Northern Lights: Political Economy and the Terroir of the Norwegian Enlightenment*

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Northern Lights: Political Economy and the Terroir of the Norwegian Enlightenment* Northern Lights: Political Economy and the Terroir of the Norwegian Enlightenment* Sophus A. Reinert Harvard Business School On May 27, 1776, the Scottish immigrant John Robertson Brand, sometimes known as John Brandt, was awarded a silver medal by the Royal Norwegian Sci- entific Society in the church of the fishing village of Hustad, south of the Trond- heim Fjord in central Norway. Though below the Arctic Circle, Hustad lies slightly off the sixty-third parallel north, which runs through Canada’s Nunavut and Yukon Territories, the Davis Strait, and the deep Russian tundra—a decidedly hyperbo- rean region compared to the traditional latitudes of Enlightenment. And yet, step- ping into the small wooden church’s aisle on that spring day to deliver a speech marking the occasion, District Governor Even Hammer of Romsdal (1732–1800; fig. 1) summoned a language of reform, improvement, industriousness, civic vir- tue, public happiness, jealousy of trade, and political economy that would have resonated deeply and widely across the European world, a language indebted to international currents but resolutely inflected by local conditions in what he ap- propriately called “our cold North.”1 Few cases better justify the great Turinese * Rolv Petter Amdam first introduced me to Even Hammer, and I would like to ex- press my gratitude to him; to Mads Langnes at Romsdalsmuseet in Molde, Norway, for going well beyond the call of duty in facilitating my work on this intriguing figure; and, particularly, to Marit Sjelmo for jovial research assistance and to John Brewer, Rob- ert Fredona, Steven L. Kaplan, Erik S. Reinert, Hugo Reinert, John Robertson, John Shovlin, Andre Wakefield, Carl Wennerlind, and Sophie Wilkowske for suggestions. I am furthermore grateful to Ann Thomson and Richard Whatmore for the kind invitation to present on Hammer at the European University Institute in Florence, and to Alexandra Chadwick, Rory Cox, Franz Leander Fillafer, Konrad M. Lawson, and Koen Stapelbroek for comments there. Finally, I would like to thank the journal’s three incisive reviewers for their feedback, and Isabelle Lewis for preparing the map. This article develops my earlier “Even Hammer: Politisk økonomi i den norske opplysningstiden,” in Årbok 2017: Opplysningstida i Romsdal 1700–1814 (Molde, 2017), 9–39. 1 Even Hammer, Vinskibeligheds høye Fornødenhed og ærefulde Løn . (Copenha- gen, 1776), 12. The pamphlet is exceedingly rare, but I have consulted the copy classified R.Ark.1264/H/L0003 in Romsdalsmuseet, Molde, Norway. For a review, see Kritisk Tilskuer over Indenlansk og Udenlandsk Literatur, nos. 47–48 (1776), 369–71. On “the North Sea and Baltic region” as a “northern, colder and poorer reflection of Braudel’s Mediterranean,” as well as illuminating caveats, see Hanno Brand and Leos Müller, “In- troduction,” in The Dynamics of Economic Culture in the North Sea and Baltic Region in The Journal of Modern History 92 (March 2020): 76–115 © 2020 by The University of Chicago. 0022-2801/2020/9201-0003$10.00 All rights reserved. Political Economy and the Norwegian Enlightenment 77 Fig. 1.—Anonymous portrait of Even Hammer. Domkirkeodden Photoarchive, Hamar, Norway. Color version available as an online enhancement. the Late Medieval and Early Modern Period, ed. Brand and Müller (Hilversum, 2007), 7– 12, 7, as well as the volume’s essays. The reference is of course to Fernand Braudel, The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip II, 2 vols., trans. Siân Reynolds (Berkeley, 1996). 