply not inclined to debate the latter appraised as a period of deep decadence of (Malo 1998, 378, 459-515).1) As for the in- political economy in Spain( Velarde 1974). stitutional development of the political econ- On the other hand, the last members of the omy in Spain, neither group contributed to economist school like Carreras y González, the adoption of the neoclassical approach. Martín Rodríguez, Figuerola or Sanromá, The successive educational reformations, gradually passed away and the liberal eco- however, did result in placing the chairs for nomic agenda was unable to successfully political economic at the faculties of Law; contend with the problems that arose from thus, the majority of Spanish economists the economic crisis during the 1880s. Leav- held legal backgrounds, seemingly contribut- ing aside the remarkable response of revolu- ing to the disregard for marginalism. The tionary working-class movements, the re- prevalence of French economic literature- formist reaction was basically comprised of the main French journals at the time such as three approaches: the conservative approach Journal des économistes or L’économiste of some politicians who defended the inter- Français were profusely read in Spain-that ventionism of the State; the social-catholic did not pay particular attention to economic alternative to the classical political economy theory and the professional dispersion of and; the so-called Krausist economists. So- Spanish economists who devoted a consider- cial Catholicism was a heterogeneous move- able part of their time to politics, public de- ment that shared the acceptance of a moral bates and consulting, seems also to have framework inspired by the Church and the been an impediment to the introduction of moderate interventionism of the State in so- marginalism into Spain( Almenar 2000, 82; cial issues in common. The movement pro- Laurent and Marco 1996). moted the translation into Spanish of a wide The isolationism of the Spanish political range of works by Antoine, Hervé-Bazin, Le economy began to come to an end when An- Play, Pesch, Toniolo and many other Euro- tonio Flores de Lemus returned from Germa- pean social Catholics (Zabalza 2005). By ny in 1903. Flores, together with Bernis and contrast, Krausist economists were some Zumalacárregui, carried out the first steps of kind of Spanish historicists that criticised the modernisation of Spanish economics in classical political economy on two princi- the first third of the twentieth century by ples: its lack of ethical foundation and the promoting the gradual introduction of Ger- narrow role attributed to State intervention- man neo-historicism and marginalism( Ve- ism. They were inspired by Italian Civil Law larde 1990). Whilst Flores and Bernis were experts or in some questions such as co-op- more connected to German neo-historicism erative movement by Fawcett, and they without ignoring the analytical advances of ASTIGARRAGA AND ZABALZA: WALRAS IN SPAIN( 1874-1936) 3 British marginalists such as Marshall or cal school of economics and that he defend- Edgeworth, Zumalacárregui seems to have ed bimetallism( Carreras y González 1881; been responsible for the introduction of mar- Madrazo 1874; Olózaga and Salvá 1892-93; ginalism and, in particular, the approach of Piernas 1903, 94-95). the Lausanne School into Spain (Fuentes The most outstanding Krausist econo- 2001, 345-429). However, the education on mists like Piernas Hurtado or Alvarez Buylla economics in the Spanish university seems seem to have been well prepared to grasp the to have ignored this reception, since margin- meaning of the marginal revolution, but they alism, as far as we know, was only taught in kept the debate grounded on a mere descrip- some specific academic spheres. A second tion of the principles of neoclassical eco- generation of economists advanced the ef- nomics, and in some cases such as Alvarez forts of this trio of pioneers. These econo- Buylla, they explicitly rejected the use of mists did not produce any theoretical contri- maths by Walras. In any case, they focused bution to economics with the exception of their attention on Austrian marginalists such Bernácer. However, some of them like Olar- as Menger or Böhm-Bawerk( Malo 1998). iaga or Fernández Baños seem to have com- Other minor Krausist economists like Jimén- pletely understood the meaning of neoclassi- ez, following