The Eastland Company in Prussia, 1579-1585 Author(S): Adam Szelagowski and N

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Eastland Company in Prussia, 1579-1585 Author(S): Adam Szelagowski and N The Eastland Company in Prussia, 1579-1585 Author(s): Adam Szelagowski and N. S. B. Gras Source: Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, Vol. 6 (1912), pp. 163-184 Published by: Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Royal Historical Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3678245 Accessed: 27-06-2016 07:37 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Cambridge University Press, Royal Historical Society are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Transactions of the Royal Historical Society This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Mon, 27 Jun 2016 07:37:36 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms THE EASTLAND COMPANY IN PRUSSIA, 1579-1585 By Professor ADAM SZELAGOWSKI and N. S. B. GRAS, Ph.D. (Harvard). Read December 21, 1911 VERY little is known about the early history of English mercantile venture into the far Eastland. Although some ambitious traders from this island steered their course through the Sound in the fourteenth century, or earlier, and in the fifteenth century seem to have aspired to some degree of common action, it remains true that, previous to the foundation of the Eastland Company in 1579, there was no important body of English merchants organised to trade in the Baltic. It is intended here to focus attention upon the early struggles of this company in Prussia, and particularly in the town of Elbing, where was carried on a contest similar to that maintained in the West by the Merchant Adventurers. Elbing, situated at the mouth of the Vistula, was, in the second half of the sixteenth century, but a shadow of its former greatness, and its citizens recalled with regret the time when their trade had equalled that of Dantzic. Elbing, like Bruges a century earlier, saw itself threatened by a change in the channel of the river--a change which had already spelt partial decay and might mean total ruin. But, enemy though Nature seemed, she was not more patently adverse to the fortunes of Elbing than the neighbouring Dantzic. In this unequal contest with an overshadowing rival, Elbing saw in the king of Poland an ally as willing as able; for the Polish crown had found the proud and arbitrary republic of Dantzic traders little M2 This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Mon, 27 Jun 2016 07:37:36 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 164 TRANSACTIONS OF THE ROYAL HISTORICAL SOCIETY inclined to serve its ends or to bow to its will. As an earnest of support, both Sigismund Augustus and Stephen Bathory published edicts, by which they sought to raise Elbing from a state of decay. The latter, shortly after his election, went so far as to invite foreign merchants to choose their homes and set up their warehouses in Elbing.' When, therefore, at a later date, during its quarrel with Dantzic, Elbing maintained that the idea of the establish- ment of the English company within its walls really emanated from the Polish king, there was much force in the contention. During the rebellion of Dantzic in 1577, Stephen Bathory ordered his secretary, Peter Kloczewski, to take the measure- ment of the gulf of Svieza. The king's project was, if possible, to restore the port of Elbing.2 But the citizens of Dantzic, seeing in this a supreme danger, conceived the idea of preventing it for ever by blocking up the entrance to the gulf. They held their hand only through the fear that such a step would injure Kd*nigsberg, and decided that it would be safer to destroy the entrance of the little Elbing river. This attempt of Dantzic on Elbing cost the Elbingers more than sixty ships and about Ioo,ooo florins.s Elbing was to be more successful in another direction. As early as the latter half of 1578, and in the first months of 1579, it began to negotiate with English merchants with a view to their settlement within its borders. And at about this time, the magistrates of Dantzic complained that Elbing took the liberty of granting freedom of trade to foreign merchants, which in its eyes was not only a detriment to Elbingers themselves, and contrary to Prussian rights, but quite contrary to the rules and the spirit of the Hanseatic Union.4 But no matter what the ostensible motives were there can be no doubt that the 'Pearl of Poland' kept W. Behring, Beitrdge zur Geschichte Elbings (1900oo), 4. 2 Behring, 6. 