78 Reinert historian Franco Venturi’s admonition, a few days before his death, to “the young and the less young” to remember “always that local roots and the great ideas that break the skies of Europe can never be separated.”2 So how were the two—local roots and great ideas—related in the case of Dis- trict Governor Hammer, and what might it tell us about the larger questions of the Enlightenment? What cursory scholarship about him that exists, including even the Norwegian Biographical Dictionary, argues doggedly but with little evidence that “French Physiocracy” was the “starting point” for his work and that he was essentially a boreal recipient of François Quesnay’s doctrines ex- pounding laissez-faire, large-scale capitalist landowning, and the exclusive power of agriculture to create wealth.3 Hammer may have been a figure of the Enlighten- ment, in short, but hardly more than a dim reflection at the utmost periphery of the movement. Only Rolv Petter Amdam has suggested that scholars may have exag- gerated the influenceofphysiocracyinNorwayingeneralandonHammerinpar- ticular. This article builds on his observation to provide a more nuanced portrayal of Hammer’s world and of his vision as a means of integrating Norway’s expe- rience into our understanding of the emergence and internationalization of polit- ical economy in the eighteenth century—what Steven L. Kaplan and I have called “the Economic Turn”—and, more broadly, into the European Enlightenment.4 For 2 FrancoVenturi, quoted inLeonardoCasalino,“Notaintroduttiva ebiografica,”in Franco Venturi, La lotta per la libertà: Scritti politici, ed. Leonardo Casalino (Turin, 1996), liii–lxv, lxv. On Venturi see, among others, Adriano Viarengo, Franco Venturi, politica e storia nel novecento (Rome, 2014). On his vision of the Enlightenment, see John Robertson, “Franco Venturi’sEnlightenment,” Past & Present 137, no. 1 (1992): 183–206. 3 ArneApelseth,“EvenHammer,”February13,2009,https://nbl.snl.no/Even_Hammer; Asbjørn Øverås, “Upplysningstida i Romsdal: Amtmann Even Hammer,” Syn og Segn 41 (1935): 274–84, and Øverås, Romsdals Soga, vol. 2, Dansketida (Trondheim, 1941), 283–301; Arne Odd Johnsen, “En amtmann fra oplysningstiden: Etatsråd Even Hammer; fremskrittsmannen og patrioten,” Heimen 5, no. 4 (1939): 177–96, 178; Sven Erik Skarsbø and Jógvan Hammer, “Knut Ellingsgaard—tresfjordingen som vart plogkar på Færøyane,” Romsdal Sogelag Årsskrift [Molde] 72 (2008): 274–96, 281–82. On the physiocratic experiment, see Steven L. Kaplan, Bread, Politics, and Political Economy in the Reign of Louis XV, 2nd ed. (London, 2015), and, for the most recent literature, Kap- lan, The Stakes of Regulation: Reflections on Bread, Politics and Political Economy Forty Years Later (London, 2015). On the international influence of physiocracy, see Bernard Delmas, Thierry Demals, and Philippe Steiner, eds., La diffusion internationale de la phys- iocratie (XVIIIe–XIXe) (Grenoble, 1995). On the numerous alternatives to physiocracy at the time, and indeed the prevalence of explicit “Antiphysiocracy,” see the essays in Gérard Klotz, Philippe Minard, and Arnaud Orain, eds., Les voies de la richesse? La physiocratie en question (1760–1850) (Rennes, 2017), and Steven L. Kaplan and Sophus A. Reinert, eds., The Economic Turn: Recasting Political Economy in Enlightenment Europe (London, 2019). 4 Rolv Petter Amdam, “Norske fysiokratar—fanst dei?,” in Det som svarte seg best: Studier i økonomisk historie og politikk, ed. Edgar Hovland, Even Lange, and Sigurd Political Economy and the Norwegian Enlightenment 79 not only does a closer reading of Hammer’s work reveal a far more complex eco- nomic vision than has hitherto been acknowledged, one indebted to cameralism rather than physiocracy; it can also serve as a beachhead from which we may better assess the Norwegian Enlightenment as such, which remains a woefully ne- glected yet fertile field for further studies, and ultimately—and perhaps more signif- icantly—the nature of political economy when it was first codified in eighteenth- century Europe.5 Indeed, the case of Even Hammer’s political economy