<<

DPRIETI Discussion Paper Series 16-E-028

From Economic Controls to Export Expansion in Postwar : 1946-1960

Tsong-Min WU National Taiwan University

The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/

RIETI Discussion Paper Series 16-E-028 March 2016

From Economic Controls to Export Expansion in Postwar Taiwan: 1946-19601

Tsong-Min WU Department of Economics, National Taiwan University

Abstract During 1955-2000, Taiwan's per capita gross domestic product (GDP) growth rate was the highest in the world. In the first half of the 20th century, the Japanese colonial government laid the basis for economic growth by establishing a modern economic institution in Taiwan. After taking over Taiwan in 1945, however, the (KMT) government adopted economic control policies which caused during 1946-1949. The control policies were continued after the KMT government retreated to Taiwan in late 1949. As a result, economic growth was stagnant. Fortunately, deregulations were initiated in the late 1950s, and Taiwan was able to rapidly expand its export sector. Using the textile industry as an important case, this paper analyzes what policy changes were critical in fostering the postwar export expansion and economic growth.

Keywords: Economic growth, Inflation, Exchange rate, Tax policy JEL classification: E31, O24, O43

RIETI Discussion Papers Series aims at widely disseminating research results in the form of professional papers, thereby stimulating lively discussion. The views expressed in the papers are solely those of the author(s), and neither represent those of the organization to which the author(s) belong(s) nor the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry.

1This study is conducted as a part of the Project “Historical Study on Japan's Trade and Industrial Policy: From an International Perspective” undertaken at Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). I thank Professor Haruhito Takeda, Professor Masahisa Fujita, other members in the project, and Discussion Paper seminar participants in RIETI for providing valuable comments on the previous drafts of this paper. I also thank Professor Teruhiro Minato for Japanese translation.

1 Introduction

In ϕ–ªªª, Taiwan’s GDP per capita growth rate was the highest in the world, fol- lowed by South Korea, Equatorial Guinea, Botswana, Oman, Singapore, Hong Kong, and Japan.Ï Equatorial Guinea, Botswana and Oman are endowed with rich natural re- sources of oil and diamonds, which partly explains why they grew so fast. ae average growth rates of the other ûve countries are: Taiwan (E.Êì), South Korea (E.•ì), Sin- gapore (.Eì), Hong Kong (.ì), and Japan (.Ïmì). In contrast, the growth rates of U.K. and U.S. were .•ì and .ì, respectively. In ϕ, Taiwan’s GDP per capita ranked the ÊEth in the world. Because of the ex- tremely high growth rate, the ranking of Taiwan’s GDP per capita rose quickly during the second half of the ªth century. She ranks the Ïth in ªÏª. Taiwan, South Korea, Hong Kong and Singapore was called the Asian Four Dragons due to their high eco- nomic growth rates aer World War II. aere have been many studies trying to explain the high growth of the Four Dragons. In the case of Taiwan, almost all the researchers agree that the institutions and infrastructure established during the Japanese colonial period laid the foundation for the postwar high growth. Taiwan’s postwar high growth was accompanied by export expansion, and many studies tries to explain how export expansion was initialized in the late ϕªs. Important studies include Hsing (ϕ;Ï), Lin (ϕ;m), Ho (ϕ;Ê), Little (ϕ;•) and Scott (ϕ;•). In particular, Scott (ϕ;•, pp. mÏ–mª) analyzed the policy changes in the late ϕªs, and concluded that the following were crucial: tax rebate for exports, removal of import restriction, moving from multiple exchange rate to single exchange rate system, and depreciation of the New Taiwan . Figure Ïcompares the growth patterns of Taiwan and ûve other countries. In ϕ, GDP per capita in the Philippines was higher than that in Taiwan by Ïì. But in ϕ–ªªª, its growth rage was only Ï.m;ì. Because of this, its GDP per capita was only Ï.ªì of Taiwan in ªªª. Figure Ï also shows that Taiwan’s high growth began in the early ϕEªs, the growth rate in the ϕªs was nothing special. Aer World War II, the KMT government adopted economic control policies which brought adverse eòects on the economy. ae dereg- ulations in the late ϕªs eòectively promoted economic growth. However, the policy change from controls to de-controls have not been fully understood. ais study will investigate the origin of the control policies ûrst. We then provide a detailed case study of the textile industry, and analyze how export expansion policy was implemented in

ÏSource, Maddison Project, http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/maddison-project/home.htm, unit, ϕ•ª International Geary-Khamis .Growth rate was calculated by taking the ratio of the ûrst year to that of the last year, and then computed the average growth rate. Using the data from the World , Taiwan ranks the nd in ªÏm.