3 Behring, Ix. 4 Royal Archives, Dantzic: A cta Hanseatica, zo8, This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Mon, 27 Jun 2016 07:37:36 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms THE EASTLAND COMPANY IN PRUSSIA 165 always in mind the undoubted loss which would ensue from the establishment of an English staple in a near-by town. For up to this time, English merchants trading in the Baltic had made Dantzic their headquarters, though, so far as is known, they had not organised as a trading company. Elbing, then, in bidding for the English trade, was threatening the coffers of Dantzic and the purses of its citizens. It is an interesting coincidence that at this very time, the ten years period 1 of settlement of the Merchant Adven- turers at Hamburg was elapsing. Hamburg had been the first Hanseatic town to withdraw from the general practice of excluding foreign merchants from the greater part of local trade. There was then a natural fear in the minds of the magistrates of Dantzic that Elbing, like Hamburg, being governed by the calculation of its own interests, would follow this example and admit the English merchants who were clamouring for a foothold in the Baltic. The line of cleavage between the rival towns was deeper now than even before. Dantzic could reckon on the support of a large part of the Hanse against the English-- the common foe of the league. Elbing turned instinctively to Poland and hoisted the banner of national rights, which gave to the Prussian towns, as well as to the nobility, the freedom of concluding commercial treaties with other maritime nations, subject to the consent of the king and the estates of the realm. True to its international, and even anti-national, position, Dantzic took the obvious course of enlisting foreign allies. Denmark had been her friend, and to Denmark Dantzic now turned. Mathias M611er was sent to point out the losses and injuries which would inevitably ensue to the Baltic towns, if English monopolists, as they were called, were suffered to gain a footing in Elbing. Frederic II of Denmark, however, was too prudent to pick a quarrel with 1 1567-77; actually terminating in 1578. This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Mon, 27 Jun 2016 07:37:36 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms i66 TRANSACTIONS OF THE ROYAL HISTORICAL SOCIETY England and Poland at one and the same time. So his answer was a curt refusal. As yet, he saw no signs that the commercial enterprises of the English would damage, in any way, either himself or his subjects. If in the future he should see that his tolls were injured, then he would take the necessary steps to protect his interests. Besides, it might be expected that the attempt of the English merchants to find a staple in the Baltic would, as heretofore, end in failure. While in this frame of mind, Frederic could not be induced even to send a letter to Queen Elizabeth on the subject.1 It was in November of the year 1579, about three months after the grant of a charter by Elizabeth, that the following English merchants arrived in Elbing: George Rucks, Robert Walton, Matthew Gray, Thomas Gorney, and John Bricks. They lost no time in declaring to the magis- tracy of Elbing, in the name of the newly chartered company, that with the assurances of the goodwill of the town, they would bring in their wares.2 They were at once welcomed to Elbing; and, practically, from this time dates the staple of the Eastland Company at Elbing, though some time was to elapse before final terms were reached between the company and the Elbingers, and before the king gave his sanction to the pact. A working agreement seems soon to have been reached. The English stipulated that they should be guaranteed freedom of trade and navigation, and exemption from new tolls, and they reserved to them- selves the right of withdrawing from the town in case of oppressive measures injurious to their liberty or their trade. To all these conditions Elbing agreed, with the reservation of the dues at the mouth of the river, which it shared conjointly with Kdnigsberg.3 In focusing attention upon the actual events taking place at Elbing, we should not forget the larger arena of I Hanseatica, lo8. 2 Cf. Record Office, State Papers, Foreign, Poland, i. 4. " Kiln. Inv., ii. p. 617. This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Mon, 27 Jun 2016 07:37:36 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms THE EASTLAND COMPANY IN PRUSSIA 167 struggle, for this was a contest in which a great part of western Europe was to be involved, and in which at this time there were two storm-centres other than Elbing- England itself and Hamburg.