and how it developed at the northern extreme of the European Enlightenment suggests that intellectual historians would benefit from considering the ideation, reception, appropriation, and development of ideas in relation to not merely shifting cultural, economic, and political contexts but also more fundamental environmental and geological conditions, that is, to their physical ecologies. Though an intellectual portrait of Hammer is interesting for what it teaches us about the varieties of political econ- omy in the European Enlightenment, it more fundamentally—and broadly— challenges us to take the terroir of intellectual history more seriously: that is, Rysstad (Oslo, 1990), 19–30, 20 and 26. On physiocracy’s more complex reception in Sweden, see Lars Herlitz, Fysiokratismen i svensk tappning 1767–1770 (Gothen- burg [but Lund], 1974), and, more broadly, Carl Wennerlind, “Theatrum Oeconomicum: Anders Berch and the Dramatization of the Swedish Improvement Discourse,” in New Perspectives on the History of Political Economy, ed. Robert Fredona and Sophus A. Reinert (Basingstoke, 2018), 103–30, and Lars Magnusson, “Physiocracy in Sweden: A Note on the Problem of Inventing Traditions,” in Kaplan and Reinert, The Economic Turn, 585–605. On “the Enlightenment” as essentially a matter of “political economy,” see also John Robertson, The Case for the Enlightenment: Scotland and Naples, 1680– 1760 (Cambridge, 2005); Sophus A. Reinert, Translating Empire: Emulation and the Origins of Political Economy (Cambridge, MA, 2011), and Reinert, The Academy of Fist- icuffs: Political Economy and Commercial Society in Enlightenment Italy (Cambridge, MA, 2018). 5 Axiomatically, Norway was excluded even from Roy S. Porter and Mikuláš Teich, eds., The Enlightenment in National Context (Cambridge, 1981), long the Bible of those interested in the national varieties of Enlightenment. For a comparative sketch of the Scandinavian Enlightenment,
Recommended publications
  • New Working Papers Series, Entitled “Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics”
    Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 74 the other canon foundation, Norway Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn Ragnar Nurkse Department of Innovation and Governance CONTACT: Rainer Kattel, [email protected]; Wolfgang Drechsler, [email protected]; Erik S. Reinert, [email protected] 80 Economic Bestsellers before 1850: A Fresh Look at the History of Economic Thought Erik S. Reinert, Kenneth Carpenter, Fernanda A. Reinert, Sophus A. Reinert* MAY 2017 * E. Reinert, Tallinn University of Technology & The Other Canon Foundation, Norway; K. Car- penter, former librarian, Harvard University; F. Reinert, The Other Canon Foundation, Norway; S. Reinert, Harvard Business School. The authors are grateful to Dr. Debra Wallace, Managing Director, Baker Library Services and, Laura Linard, Director of Baker Library Special Collections, at Harvard Business School, where the Historical Collection now houses what was once the Kress Library, for their cooperation in this venture. Above all our thanks go to Olga Mikheeva at Tallinn University of Technology for her very efficient research assistance. Antiquarian book dealers often have more information on economics books than do academics, and our thanks go to Wilhelm Hohmann in Stuttgart, Robert H. Rubin in Brookline MA, Elvira Tasbach in Berlin, and, above all, to Ian Smith in London. We are also grateful for advice from Richard van den Berg, Francesco Boldizzoni, Patrick O’Brien, Alexandre Mendes Cunha, Bertram Schefold and Arild Sæther. Corresponding author [email protected] The core and backbone of this publication consists of the meticulous work of Kenneth Carpenter, librarian of the Kress Library at Harvard Busi- ness School starting in 1968 and later Assistant Director for Research Resources in the Harvard University Library and the Harvard College 1 Library.