the Italian Loria, considered cal economics (Almenar 2001). However, the contributions to mathematical economics the most worthwhile contributions of the and in particular those by Walras as entirely Spanish to economic science were made in inaccurate (Perdices and Reeder 2003, the applied fields. In particular, during the 414-15). The members of the liberal econo- 1930s and on the trail of Flores, both Romà mist school mentioned above seem to have Perpiñá and Torres took the notion of gener- perceived the significance of marginalism in al equilibrium as the analytical framework general and Walras’s contributions in partic- with which to address the Spanish backward- ular. Figuerola, for example, praised in 1880 ness as we will demonstrate below. the mathematical contributions of Walras as they confirmed, according to him, the princi- II Walras and General Equilibrium ples of free trade3); and the economist and in Spanish Economic Literature winner of the Nobel Prize for Literature José (1874-1936) Echegaray declared in his memories to have The isolationist context described above did a profound knowledge of Walras’s work and not promote a propitious climate for the ex- to have planned a mathematical reinterpreta- pansion of Walrasian ideas in Spain. In fact, tion of the political economy, which actually the Spanish economists only marginally never was completed( Cabrillo 2000, 486- mentioned Walras’s contributions to eco- 87; Pascual 2000, 540-41).4) Summing up, nomics.2) The mentions, however, were the works of the Spanish economists of the mainly embedded within handbooks normal- last third of the nineteenth century reveal ly used to teach political economy at the fac- that they had heard of Walras’s contributions ulties of Law, and thus, they merely pointed to mathematical economics but not to what out that Walras belonged to the mathemati- extent they had understood them.5) 4 経済学史研究 51 巻 1 号 Flores’s return to Spain at the beginning wrote an intellectual biography of Pareto in of the twentieth century brought about a which he stressed and explained the close change in the pattern of reception of eco- connection between Walras and Pareto, re- nomic ideas in Spain. As mentioned, he be- garding the representation of general equilib- came fascinated by German neo-historicism rium through the system of simultaneous
Recommended publications
  • Lucas on the Relationship Between Theory and Ideology
    Discussion Paper No. 2010-28 | November 17, 2010 | http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2010-28 Lucas on the Relationship between Theory and Ideology Michel De Vroey IRES, University of Louvain Please cite the corresponding journal article: http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2011-4 Abstract This paper concerns a neglected aspect of Lucas’s work: his methodological writings, published and unpublished. Particular attention is paid to his views on the relationship between theory and ideology. I start by setting out Lucas’s non-standard conception of theory: to him, a theory and a model are the same thing. I also explore the different facets and implications of this conception. In the next two sections, I debate whether Lucas adheres to two methodological principles that I dub the ‘non-interference’ precept (the proposition that ideological viewpoints should not influence theory), and the ‘non-exploitation’ precept (that the models’ conclusions should not be transposed into policy recommendations, in so far as these conclusions are built into the models’ premises). The last part of the paper contains my assessment of Lucas’s ideas. First, I bring out the extent to which Lucas departs from the view held by most specialized methodologists. Second, I wonder whether the new classical revolution resulted from a political agenda. Third and finally, I claim that the tensions characterizing Lucas’s conception of theory follow from his having one foot in the neo- Walrasian and the other in the Marshallian–Friedmanian universe. JEL B22, B31, B41, E30 Keywords Lucas; new classical macroeconomics; methodology Correspondence Michel De Vroey, IRES, University of Louvain, Place Montesquieu 3, B- 3458 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium: e-mail: [email protected] A first version of this paper was presented at seminars given at the University of Toronto and the University of British Columbia.