Recommended publications
  • Investment in the East India Company
    The University of Manchester Research The Global Interests of London's Commercial Community, 1599-1625: investment in the East India Company DOI: 10.1111/ehr.12665 Document Version Accepted author manuscript Link to publication record in Manchester Research Explorer Citation for published version (APA): Smith, E. (2018). The Global Interests of London's Commercial Community, 1599-1625: investment in the East India Company. The Economic History Review, 71(4), 1118-1146. https://doi.org/10.1111/ehr.12665 Published in: The Economic History Review Citing this paper Please note that where the full-text provided on Manchester Research Explorer is the Author Accepted Manuscript or Proof version this may differ from the final Published version. If citing, it is advised that you check and use the publisher's definitive version. General rights Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the Research Explorer are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. Takedown policy If you believe that this document breaches copyright please refer to the University of Manchester’s Takedown Procedures [http://man.ac.uk/04Y6Bo] or contact [email protected] providing relevant details, so we can investigate your claim. Download date:05. Oct. 2021 The global interests of London’s commercial community, 1599-1625: investment in the East India Company The English East India Company (EIC) has long been identified as an organisation that foreshadowed developments in finance, investment and overseas expansion that would come to fruition over the course of the following two centuries.
    [Show full text]
  • Institutional Innovations, Theories of the Firm, and the Formation of the East India Company
    UC Berkeley Berkeley Program in Law and Economics, Working Paper Series Title Institutional Innovations, Theories of the Firm, and the Formation of the East India Company Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/2216c263 Author Harris, Ron Publication Date 2004-02-01 eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California Institutional Innovations, Theories of the Firm and the Formation of the East India Company Ron Harris* Preliminary Draft - February 2004 Please do not quote or cite without the permission of the author * Professor of Law and Legal History, School of Law, Tel Aviv University, Visiting Professor Boalt Hall School of Law, UC Berkeley ([email protected] [email protected]) The English East India Company [EIC] is considered to be the first significant publicly-held joint-stock corporation in England, in Europe, and, in fact, in the world. Some would say that it was the first multi-divisional or multinational corporation in history. It was the largest merchant corporation in the world throughout much of its 250+ years of existence. It had a monopoly over England’s trade with Asia, played a significant role in financing the British State, and eventually became the ruler of the Indian sub- continent. The EIC was chartered on a symbolic date: December 31st 1600. It predated by almost a century the formation of an effective market in stocks in Britain which began to pick up as a market place for government bonds after the Glorious Revolution of 1688 and only became an active market in corporate shares in the 18th century.
    [Show full text]
  • Enterprising Empires Matthew P. Romaniello Index More Information
    Cambridge University Press 978-1-108-49757-2 — Enterprising Empires Matthew P. Romaniello Index More Information Index Abbas II, Shah of Iran, 30–1 Appelbaum, Richard, 8 Academy of Sciences, 101, 220, 222–3, Apraksin, Stepan Fedorovich, 161, 164 226–7 Arapov, Semen, 131, 150, 156 Act of Union, 96. See also Great Britain Arkhangel’sk, 3, 7, 22, 25–7, 31, 33–4, Acts of Navigation, 13, 40–3, 45, 47, 49, 38–9, 41–2, 49, 58, 65, 72, 78, 80, 58, 60, 71, 82, 88, 93, 108, 120, 86–7, 90–1, 93, 95, 145, 178, 184–6, 132–3, 135, 137, 175, 179, 197, 260. 191, 205, 219, 221, 232, 240–1, 249 See also Navigation Act of 1651, 1660, Armed Neutrality, 12, 201–2, 204–5, and 1663; regulations 207–9, 230. See also American Adams, John Quincy, 241 Revolution Admiralty (Britain), 237–8. See also navy Armenian Company, 62, 87, 131, 133. Admiralty (Russia), 129, 225. See also navy See also Armenians Afinogenov, Gregory, 229 Armenians, 62, 95, 98, 106, 119, 130, 133, Agryzhans, 151 135–40, 144, 147, 149, 151, 173, 177, alcohol, 87, 97–8, 215, 218, 244, 252. 183, 189, 232. See also Armenian See also taverns, wine Company, Persian Company Aleksei Mikhailovich, Tsar of Russia, 29, asbestos, 100 31, 38, 42–3, 46 Aster, John Jacob, 252 Aleutian Islands, 188, 224–7, 255. See also Astrabad, 121 Kodiak, Sitka, Unalaska islands Astrakhan, 23, 30, 33–5, 63, 76, 82, 99, Algarotti, Francesco, 158–9 119, 132, 136–7, 145, 152, 154, 158, Alta California, 9, 212–13, 236–7, 243–4, 177, 183–4, 198, 200, 232, 257.