Ï 30,000

10,000 USA Taiwan 5,000 Japan 2,000

1,000

500 China Philippines South Korea 200

1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure Ï: GDP per capita growth rate

Source: Taiwan, Wu (ªª); other countries, Maddison Project. the late ϕªs. In the following, section  explains how the economic controls in the second half of ϕªs led to a hyperination in Taiwan. ae Provincial government adopted a monetary reform in June ϕ•, and issued the New Taiwan (NT) dollar. To establish the public conûdence on the new , the NT dollar was supported by gold standard and ûxed exchange rate. However, since the price level did not stabilize completely, the exchange rate was forced to be adjusted repeatedly. Section m explained that in order to solve the trade deûcit problem, the (BOT) started to diòerentiate the exchange rate for export and import, the rates for public and private companies were also diòerent. ae textile industry began to develop in the early ϕªs, it became the most impor- tant private industry in the ϕEª–;ªs. Section  shows that in ϕª, textile industry was free from regulation. But by the end of ϕ, both prices and quantities were controlled by the government. During ϕm–E, there were de-controls, re-controls, and then de- controls again. Section  ûrst shows that over-valuation of the NT and high tax rate made it impossible for Taiwan to export cotton yarn and clothing. In the late ϕªs, with the introduction of tax refund and depreciation of NT dollar, the comparative ad- vantage of cheap labor emerged, and Taiwan was able to export textile products. Section E analyzes the conditions of high growth, and argues that institutions and infrastructure were essential for Taiwan’s postwar growth. And ûnally in section ;, we argue that, in contrast to a widely-held view, import substitution in the early ϕªs was not a necessary condition for the export expansion later.

 2 Economic Controls and Hyperination

Aer the KMT government took over Taiwan in ϕ, almost all of the Japanese en- terprises were turned into public enterprises. ae most important one was the (TSC), which was consolidated from four Japanese private compa- nies, and became a monopoly aer ϕE.

2.1 State Enterprise and Hyperination ae rationale used by the KMT oõcials for turning Taiwan into a state enterprises system was the doctrine by Dr. Sun Yat-sen, “developing state capital, restricting pri- vate capital” (「發達國家資本, 節制私人資本」). However, Sun’s proposal was mainly for heavy industry, utilities and transportation, and sugar industry was none of them. Trad- ing company was another example. In November ϕ, the KMT government consoli- dated seven Japanese trading companies into the Taiwan Trade Bureau (貿易局), a state enterprise. In ϕE, more than one third of the trading service in Taiwan was provided by the Bureau. If “developing state capital” was at most a slogan, what was the real motive for creat- ing a state enterprise system? arough public enterprises, it was easier for the govern- ment to get income to ûnance its expenditure. In FY ϕE, for example, public enter- prises and state monopolies contributed m.ì of government income. ae percentage for ϕ;–• was mE.Eì, .;ì, and •.Ïì, respectively.m ae Taiwan Trade Bureau played a especially important role in government ûnance. In FY ϕE, its contribution to the Treasury was ; million Taiwan dollars, or Ï.ªì of the Provincial government’s ex- penditure. Chen (ϕE, p. Ϫ) pointed out that Taiwan Trade Bureau and the succeeding Trade Committee (貿易調節委員會) was operated with an aim to ûnance the budget deûcit. ae Trade Bureau’s big proût actually came from a tax on private and public enterprises, and hence led to protests from the latter. However, the practice of using the proût of public enterprises to ûnance government budget deûcit was continued aer the KMT government retreated to Taiwan at the end of ϕ•. Fig  shows the percentage of production of the public enterprises to total manu- facturing. Comparing with the prewar period, the share increased tremendously aer ϕE. Unfortunately, the enormous scale of the public enterprise system produced seri- ous eòects on the economy, and hyperination was one of them. Figure m shows money supply and WPI in ϕ–. From the end of August to the year-end of ϕª, Taiwan’s

mTaiwan Provincial Government (ϕ;Ï), pp. E•–•。 Wu (ϕ•;), pp. mE–mÊ。

m % 80

60

40

20

1931 1934 1937 1940 1943 1946 1949 1952 1955 1958 1961 1964 1967 1970 Figure : Percentage of state enterprises production

Source: Wu (ϕ•;), ûgure Ê.