    [Show full text]
  • The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: a Critique of Received Explanations
    The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: A Critique of Received Explanations Joseph T. Salerno or roughly the first three quarters of the nineteenth century, the "liberal school" thoroughly dominated economic thinking and teaching in F France.1 Adherents of the school were also to be found in the United States and Italy, and liberal doctrines exercised a profound influence on prominent German and British economists. Although its numbers and au- thority began to dwindle after the 1870s, the school remained active and influential in France well into the 1920s. Even after World War II, there were a few noteworthy French economists who could be considered intellectual descendants of the liberal tradition. Despite its great longevity and wide-ranging influence, the scientific con- tributions of the liberal school and their impact on the development of Eu- ropean and U.S. economic thought—particularly on those economists who are today recognized as the forerunners, founders, and early exponents of marginalist economics—have been belittled or simply ignored by most twen- tieth-century Anglo-American economists and historians of thought. A number of doctrinal scholars, including Joseph Schumpeter, have noted and attempted to explain the curious neglect of the school in the En- glish-language literature. In citing the school's "analytical sterility" or "indif- ference to pure theory" as a main cause of its neglect, however, their expla- nations have overlooked a salient fact: that many prominent contributors to economic analysis throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries expressed strong appreciation of or weighty intellectual debts to the purely theoretical contributions of the liberal school.
    [Show full text]
  • Firmin Oulès and the “New Lausanne School”
    Firmin Oulès and the "New Lausanne School" David Sarech (University of Lausanne, Ph.D. Student) In this paper I will present Firmin Oulès’ “harmonized economics” and interrogate the relationship between state and market in his thought. “Harmonized economics” were conceived as the continuation of Léon Walras’ theory. The key concept of the first Lausanne school is the notion of equilibrium. Indeed, Walras forged it in order to “scientifically” demonstrate the superiority of a competition-based economy. However, the mathematical approach he chose, as well as his disdain for the orthodox economy of his time, led him to be misunderstood and he did not receive the recognition he was expecting. Thus the concept of general equilibrium would be forgotten until the mid 1950’s when it would become the core of microeconomics. However, as recent studies in history of economic thought have shown, the concept of equilibrium in Walras’ thought has to be understood in a broader context than a purely economical one. Indeed, the main goal of Walras was to bring an answer to “the social question”. Contrary to Marx, he did not think of it as being a problem of profit distribution between labor and capital. Instead he thought the goal of the economist was to create an economic system were everyone would be able to exert its inner abilities and in which inequalities would be based solely on merit. The incentive created by private property and profit-seeking being the groundwork of a flourishing economy, the equilibrium had to be understood as a tool to establish this idealistic society.
    [Show full text]
  • Adam Smith and the Austrian School of Economics: the Problem of Diamonds and Water
    Stefan Poier 1st year Part-time Doctoral Studies Adam Smith and the Austrian School of Economics: The Problem of Diamonds and Water Keywords: Adam Smith, Austrian School of Economics, Value Paradox, Marginal Utility, Decision Making Introduction When end of 2017 Leonardo da Vinci's painting "Salvator Mundi" was auctioned off for over $450 million, it was nearly three times as expensive as the second most expensive painting, a Picasso, and it could have compensated for the state deficit of Lithuania. An absurdly high sum for a piece of wood and oil paint. How do you explain such a price? Neither the amount of time spent working on it, nor the benefits from this work alone could justify it. Why do we often pay high prices for goods with little use, but low prices for things that are sometimes partially vital? Generations of economists and philosophers have tried to resolve this apparent paradox. An explanation for this price is - quite simply - an individual’s willingness to pay this price. The prestige gain of owning one of only fifteen paintings of the probably most important artist and universal scholar of all time can already provide an enormous increase in status. It is the scarcity, the uniqueness of the artwork, which justified the high increase in utility or satisfaction. If there were any number of similar works, no one would pay more than the utility value for it. This – today rational – economic inference was not always granted. It is based on the recognition that the benefits of consumption of a good decreases with the amount consumed (and thus with the saturation of the consumer).