    [Show full text]
  • The Emergence of the Joint-Stock Companies in the Dutch Republic and Their Democratic Elements in Business
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The emergence of the joint-stock companies in the Dutch Republic and their democratic elements in business Economou, Emmanouel/Marios/Lazaros and Kyriazis, Nicholas University of Thessaly, Department of Economics, University of Thessaly, Department of Economics 10 January 2019 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/91447/ MPRA Paper No. 91447, posted 17 Jan 2019 09:55 UTC The emergence of the joint-stock companies in the Dutch Republic and their democratic elements in business1 Emmanouil-Marios L. Economou1 and Nicholas Kyriazis2 1,2 Department of Economics, University of Thessaly, 28 October 78, PC: 38333, Volos Thessaly Greece Abstract In the present essay we analyse the emergence of joint-stock companies during the 16th and 17th centuries in business (the Dutch partenrederij), and the VOC East India Companies). We suggest that in the Dutch Republic (DR) characterised by relative weak central authority, market solutions were found to solve organisation problems and these solutions, the first joint-stock companies, are efficient but also democratic in their structure. The DR demonstrate that democratic elements emerge in parallel in the economy (sometimes even preceding) and in the political field, which can be mutually reinforcing. Keywords: Joint-stock companies, Dutch Republic, Democratic elements in business 1. Introduction There is a substantial and growing literature on the emergence of joint–stock companies (Lawson 1993; Leeson 2009; Robins 2012; Roy 2012; Vlami 2015; Kyriazis, Metaxas and Economou 2018 etc.) their operations and a discussion of specific aspects, as for example, the principal-agent problem (Carlos, 1992; Carlos and Stephen, 1996) or their influence on history, such as the expansion of European states in Asia and their transformation into empires (Rodger 1997, 2004; Gaastra 2003; Krishna 2014).
    [Show full text]
  • GIPE-085247-Contents.Pdf
    Dhananjayarao Gadgil Library 111111111111111111111111111111111111 liD GIPE-PUNE-08S247 _ _ -(>"'8F'.,..: • . SERVANTs OF iNOI.\.:$QCIEn'S LIBRARY, . ~ .. ~:': ·fdoN~·. .. Cl. N 0.1(~;:; • 5. t'4: . Date ofrelease for loan Ac. No. ~ls.2.41 . .GtS;JS.~ SEP1S0j This book should be returned OD or bdore the date last meDtio~ed below • • Failure to comply will involvB cancellation 'oj the Bom)wer's Card andjor/eiture oj deposit • . ~~------------------------~ . 21l ~197r 'J AVtiI9J~1 (f -AUG.t979 l3 S'EP1~19 ,,2JAN \9~~ . 2 7 AUG l~ bl \ 9 - t,.-8.3 (Ill I&'1) -~, AUG t~9 ..: B. P.P.] * MERQAN'l'ILISM MERCANTILISM by ELI F. HECKSCHER Authorized Translation by MENDEL SHAPIRO Revised. Edition Edited b..., E. F. SODERLUND VOLUME TWO LONDON: GEORGE ALLEN & UNWIN LTD NEW YORK: THE MACMILLAN COMPANY First publish.d in Sw.dish in 1931 "The"English /ranslation, pr.par.dfrom the GmtI4n .dition and revised by the author, published in 1935 Revised lind Edition 1955 This book is copyright under th. Berne Convention. Apart from any fair dealing for lhe purposes of prWa" study, research, criticism or review, as per­ mit"d under the Copyright Act 1911, no portion may be reproduced by any process without writUn per­ mission. E"'luiry should b. made 10 the publisher. © George Allm and Unwin Ltd.• 1935 X5.5·M GS. J J5·!J- ca 5247 PRINTED IN GREAT BRITAIN BY BRADFORD AND DICKENS LONDON W.C.I CONTENTS VOLUME II PART II Mercantilism as a System oj Power ."GB I: THE ESSENCE OF THE SYSTEM OF POWER Nationalism and the interests ofthe state 13~-The state as an end in itself 16.-8tatic conception 23.-Eclectic point of view 29.