WPI increased by m thousands times. ae study by Wu (ϕ•;) showed that the two main causes for Taiwan’s hyperination were the state enterprise system and the government budget deûcit. For the former, the government asked the Taiwan Sugar Company to sell sugar in Shanghai at a price usually lower than the production cost. ae money-losing TSC then had to borrow money from the BOT. ae more strict of the government con- trol on sugar price, the more the TSC had to borrow from the BOT, and the more money was printed. In the beginning of the ϕªs, the Taiwan District Production Business Management Committee (TDPBMC) was in charge of designing the industrial policy. ae TDPBMC was established on the Ϫth of June, and ûve days later the Provincial government an- nounced a monetary reform. To counter hyperination, the Provincial government de- clared that “production must increase, ... and all the public enterprises must cooperate under the direction of the TDPBMC”. Ironically, loans from the BOT to public en- terprises was the main cause of money supply increase at least during the period of ϕE–Ê. ais situation did not change aer the monetary reform. At the end of ϕÊ, among the total loans from the BOT,ÊÏ.;ì was directed to pub- lic enterprises, and ÏÊ.mì was to the government oõces.E Toward the end of ϕ•, the total amount of loans increased tremendously, but the percentage of loans to public en- terprises was lowered to ª.ì, while the percentage to government oõces increased to •.Eì. Aer the KMT government retreated to Taiwan at the end of ϕ•, defense spending increased tremendously. ae percentage of defense spending to central gov- ernment spending reached ʕ.ì in FY ϕª, and government budget deûcit became the main cause of ination.

Chen (ϕm), pp. Ï–Ï. EWu (ϕ•), table , p. ϕ.

 10,, 000 000

10,000,000

1,000,000

100,000 Net currency issues WPI

10,000

1,000

100 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 Figure m: Money supply and ination: ϕ–ϕ

ae unit of net currency issues was million Taiwan dol- lars. ae base year of WPI was ϕm;, WPI = Ϫª. Source: Wu and Kuo (ϕ•Ï).

2.2 Monetary Reform and Gold Savings Deposit On June Ï, ϕ•, the Provincial government launched a monetary reform, a new cur- rency called the New Taiwan dollar was issued to replace the original one, with the exchange rate set to be Ï to ª,ªªª. To establish public conûdence on the new currency, the government introduced two policies. ae ûrst policy was to ûx the price of the NT dollar to gold, with one Taiwanese ounce to be equal to NT mmª dollar. ae second policy was to ûx the exchange rate of one US dollar to be equal to ûve NT dollars. ae public were allowed to buy gold or US dollar from the BOT with NT dollar. Comparing the price level of ϕm; and June ϕ•, the oõcial exchange rate was an over-valuation of the NT dollar. In ϕm;, the market exchange rate of the Taiwan dollar with the US dollar was m.;Ï. From the ûrst half of ϕm; to June ϕ•, ’s retail

 price index increased by Ï,E.m times. During the same period, the US CPI increased by Ï.E times. According to purchasing power parity, the market equilibrium exchange rate of the NT dollar in June ϕ• would be Ê.Ê. As expected, the over-valuation caused drainage of the BOT’s foreign reserves. About one month before the monetary reform, the BOT launched the Gold Savings Deposit on May Ï;th. ae public were encouraged to open an account in any of the branches of the BOT. Aer a deposit in Taiwan dollar was made, and the money had been stored in the account for over one month, the depositor had the option to withdraw an equivalent value of gold. When the monetary reform was launched, the time required for drawing out gold was shortened to ten days. ae purpose of the Gold Savings Deposit was to establish the NT dollar as a gold standard currency. However, the reform did not completely stabilize the price level. Between ϕª and ϕ, WPI increased by .mm times, which amounted to an annual ination rate of ÏÊ.ì. ae public rushed to the BOT to open a Gold Savings account and to withdraw gold two weeks later, and importers bought a large amount of US dollars from the BOT. As a result, there were a big drain of gold and foreign exchanges, and the BOT was forced to change both policies. ae changes and adjustments in the exchange rate policy led to the notorious multiple exchange rate system in the ϕªs.