    [Show full text]
  • Cameralism in Practice: State Administration and Economy in Early
    BOOK REVIEW: CAMERALISM IN PRACTICE: STATE ADMINISTRATION AND ECONOMY IN EARLY MODERN EUROPE BY MARTEN SEPPEL AND KEITH TRIBE REVIEWED BY CARLOS EDUARDO SUPRINYAK* *CEDEPLAR, Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais, Belo Horizonte, Brazil. Contact: [email protected] This “preprint” is the accepted typescript of a book review that is forthcoming in revised form, after minor editorial changes, in the Journal of the History of Economic Thought (ISSN: 1053-8372), issue TBA. Copyright to the journal’s articles is held by the History of Economics Society (HES), whose exclusive licensee and publisher for the journal is Cambridge University Press (https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/journal-of-the- history-of-economic-thought). This preprint may be used only for private research and study and is not to be distributed further. The preprint may be cited as follows: Suprinyak, Carlos Eduardo. Review of “Cameralism in Practice: State Administration and Economy in Early Modern Europe” by Marten Seppel and Keith Tribe. Journal of the History of Economic Thought (forthcoming). Preprint at SocArXiv, osf.io/preprints/socarxiv Book Review SEPPEL, Marten & TRIBE, Keith (2017). Cameralism in Practice: state administration and economy in Early Modern Europe, Woodbridge/Rochester: The Boydell Press. By Carlos Eduardo Suprinyak, Cedeplar/UFMG A quick internet search returns the following definition of cameralism, provided by Oxford Living Dictionaries: “an economic theory prevalent in 18th-century Germany, which advocated a strong public administration managing a centralized economy primarily for the benefit of the state”. In the collection of essays Cameralism in Practice, editors Marten Seppel and Keith Tribe seem bent on deconstructing every single element of this definition.
    [Show full text]
  • Le Pour Et Le Contre. Galiani, La Diplomatie Et Le Commerce Des Blés
    Le pour et le contre. Galiani, la diplomatie et le commerce des blés « Il y a quelque subalterne à Naples qui méritent d’être observé, entre autres l’abbé Galiani, qui aspire à jouer un rôle et croit se faire un mérite en s’opposant de tout son petit pouvoir à ce qui intéresse la France. »1 La plupart des études sur l’abbé Galiani, et particulièrement sur ses Dialogues sur le commerce des blés et sa période parisienne, oscillent entre trois grands pôles : l’histoire littéraire2, l’histoire de la pensée économique3; et l’histoire culturelle des Lumières et des sociabilités4. Ces études fondamentales ont ainsi éclairé les liens intellectuels de Galiani avec les écrivains et philosophes (en particulier Diderot et Grimm), le contenu théorique de sa pensée économique, et son inscription dans les cercles mondains de la capitale française. Cependant, une dimension d’importance semble négligée : l’activité diplomatique de l’abbé, qui ne peut être traitée séparément du reste. En effet, non seulement la « république des lettres » était encastrée dans le jeu du pouvoir, mais Ferdinando Galiani avait pour propriété sociale éminente d’être le chargé d’affaire du Royaume des Deux-Siciles, chargé d’informer le gouvernement de son royaume sur le cours des négociations du Pacte de Famille. Sa présence assidue dans les salons parisiens ne témoigne pas seulement de son goût pour la bonne compagnie et la conversation mondaine, mais de son professionnalisme : hors Versailles, nul espace plus propice, en effet, à la fréquentation des grands5. Si le terme diplomate apparaît tardivement, sous la Révolution semble-t-il, pour désigner le métier de représentant d’une puissance étrangère, la réalité professionnelle lui est antérieure6.