    [Show full text]
  • From Stockholm to St. Petersburg
    From Stockholm to St. Petersburg Commercial Factors in the Political Relations between England and Sweden 1675-1700 By Sven-Erik Åström Helsinki 1962 STUD IA HISTORICA Published by The Finnish Historical Society Suomen Historiallinen Seura — Finska Historiska Samfundet vol. 2 SVEN-ERIK ÅSTRÖM From Stockholm to St. Petersburg Commercial Factors in the Political Relations between England and Sweden 1675-1700 o TURUN SANOMALEHTI JA KIRJAPAINO OSAKEYHTIÖ TURKU 19(12 The dating of letters and documents is that of the originals. This means that Swedish documents are dated Old Style, whereas the English ones are usually dated according to both Old and New Styles. Where only one style is used this can be assumed to be the Old Style, which in the seventeenth cen- tury was for both England and Sweden ten days behind that of the New Style used on the Continent. One exception to the con- temporary dating has been adopted. In Eng- land the year began officially on Lady Day, March 25, though in many cases Englishmen, particularly when writing from abroad or to someone abroad, indicated the year between Jan. 1 and March 25 by double dating. For the sake of clarity I have always taken the year to begin on Jan. l. • Preface Northern Europe provides us with a sector of English foreign policy during the 17th and 18th centuries in which elements of power politics and commer- cial policy came together in an interesting way. Interests of trade and power were closely entwined in the political relations between England and the Nordic Kingdoms. The commercial element in England's Baltic policy during these critical years, especially at the beginning of the 18th century, has already been strongly emphasised by historians.1 So far, however, research has principally been concerned with connections between England and Russia and their economic aspects.
    [Show full text]
  • Re-Evaluating the Role of Voluntary Organisations: Merchant Networks, the Baltic, and the Expansion of European
    Working Papers No. 138/10 Re-evaluating the Role of Voluntary Organisations: Merchant Networks, the Baltic and the Expansion of European Long-Distance Trade . Esther Sahle © Esther Sahle April 2010 Department of Economic History London School of Economics Houghton Street London, WC2A 2AE Tel: +44 (0) 20 7955 7860 Fax: +44 (0) 20 7955 7730 Re-evaluating the Role of Voluntary Organisations: Merchant Networks, the Baltic and the Expansion of European Long-Distance Trade Esther Sahle Abstract Based on a letter book of the London Baltic merchant Michael Mitford dating 1703-1707 this paper argues that the ability of merchant networks to secure property rights in long distance trade must be re-evaluated. Contrary to the argument of the New Institutional Economists, these were not inferior to the nation state in facilitating the expansion of trade and thereby Smithean growth. It is shown that Mitford's network did not limit membership by non-economic criteria but adapted to the needs of trade. It efficiently solved the free-rider problem through a reputation mechanism. As social ties developed parallel to business ties, the shadow of the future was furthermore supported by the threat of ostracism from the community and helped maintain agents' honesty. Members shared a common set of values, including reciprocity, which played an important role in their conduct of business. The network's attempts at expansion were, however, of limited success. This is related to mercantilist policies and ongoing warfare in the region, not to the network's lacking ability. Furthermore it is shown that the network provided the members with contacts and business opportunities and thereby supported their business activities more than political institutions did.