2.3 The End of Hyperination Because the drainage of gold, the BOT began to change the oõcial price of gold in June ϕª, but the drainage did not stopped. Before the monetary reform, the BOT accumulated gold worthy of .Ê million US dollars and Ϫ millon US dollars in .

Toward the end of ϕª, the BOT lost about two thirds of gold reserves.; On December ;, ϕª, the BOT abandoned the Gold Savings Deposit policy. Why the Gold Savings Deposit policy failed? In the second half of ϕ•, the military situation of the KMT government in the mainland deteriorated quickly. and ûnally the KMT government retreated to Taiwan in December ϕ•. In the beginning of ϕª, oõ- cial information agencies in the US and UK predicted that the Communist would attack

Taiwan in June ϕª.Ê In May ϕª, the US consulate in Taipei began to prepare for the withdrawal of the personnel in anticipation that the Communist would attack Taiwan.

He also asked all the American civilians to leave Taiwan.• Under the circumstances, it was impossible for the Gold Savings Deposit policy to raise the public conûdence on the NT dollar.

;See Shih,Chou, and Su (ϕEÏ), pp. Ϫ•–Ϫ, and Lin (ϕ;m). ÊCumings (ϕ•ª), p. . •Jarman (ϕ•;), vol. •, p. ÏÏ;.

E ae report of the British Consulate in Tamshui said that the breakout of the Korean

War on June , ϕª was a “Deus ex Machina” to Taiwan.Ϫ On June ;, ϕª, US presi- dent Truman announced that the US would resume the aid program to Taiwan. ae US government ûrst provided aid to the Republic of China in ϕÊ, but the program was suspended in ϕ•. ae resumption of the US aid saved Taiwan from being taken over by the Communist China. In addition, the US aid was the key to the ending of Taiwan’s hyperination, because it tremendously reduced Taiwan’s budget deûcit.

3 Controls on Exchange Rate and Trade

When the monetary reform was announced, the exchange rate of the NT dollar to the US dollar was . To establish public conûdence on the NT dollar, the BOT did not restrict foreign exchange transactions. Importers were allowed to apply for as much foreign exchanges as needed from the BOT. Since the US dollar was under-valued, the

BOT’s foreign exchange reserve was drained.ÏÏ ais was exactly the same as the eòects of the Gold Savings Deposit policy. ae termination of the Gold Savings Deposit did not produce adverse eòects on the economy because gold was not the medium of exchange. In contrast, the US dollar was extensively used in international trade. ae BOT could also terminated US exchange transactions, but this would be equivalent to the abandonment of ûxed exchange rate system. ae KMT government took another route instead: controlled exchange rate, restrained public holdings of foreign exchange, and ûnally controlled foreign trade. As the ûrst step to stop drainage of the foreign reserves, the government asked all the public enterprises to transfer their foreign exchange holdings to the BOT in February ϕª. However, this did not lessen the draining because the private enterprises contin- ued to buy foreign exchanges from the BOT. ae oõcial exchange rate was changed to ;.ª dollar on February Ï, ϕª, and then to Ê.ª on April ÏÊ. At the time, the exchange rage in the black market was •.mm, so the depreciation did not stop speculation on the foreign exchange.Ï On December ϕ, ϕª, the BOT started to control the demand for foreign exchange. All the applications for foreign exchange needed to be examined and veriûed. Without passing the veriûcation, foreign exchange would not be provided. However, if an im- porter bought foreign exchange from the market, he was still able to import goods from abroad. On April •, ϕÏ, the Executive announced a new “Policy on Financial

ϪJarman (ϕ•;), vol. •, pp. Ï–. ÏÏHu (ϕ), pp. Ï–m; Chen (ϕE), pp. Ïm–. ÏChen (ϕE), pp. ªª–ªÏ。

; 50 Black market 40 Private import 30

20

Private export 10 Public export (Sugar and Rice)

1949 1951 1953 1955 1957 1959 1961 1963 1965 1967 Figure : ae Exchange Rate to the US Dollar (End of Year) Private import includes machinery and material. Private export includes banana and other exports, what is shown in the ûgure is for other exports only. Source: ϕ•–ª,Chen (ϕE), pp. Ϫª–ªÏ. ϕÏ and later, Ho (ϕ;Ê), pp. m•–•E. Black market, Lin (ϕ;m), p. E.