    [Show full text]
  • Schools of Economic Thought (Pdf)
    SCHOOLS OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT A BRIEF HISTORY OF ECONOMICS This isn't really essential to know, but may satisfy the curiosity of many. Mercantilism Economics is said to begin with Adam Smith in 1776. Prior to that, nobody thought of economics, or markets, as an object of study. It is not that they didn't pay attention to economic matters, it is simply that they didn't think of it in any systematic or coherent manner. It was all just off-the-cuff intuition and policy proposals by a myriad of merchants, government officials & journalists, principally in Britain. It is common to denote the period before 1776 as "Mercantilism". It wasn't a coherent school of thought, but a hodge-podge of varying ideas about improving tax revenues, the value & movements of gold and how nations competed for international commerce & colonies. Mostly protectionist, 'war-minded', and all haphazardly argued. (the principal features of the Mercantilist school are discussed in our "Gains from Trade" handout). There was some opposition to Mercantilist doctrines, notably among French and Scottish thinkers (e.g. Pierre de Boisguilbert, Francois Quesnay, Jacques Turgot and David Hume) Classical School The Enlightenment era (mid-1700s) in Europe brought a new spirit of scientific inquiry. Thinkers began looking to apply scientific principles not only to the physical world, but also to human society. In the same spirit that Sir Isaac Newton 'discovered' the "law of gravity" to explain the interaction of natural forces and decipher how the physical world operates, Enlightenment thinkers began trying to discover the "laws" of human interaction, to explain how human society operates.
    [Show full text]
  • Austrian Economic Thought: Its Evolution and Its Contribution to Consumer Behavior
    A Great Revolution in Economics –Vienna 1871 and after Austrian economic thought: its evolution and its contribution to consumer behavior Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen A great REVOLUTION In economics —VIENNA 1871 and after AUSTRIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT: ITS EVOLUTION AND ITS CONTRIBUTION TO CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen The letter type on the cover is of Arnold Böcklin (Basel 1827-1901 Fiesole). It is a typical example of the Art Nouveau (Jugendstil) style—the fashionable style of art in Vienna at the end of the 19th century (the time older Austrianism came in full swing). In a sense, Böcklin’s work represents the essence of Austrianism: “Never was he interested in the accidental; he wanted the everlasting”. Cereales Foundation, publisher Wageningen University P.O. Box 357, 6700 AJ Wageningen, The Netherlands E [email protected] Printed by Grafisch Service Centrum Van Gils B.V. Cover design by Hans Weggen (Art Director Cereales) © 2001 Lazaros Th. Houmanidis and Auke R. Leen ISBN 90-805724-3-8 In the memory of our beloved colleague JACOB JAN KRABBE PREFACE A Great Revolution in Economics—Vienna 1871 and after is about the revolution in economic thought that started in Vienna in the last quarter of the nineteenth century. After a time of trying to save the objective value theory the time was there for a new awakening of economic thought. In Vienna, for the first time by the 1871 publication of Menger’s Grundsätze, value become subjective, and the market a process with a sovereign consumer. This book is about this awakening that proved to be more than a plaisanterie viennoise.
    [Show full text]
  • Regarding the Past
    Regarding the Past Proceedings of the 20th Conference of the History of Economic Thought Society of Australia University of Queensland 11-13 July 2007 Edited by Peter E. Earl and Bruce Littleboy This book comprises complete texts and/or abstracts of refereed papers presented at the 20th Conference of the History of Economic Thought Society of Australia held at The Women’s College, University of Queensland, 11-13 July 2007. © Selection and editorial material Peter E. Earl and Bruce Littleboy; individual chapters, the respective contributors Published by The School of Economics University of Queensland St Lucia, Brisbane QLD 4072 Australia ISBN: 9781 8649 98 979 (pbk); 9781 8649 98 955 (CD-ROM) All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical or photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior permission of the publisher. Printed in Australia by the University of Queensland Printery Contents List of Contributors v Introduction Peter E. Earl and Bruce Littleboy vii 1 History for Economics: Learning from the Past 1 Alexander Dow and Sheila Dow 2 Theories of Economic Development in the Scottish Enlightenment 9 Alexander Dow and Sheila Dow 3 Ethical Foundations of Adam Smith’s Political Economy 25 James E. Alvey 4 Smith and the Materialist Theory of History 44 Jeremy Shearmur 5 Post-Keynesianism and the Possibility of a Post-Keynesian Politics 62 Geoff Dow 6 George Stigler’s Rhetoric – Dreams of Martin Luther 78 Craig Freedman 7 Why is the Austrian School’s Methodology Problematical? 103 Troy P.