    [Show full text]
  • The History of Economic Policy in Thecontext of a History of Economic Thought
    The History of Economic Policy in the Context of a History of Economic Thought. Erik S. Reinert, January-February 2002. 1. Introduction. Methodology and Toolboxes: The Different Kinds of Economics. Readings: The Other Canon, ‘Two Different Ways of Understanding the Economic World and The Wealth and Poverty of Nations (3 pages), Bruce Henderson, Boston Consulting Group, Perspectives on Strategy (1998): ‘Business Thinking’, BCG, pp. 260-263. 2. Theories of History: Learning, Technological Change and Economic Development. Erik Reinert: ‘Karl Bücher and the Geographical Dimensions of Techno-Economic Change: Production-Based Economic Theory and the Stages of Economic Development’. Albert O. Hirschman: ‘The Passions and the Interests’, pp. 9-31+132-135. 3. The Renaissance and Duty-Based Systems: From Economic Anthropology to Statecrafting and Nation-Building. The Failure of Spain’s 16th Century Policies. Readings: Reinert & Daastøl, ‘Exploring the Genesis of Economic Innovations: The Religious Gestalt-Switch and the Duty to Invent as Preconditions for Economic Growth’, pp- 1-24 (= 233-264). Gustav Schmoller: ‘The Mercantile System and its Historical Significance’, particularly pp. 1-17, 29-36, 49- 80, 4. Mercantilism, Colbertism and Cameralism: Economic Growth as Activity-Specific, ‘Good’ and ‘Bad’ Trade, The Role of Cities and Diversity, Scale and Synergies. Readings: Antonio Serra, ‘A Brief Treatise’ (1613), (Monroe pp. 145-167), Daniel Defoe, ‘A Plan of English Commerce’ (1730) pp. 126-135, Philipp von Hornick, ‘Nine Principal Rules of National Economy’, from ‘Austria Over All if She Only Will (1684), (Monroe pp. 223- 227). 5. The 18th Century and the Mandevillean Revolution; Physiocracy and Adam Smith. Reading: Eric Roll on Adam Smith, ‘A History of Economic Thought’, pp.
    [Show full text]
  • Hollsten, Laura. "Controlling Nature and Transforming Landscapes in the Early Modern Caribbean." Global Environment 1 (2008): 80–113
    Full citation: Hollsten, Laura. "Controlling Nature and Transforming Landscapes in the Early Modern Caribbean." Global Environment 1 (2008): 80–113. http://www.environmentandsociety.org/node/4218. First published: http://www.globalenvironment.it. Rights: All rights reserved. Made available on the Environment & Society Portal for nonprofit educational purposes only, courtesy of Gabriella Corona, Consiglio Nazionale delle Ricerche / National Research Council of Italy (CNR), and XL edizioni s.a.s. Controlling Nature and Transforming Landscapes in the Early Modern Caribbean Laura Hollsten he Early Modern Caribbean is a highly in- teresting area for the global as well as the environmental historian.1 h e Caribbean islands were some of the most important colonies in the seventeenth century and part of the international trade network as one of the cornerstones of the so-called T “triangular trade” between Europe, Africa and the Americas. h e growth of markets and buying power in Europe stimulated investments in sugar plan- tations. Westbound European ships, on their way to what they ini- tially thought of as India, i rst arrived here bringing with them peo- ple, animals, diseases, arms and the beginnings of a new culture. h e Caribbean has sometimes been characterised as a place where people, plants and animals were acclimatised before they entered the mainland of America. Mary Louise Pratt’s concept of a contact zone, designating an area of contact between dif erent peoples in a colonial situation, can be applied to contacts between biotypes, animals and plants, as well as humans.2 h e seventeenth-century Caribbean was a contact zone for dif erent peoples, as well as animals and plants.
    [Show full text]
  • The In/Visible Woman: Mariangela Ardinghelli and the Circulation Of
    The In/visible Woman: Mariangela Ardinghelli and the Circulation of Knowledge between Paris and Naples in the Eighteenth Century Author(s): Paola Bertucci Source: Isis, Vol. 104, No. 2 (June 2013), pp. 226-249 Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of The History of Science Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/670946 . Accessed: 29/06/2013 11:12 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press and The History of Science Society are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Isis. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 130.132.173.211 on Sat, 29 Jun 2013 11:12:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions The In/visible Woman Mariangela Ardinghelli and the Circulation of Knowledge between Paris and Naples in the Eighteenth Century By Paola Bertucci* ABSTRACT Mariangela Ardinghelli (1730–1825) is remembered as the Italian translator of two texts by the Newtonian physiologist Stephen Hales, Haemastaticks and Vegetable Staticks. This essay shows that her role in the Republic of Letters was by no means limited to such work.