Transactions” (有關金融措施規定辦法), in which holding foreign exchange and gold was still allowed, but transactions were prohibited. In other words, all the transactions of foreign exchange and gold had to be done with the BOT. ais policy put all the im- ports under the control of the government. On April ÏÏ, ϕÏ. the exchange rate for the public enterprise’s export was changed to

Ϫ., and Ï.;m for private enterprise’s export.Ïm ae exchange rate for public enterprise’s imports and the US aid imports was Ϫ.; and the rate was Ï.Ê for private sector’s import. A complicated multiple exchange rate system was developed, as shown in Figure . ae multiple exchange rate system was complicated, but there were three charac- teristics. First, the NT dollar was over-valued. Second, the NT dollar was gradually de-valued through the ϕªs. Finally, the exchange rate for public enterprise’s export was lower than that of the private enterprise. ae long-term de-valuation of the NT dollar was easy to understand. From June ϕ• to the end of ϕÊ, Taipei’s retail price index increased by ;.ª times, and the US CPI increased by Ï.Ï times. According to purchasing power parity, the equilibrium exchange rate would increase by .Ê times, but in fact the oõcial exchange rate was increased by ;. times. ais implied that the NT dollar was over-valued in June ϕ•. Why the government set the export exchange rate of public enterprise to be lower than that of the private enterprise? In the early ϕªs, price had not yet been completely

ÏmHu (ϕ), pp. ;–Ê;Shih,Chou, and Su (ϕEÏ), pp. Ϫ–m; Chen (ϕE), pp. Ï;–•.

Ê stabilized. To reduce ination pressure, the BOT tried hard to reduce money supply. During the period, the TSC was the most important exporter. ae foreign exchanges earned from sugar export was required to be sold to the BOT.If the exchange rate was low, the BOT would issue less money, which presumably would reduce ination pres- sure. ae policy looked like a smart method to reduce the ination pressure, but actu- ally it did not work. Because of the exchange rate control, the TSC’s export was losing money and so it had to borrow from the BOT. ae money supply might decrease in the beginning, but eventually it had to increase.Ï Besides, the interest rate charged on public enterprises was signiûcantly lower than the market rate, this encouraged public enterprises to borrow from the BOT. Due to over-valuation of the NT dollar, Taiwan’s export had diõculty to compete in the international market. On January , ϕm, exchange rate for sugar export was raised to Ï.•. In September, import exchange for private sector was raised to ÏÊ.;Ê, but the adjustment was due to a new Defense surtax introduced by the Ministry of Finance. In ϕ, the BOT introduced a foreign exchange certiûcate system, which in eòect raised the exchange rate by six NT dollars. At the end of ϕ, market price for the certiûcate was Ï.• dollars, and so import exchange rate for private enterprise was mÏ.E• dollars. In contrast, export exchange rate was .Ê; dollars.Ï As shown in Figure , from ϕ• to ϕE; the oõcial exchange rate was always lower than the black market rate, indicating an over-valuation of the NT dollar. In the ϕªs, Taiwan faced persistent trade deûcit. A de-valuation of the NT dollar should be helpful to reverse the trend, but government oõcials did not believe that Taiwan was able to produce new industrial products to compete in the international market.ÏE aey also worried that de-valuation would cause price increase for imports, and hence worsen the ination problem.

4 Import Substitution: Textile Industry

During the Japanese colonial period, Taiwan imported most of the clothing from Japan. In ϕmÊ, domestic production of cotton cloth amounted to .•Êì of total supply, the rest was imported from Japan. aere were some small textile ûrms in Taiwan, which were consolidated into a public enterprise by the KMT government aer World War II. In ϕE–•, clothing were imported from the instead. Aer the mainland

ÏChen (ϕE), pp. Ï;–Ê. ÏShih,Chou, and Su (ϕEÏ), pp. Ϫ–. ÏEScott (ϕ;•), p. mʪ.