    [Show full text]
  • Food Safety Versus an Individual in the Theory of Economics
    p-ISSN 0044-1600 e-ISSN 2392-3458 Problems of Agricultural Economics www.zer.waw.pl 3(352) 2017, 41-59 Translation from Polish StaniSław KowalczyK DOI: 10.5604/00441600.1245845 Institute of Agricultural and Food Economics – National Research Institute Warsaw FOOD SAFETY VERSUS AN INDIVIDUAL IN THE THEORY OF ECONOMICS one knows little of little life unlesshe has a theoretical system by which to interpret it. (J.K. Galbraith, the new industrial State, 1967) Abstract the paper attempts to define theoretical grounds for the phenomenon of food safety. Usually, food safety refers to two key areas: the presence of foreign substances in food and food falsification.t he former describes food safety in terms of health, the latter in terms of economic aspects. the focal point of the analysis is the “individual”, whose status is very different in respective theories of economics. the discussions compared the approach to the role and character of the individual in all major schools of economic thought ranging from classical liberalism, Keynesian school, Schumpete- rian school to neo-institutional and behavioural schools. the author con- cludes that what best explains the behaviour of individuals in its market activity as regards food safety is the neoclassical approach. Finally, the paper formulates the prerequisites to provide consumers with the desired food safety status. Keywords: food safety, individual in the theory of economics, food quality, schools of economic thought, technostructure. JEL codes: A11, L66, Q18. Problems of Agricultural Economics 42 Stanisław Kowalczyk Food safety today According to Galbraith, there is little in theory that cannot be tested in life.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic History
    History of Economic Thought Ed. by Dr. Edilberto Segura Throughout history, economists have been concerned with the workings of an economy. A typical representation of the workings of an economy would include three markets, goods markets, labor markets, and capital markets, as follows: The concerns of economists over time included questions such as: What determines prices in these three markets (good prices, labor prices [wages], money price [interest rates])? What determines quantities in these three markets (goods produced/consumed, quantity of labor employment, investment levels)? What should be the organization of production (private sector, collective, government)? What should be the role of the government? How to maintain economic growth and stability?, etc. These questions were addressed by different schools of economic though over time, by the following main schools of economic thought: Ancient Greek Economists (380 BC) The Scholastics (1200 AD) Late Scholastic Period: The Salamanca School (1536 AD) The Mercantilists (1568 AD) The Physiocrats (1768 AD) The Classical School (1776 AD) The Neoclassical School (1870 AD) The Marxist School (1848 AD) The Keynesian School (1936 AD) The Neo-Keynesian School (1937 AD) The Post-Keynesian School (1965 AD) The New Monetarist Chicago School (1970 AD) The New Classical School (1980s AD) The Institutional School (1900 AD) The Economic Development Theories (1930 AD) 2 Ancient Greek Economists (380 BC) The study of Economics started with the ancient Greeks, principally Aristotle (380 BC). They looked at economics from an ethical and moral angle. On the goods market: What is a just or fair price in an exchange of money for goods? In the labor market: Is forced labor without wages (slavery) justified? In the capital markets: Is it fair to charge interest rates? On the issue of "just prices” Aristotle (in his book Ethics) had said that the “just” exchange ratio of goods (i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomics: Theories and Policies Ii (Eco2c06)
    School of Distance Education MACROECONOMICS: THEORIES AND POLICIES II (ECO2C06) STUDY MATERIAL II SEMESTER CORE COURSE MA ECONOMICS (2019 Admission ONWARDS) UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION Calicut University P.O, Malappuram Kerala, India 673 635. 190306 Macro Economics : Theories and Policies II Page 1 School of Distance Education UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION STUDY MATERIAL SECOND SEMESTER MA ECONOMICS (2019 ADMISSION) CORE COURSE : ECO2C06 : MACROECONOMICS : THEORIES AND POLICIES II Prepared by : SUJIN K N, Assistant Professor, PG & Research Department of Economics, Government College, Kodanchery, Kozhikode - 673 580. Scrutinized by : Dr.K.X Joseph, Professor (Retd.), Dr.John Matthai Centre, Thrissur. Macro Economics : Theories and Policies II Page 2 School of Distance Education CONTENTS I Classical Vs Keynes 5 II Monetarism 79 New Classical Macro Economics, Real III Business cycle School and Supply side 93 Economics IV The New Keynes School 126 V New Political Macroeconomics 151 Macro Economics : Theories and Policies II Page 3 School of Distance Education Macro Economics : Theories and Policies II Page 4 School of Distance Education MODULE I CLASSICAL VS KEYNES “Economics is an easy subject in which few excel”-- John Maynard Keynes INTRODUCTION TO MACROECONOMICS Macro economics is the branch of economics studying the behaviour of the aggregate economy – at the regional, national or international level. In other words Macroeconomics is the study of the behavior of the whole economy or economy as a whole. It is concerned with the determination of the broad aggregates in the economy, in particular the national output, unemployment, inflation and the balance of payments position.