    [Show full text]
  • Ancient Economic Thought, Volume 1
    ANCIENT ECONOMIC THOUGHT This collection explores the interrelationship between economic practice and intellectual constructs in a number of ancient cultures. Each chapter presents a new, richer understanding of the preoccupation of the ancients with specific economic problems including distribution, civic pride, management and uncertainty and how they were trying to resolve them. The research is based around the different artifacts and texts of the ancient East Indian, Hebraic, Greek, Hellenistic, Roman and emerging European cultures which remain for our consideration today: religious works, instruction manuals, literary and historical writings, epigrapha and legal documents. In looking at such items it becomes clear what a different exercise it is to look forward, from the earliest texts and artifacts of any culture, to measure the achievements of thinking in the areas of economics, than it is to take the more frequent route and look backward, beginning with the modern conception of economic systems and theory creation. Presenting fascinating insights into the economic thinking of ancient cultures, this volume will enhance the reawakening of interest in ancient economic history and thought. It will be of great interest to scholars of economic thought and the history of ideas. B.B.Price is Professor of Ancient and Medieval History at York University, Toronto, and is currently doing research and teaching as visiting professor at Massachusetts Institute of Technology. ROUTLEDGE STUDIES IN THE HISTORY OF ECONOMICS 1 Economics as Literature
    [Show full text]
  • Curriculum Vitae (Updated August 1, 2021)
    DAVID A. BELL SIDNEY AND RUTH LAPIDUS PROFESSOR IN THE ERA OF NORTH ATLANTIC REVOLUTIONS PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Curriculum Vitae (updated August 1, 2021) Department of History Phone: (609) 258-4159 129 Dickinson Hall [email protected] Princeton University www.davidavrombell.com Princeton, NJ 08544-1017 @DavidAvromBell EMPLOYMENT Princeton University, Director, Shelby Cullom Davis Center for Historical Studies (2020-24). Princeton University, Sidney and Ruth Lapidus Professor in the Era of North Atlantic Revolutions, Department of History (2010- ). Associated appointment in the Department of French and Italian. Johns Hopkins University, Dean of Faculty, School of Arts & Sciences (2007-10). Responsibilities included: Oversight of faculty hiring, promotion, and other employment matters; initiatives related to faculty development, and to teaching and research in the humanities and social sciences; chairing a university-wide working group for the Johns Hopkins 2008 Strategic Plan. Johns Hopkins University, Andrew W. Mellon Professor in the Humanities (2005-10). Principal appointment in Department of History, with joint appointment in German and Romance Languages and Literatures. Johns Hopkins University. Professor of History (2000-5). Johns Hopkins University. Associate Professor of History (1996-2000). Yale University. Assistant Professor of History (1991-96). Yale University. Lecturer in History (1990-91). The New Republic (Washington, DC). Magazine reporter (1984-85). VISITING POSITIONS École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales, Visiting Professor (June, 2018) Tokyo University, Visiting Fellow (June, 2017). École Normale Supérieure (Paris), Visiting Professor (March, 2005). David A. Bell, page 1 EDUCATION Princeton University. Ph.D. in History, 1991. Thesis advisor: Prof. Robert Darnton. Thesis title: "Lawyers and Politics in Eighteenth-Century Paris (1700-1790)." Princeton University.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cameralists: Fertile Sources for a New Science of Public Finance
    The Cameralists: Fertile Sources for a New Science of Public Finance Richard E. Wagner Department of Economics George Mason University Fairfax, VA 22030, USA Abstract The cameralist writers emerged after 1500, primarily in the German- speaking lands, and stayed on the scene until the middle of the 19th century. While I devote some effort to characterizing some of the work and themes of the cameralists, I devote most of this paper to an examination of the contemporary relevance of a cameralist orientation for scholarship in public finance. To place such stress upon contemporary relevance is not to ignore the vast differences between their times and ours, but is only to affirm that there are some enduring themes within the cameralist orientation that could prove interesting and fruitful for contemporary scholarship in public finance. JEL Code: B11, H1 The cameralists emerged around 1500, and were mostly located in the German-speaking lands. By the time they had disappeared in the middle of the 19th century, they had amassed a collective bibliography of more than 14,000 items, according to Magdalene Humpert (1937). To someone raised on contemporary economic theory, the cameralists would surely seem highly irrelevant. Among other things, they were oriented toward practice and not toward the refinement of theoretical schemata. Principles were present, to be sure, and these were brought to bear on various matters of substantive practice. The driving interest of the cameralists, however, lay in their ability to operate 2 more effectively in a substantive manner, and not on the development of theoretical argument. Joseph Schumpeter (1954, pp.