    [Show full text]
  • The Organization of Long-Distance Trade in England and the Dutch Republic, 1550–16501
    Chapter 9 The Organization of Long-Distance Trade in England and the Dutch Republic, 1550–16501 Oscar Gelderblom Introduction Early modern states benefited from long-distance trade in a variety of ways. First, commerce was a major source of income, either directly through the levying of monopoly fees or customs, or indirectly through excises on consumer goods or impositions on the income and wealth of merchants.2 Second, the mercantile community was a principal source of credit for early modern states. Europe’s rulers borrowed from their own subjects, but also relied on foreign financiers to which the success of international money markets in Antwerp, Genoa, or Amsterdam clearly attests.3 Third, merchants were instruments of state policy. Privateers, suppliers of ships, weapons and ammunition, and the great colonial companies were major players in the inter-state rivalries that divided Europe.4 Finally, foolishly or not, early modern rulers attached great value to the role of trade in supplementing the state’s stock of gold and silver.5 1 The author is grateful to Bas van Bavel, Maartje van Gelder, Pierre Jeannin†, Sheilagh Ogilvie, and participants in the economic history seminar of the University Carlos III for helpful comments and suggestions. 2 Richard Bonney, ‘Revenues’, in Richard Bonney (ed.), Economic Systems and State Finance, (Oxford, 1995). 3 On Antwerp: Herman Van der Wee, The Growth of the Antwerp Market and the European Economy (14th–16th Centuries), 3 vols (Leuven, 1963), vol. 2, pp. 199–207; 220–22; On Genoa: Jacques Heers, Gênes au XVe Siècle. Activité Économique et Problèmes Sociaux (Paris, 1961), pp.
    [Show full text]
  • The Function of "Dysfunctional" Boards
    University of the Pacific Scholarly Commons McGeorge School of Law Scholarly Articles McGeorge School of Law Faculty Scholarship 2008 The uncF tion of "Dysfunctional" Boards Franklin A. Gevurtz Pacific cGeM orge School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarlycommons.pacific.edu/facultyarticles Part of the Business Organizations Law Commons Recommended Citation Franklin A. Gevurtz, The unctF ion of "Dysfunctional" Boards, 77 U. Cin. L. Rev. 391 (2008). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the McGeorge School of Law Faculty Scholarship at Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in McGeorge School of Law Scholarly Articles by an authorized administrator of Scholarly Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE FUNCTION OF "DYSFUNCTIONAL" BOARDS Franklin A. Gevurtz* l. INTRODUCTION For many years , there was a scholar-in-residence on the Pacific McGeorge faculty named Abbott Goldberg. Abbot told me about a classmate of his at Harvard Law School, Louis Henkin, who ultimately became a University Professor (with the right to teach in any department) at Columbia University. Recognizing Henkin's utter brilliance , even as first year law student, Abbott asked Henkin what his approach was to studying law. Henkin answered that he outlined the substance of his courses. When Abbott seemed unimpressed, Henkin continued, "And then I outline the outlines." After Abbott asked what the next step was, Henkin explained, "And then I outline the outline of the outlines. " Abbott then said, "Don 't tell me, you then outline the outline of the outline of the outlines?" to which Henkin replied, "Now you got it".