    [Show full text]
  • Revisiting a Definition Toward the Meaning of the New Political Economy
    International Journal of Innovation, Creativity and Change. www.ijicc.net Volume 10, Issue 10, 2020 The Meaning of Political Economy: Revisiting a Definition toward the Meaning of the New Political Economy Mohd Syakir Mohd Rosdia*, Richard Jacksonb, aCenter for Islamic Development Management Studies, 11800 Universiti Sains Malaysia, Penang, Malaysia, bNational Centre for Peace and Conflict Studies, University of Otago, New Zealand, Email: a*[email protected]/[email protected] The aim of this article is to examine the meaning of political economy. Although it is clearly defined, scholars throughout history have been challenged to distinguish the science of political economy and the sciences of economics and politics as separate disciplines. There are two problems. Firstly, we need to recognize accurately the scholars in political economy. Secondly, there has been a clash of ideas as many scholars built a framework of understanding in political economy. Many scholars mixed their ideas to build a specific framework of meaning of political economy. Some scholars approached political economy from an economic perspective, others from a political perspective. Based on a literature review and textual analysis, this paper will re-evaluate the meaning of political economy that recognises the need to focus on both the definition and the history of the field. It can be difficult to recognize the contribution of economic scholars such as Smith and Ricardo or political scholars such as Marx in the field of political economy. However, it has been established that they contributed to an ideology that developed the understanding of classical political economy. Adjusting for a political scholars’ perspective and economical scholars’ perspective, the pathway from the classical political economy into the new political economy is still to infer the meaning of political economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Report on Economizing on Justice
    Report on Economizing on Justice José Castro Caldas This Report was written within the framework of Work Package 6 “Struggles for Justice’’ May 18 Funded by the Horizon 2020 Framework Programme of the European Union Acknowledgements The author is grateful to Maria Paula Meneses who first invited and challenged him to contribute with this paper to project Ethos, to Nuno Teles and two reviewers of the Ethos team whose supposedly Want to learn more about what we are working ‘minor’ remarks provoked a substantial revision of on? the first draft, hopefully leading to a much better paper. Visit us at: Website: https://ethos-europe.eu Facebook: www.facebook.com/ethosjustice/ Blog: www.ethosjustice.wordpress.com Twitter: www.twitter.com/ethosjustice Hashtag: #ETHOSjustice Youtube: www.youtube.com/ethosjustice European Landscapes of Justice (web) app: http://myjustice.eu/ This publication has been produced with the financial support of the Horizon 2020 Framework Programme of the European Union. The contents of this publication are the sole responsibility of the authors and can in no way be taken to reflect the views of the European Commission. Copyright © 2018, ETHOS consortium – All rights reserved ETHOS project The ETHOS project has received funding from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme under grant agreement No. 727112 2 About ETHOS ETHOS - Towards a European THeory Of juStice and fairness, is a European Commission Horizon 2020 research project that seeks to provide building blocks for the development of an
    [Show full text]