    [Show full text]
  • Nationalism's Entangled Histories
    With the support of the Fondation Pierre du Bois pour l'histoire du temps présent Pierre du Bois Annual Conference 2020 POLITICAL PROTEUS: NATIONALISM’S ENTANGLED HISTORIES Thursday 1 October 2020 | Friday 2 October 2020 > Maison de la paix, chemin Eugène-Rigot 2, 1202 Geneva Biographies and capitalism. She earned her PhD in History from the University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA) in 2018. She has published on US-EU-Russia trade, on trans-Atlantic economic relations in the postwar period, and on the political influence of multinational corporations. Her current book project investigates the relationship of business to the process of European integration. Grace Ballor’s research has been supported by the European CEMIL AYDIN Union Studies Association, the Business History Conference, the The University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Fondation Jean Monnet pour l’Europe, the Center for Economic Cemil Aydin is Professor of Global History at the University of History, and several research centers across the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. His research concerns both California. modern Middle Eastern history and modern Asian history, with an emphasis on the international and intellectual histories of the Ottoman and Japanese Empires. His previous research has focused on historical processes that shape transnational racial and civilisational identities, such as Muslim, Asian, African. He is the author of The Idea of the Muslim World (2017) and The Politics of Anti-Westernism in Asia: Visions of World Order in Pan-Islamic and Pan-Asian Thought (2007). SEBASTIAN CONRAD Freie Universität Berlin Sebastian Conrad is Professor of History at the Freie Universität Berlin.
    [Show full text]
  • The Futures of Global History
    Richard Drayton and David Motadel Discussion: the futures of global history Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Drayton, Richard and Motadel, David (2018) Discussion: the futures of global history. Journal of Global History, 13 (1). pp. 1-21. ISSN 1740-0228 DOI: 10.1017/S1740022817000262 © 2018 Cambridge University Press This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/86797/ Available in LSE Research Online: February 2018 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. The Futures of Global History Richard Drayton and David Motadel ‘If you believe you are a citizen of the world, you are citizen of nowhere’, declared Theresa May in autumn 2016 to the Tory party conference, questioning the patriotism of those who still dared to question Brexit. Within a month, ‘Make America Great Again’ triumphed in the polls in the United States.
    [Show full text]
  • Download Download
    Global histories a student journal From Imperial Science to Post-Patriotism: The Polemics and Ethics of British Imperial History Emma Gattey DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.17169/GHSJ.2021.357 Source: Global Histories, Vol. 6, No. 2 (January 2021), pp. 90-101. ISSN: 2366-780X Copyright © 2021 Emma Gattey License URL: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ Publisher information: ‘Global Histories: A Student Journal’ is an open-access bi-annual journal founded in 2015 by students of the M.A. program Global History at Freie Universität Berlin and Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin. ‘Global Histories’ is published by an editorial board of Global History students in association with the Freie Universität Berlin. Freie Universität Berlin Global Histories: A Student Journal Friedrich-Meinecke-Institut Koserstraße 20 14195 Berlin Contact information: For more information, please consult our website www.globalhistories.com or contact the editor at: [email protected]. From Imperial Science to Post-Patriotism: The Polemics and Ethics of British Imperial History by EMMA GATTEY 90 Global Histories: a student journal | VI - 2 - 2020 Emma Gattey | From Imperial Science to Post-Patriotism 91 VI - 2 - 2020 | ABOUT THE AUTHOR History at the University of Oxford. Emma Gattey is a first-year PhD student in History at on Māori activist-intellectuals and their participation in the University of Cambridge. Her current work focuses the University of Cambridge. century. She is a writer and literary critic from Aotearoa century. transnational anticolonial networks in the late twentieth transnational anticolonial networks New Zealand, a former barrister, and has studied law and New Zealand, a former barrister, history at the University of Otago, and Global and Imperial history at the University of Otago, Global Histories: a student journal ABSTRACT Through a brief intellectual biography of British imperial history, upon recent academic and expands this article examines of history.
    [Show full text]