    [Show full text]
  • Growth of Joint Stock Companies in the Seventeenth Century
    San Jose State University SJSU ScholarWorks Master's Theses Master's Theses and Graduate Research 2008 Growth of joint stock companies in the seventeenth century Tu Kha Tran San Jose State University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.sjsu.edu/etd_theses Recommended Citation Tran, Tu Kha, "Growth of joint stock companies in the seventeenth century" (2008). Master's Theses. 3511. DOI: https://doi.org/10.31979/etd.y7t2-rc58 https://scholarworks.sjsu.edu/etd_theses/3511 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Master's Theses and Graduate Research at SJSU ScholarWorks. It has been accepted for inclusion in Master's Theses by an authorized administrator of SJSU ScholarWorks. For more information, please contact [email protected]. GROWTH OF JOINT STOCK COMPANIES IN THE SEVENTEENTH CENTURY A Thesis Presented to The Faculty of the Department of Economics San Jose State University In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Master of Arts by Tu Kha Tran August 2008 UMI Number: 1459691 INFORMATION TO USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations and photographs, print bleed-through, substandard margins, and improper alignment can adversely affect reproduction. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. ® UMI UMI Microform 1459691 Copyright 2008 by ProQuest LLC. All rights reserved. This microform edition is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code.
    [Show full text]
  • British Diplomats in the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth (1580–1700)
    APPENDIX XII BRITISH DIPLOMATS IN THE POLIsh-LITHUANIAN COMMONWEALTH (1580–1700) Name Nationality Note Source Rogers, Dr John English or Envoy to Poland-Lithuania for the Bell, A Handlist, 153, (c.1538–1603) Scot Eastland Company. Acted also as a 213; Biegańska, “The special ambassador (from 6/8/1580 Learned Scots,” 26 to 1581) and spy until 1610. (calls him James); SSNE no. 3419. Herbert, John English Acted as an ambassador to Bell, A Handlist, (later Sir John;c.1540–1617) Denmark, Prussia, Poland and the 153, 213; SSNE no. 1410. Hanse towns (from 16/5/1583 to 1/9/1585). Harborne, William English In 1588 Harborne had an audience Bell, A Handlist, (1522–1617) with the Grand Chancellor of 154, 214; SSNE no. 1455. Poland. He visited Elbląg and Gdańsk. Parkins, Dr Christopher English Acted as a special ambassador. On Bell, A Handlist, 154, (later Sir Christopher; his journey to Denmark in 1590, 214; SSNE no. 1414. c.1543–1622) Parkins visited Poland, Prussia and the Hanse towns (from 9/5/1590 to c.26/7/1591 and again from 29/12/1594 to c.7/1595). Carew, George English Acted as a special ambassador to Bell, A Handlist, 155, (later Sir George; d. 1612) Sweden, Denmark and Poland (from 214; ODNB no. 4627; 20/5/1598 to 21/12/1598). He visited SSNE no. 1257. Gdańsk and Elbląg. Lyall, Henry (Lyel) Scot or The first Stuart-British Special Bell, A Handlist, 214; (fl. 1600–1610) English Ambassador to Poland (from SSNE no. 2404. 2/4/1603 to 8/8/1603).
    [Show full text]
  • Final Version
    World cities before globalisation The European city network, A.D. 1300-1600 by Raf Verbruggen Submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the award of Doctoral thesis of Loughborough University 3 June 2011 © by Raf Verbruggen 2011 The European city network, A.D. 1300-1600 Abstract This dissertation is a quantitative study of the spatial business strategies of 130 late medieval and 16 th -century European commercial and banking firms, the business networks of which have been put together for a structural analysis of the European city network between ca. 1300 and ca. 1600. Concretely this investigation has been carried out through the application of an interlocking network model – specifically developed for the study of the present-day global city network produced by the office networks of business service firms – to this historical case study, in order to challenge predominantly hierarchical conceptualisations of city networks which are often influenced by central place theory. After a methodological section, in which solutions are designed for reconciling the geographical model with the particularities of historical research, a first part of the analysis focuses on agency within the network, identifying and reconstructing the multiple spatial strategies used by the different agents. In a second part the overall structure and dynamics in the network are investigated, revealing the operation of Christaller’s traffic principle, as well as a cyclical variation in emphasis on continental and maritime nodes within the European city network. More generally, this study demonstrates that the functioning of dynamic transnational networks based upon complementarity and cooperation rather than competition is not limited to our contemporary globalised world, but can also be found in particular historical societies.
    [Show full text]