• % 50

40 food and beverage 30

20 textile 10

1949 1953 1957 1961 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997 Figure : Percentage Share of Food and Textile Industry

Source: DGBAS. was lost, Taiwan had to ûnd other channels for clothing supply. Taiwan’s textile industry began to develop in the early ϕªs, but production value was quite small. Aer export expansion was successful in the early ϕEªs, textile industry became one of the most successful private industries in Taiwan. ae development of the textile industry in the ϕªs reected how government of- ûcial’s thought on economic policy changed over time, from strict control in the be- ginning to market mechanism later. On the other hand, the textile industry policy also reected the constraint that the KMT government faced during the time. In the be- ginning of the ϕªs, the KMT government had to deal with three diõcult problems: hyperination, budget deûcit, and trade deûcit. Figure  compares the percentage share of food and beverage and textile industry. In early postwar period, food and beverage was the main industry, in which sugar was the most important product. However, the share of food and beverage decreased over time. In contrast, while the share of textiles increased from about ì in ϕ• to over Ïì in the mid-ϕ;ªs, the share of food and beverage had decreased to about Ϫì.

4.1 Free Market: 1949–1950 Taiwan did not grow cotton, all the cotton needed by yarn spinning mills was imported. During the US aid era (ϕª–E), almost all the cotton were imported from the US. Immediately aer the TDPBMC was established in June ϕ•, Taiwan faced a serious problem of clothing shortage. From the mid-ϕ• to mid-ϕª, the TDPBMC tried to let the market to solve the problem, adopting policies to encourage import and to promote domestic production. To encourage import, import tax for cotton cloth was reduced from Eì to ªì in

Ϫ NT dollar 800 Cotton yarn price control Cotton yarns (Ϫª kg) 600 30

400 20

Nankeens, Grey (ª yards) 200 10 Exchange rate (right axis) Cotton (Ϫª kg)

1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 Figure E: Textile prices All prices have been deated by WPI, base period, June ϕ•. Source: Taiwan Monthly of Commodity-Price Statistics, various issues.

August ϕÊ. And to promote domestic production, import tax for cotton was tem- porarily suspended for one year, and tax for cotton yarn was decreased from ªì to ì. As a result of tax reduction, cotton cloth import increased tremendously, mostly from Japan. Taiwan imported .ª million meters of cotton cloth in ϕ•, it increased to Ê.E million meters in ϕª. ae eòect of tax reduction could be seen from Figure E. From June ϕ• to March ϕª, the price of Nankeens (a widely-used fabric) decreased by m;.ì. ae domestic fabric mills were seriously aòected by the import. On the other hand, import tax reduction for cotton yarn was welcomed by fabric mills, but spinners were adversely aòected. In summary, free import and tax reduction policy were beneûcial to the public, but eòects on yarn spinning mills and fabric mills were mixed. ae extent of the adverse eòects partly depended upon the exchange rate.If ex- change rate was relatively high, domestic product would be relatively cheaper, and the eòects would be smaller, or even nil. Before March ϕª, the oõcial exchange rate was  dollar, but the black market rate of Ê.E dollar. At the end of ϕª, oõcial rate rose to Ϫ dollars, and market rate was Ï.ª dollar. Because the NT was over-valued, domestic mills had diõculty to compete with the imports.

4.2 From Free Market to Strict Control In April ϕª,Cotton Textile Association (台灣棉紡織同業公會) asked for help from the government. Speciûcally, the Association asked the government to prohibit import of cotton yarn and cloth, to provide loans from the US aid, to buy up inventories, and to supply low-interest loans. On May Ï;, the TDPBMC proposed to the Council for Inter-

ÏÏ national Economic Cooperation (經合署), which was responsible for US aid import, to stop importing US cotton yarn, and also to limit supply of clothes imported from the

US aid program.Ï; In May ϕª, the Taiwan Joint Textile Allocation committee was established, its re- sponsibility was to allocate cottons, cotton yarns, and clothes which were imported through the US aid program. ae committee was the decision maker for the textile industry policy, and the Central Trust of China (CTC) was responsible for policy ex- ecution. ae committee had been reorganized several times later, sometimes with the name changed slightly. But for simplicity of presentation, the decision-making commit- tee would be called “the Textile committee” in the following. Starting mid-ϕª, the imported cotton from the US aid program was directly al- located to yarn-spinning mills. Under the system, yarn-spinning mills were nothing more than subcontractors for the Textile committee. For every Ϫª pounds of cotton allocated, the mill got Ê pounds of cotton as remuneration, and the cotton yarn pro- duced from the latter could be freely sold in the market.ÏÊ ae cotton yarns collected back by the Textile committee were then allocated to fabric mills, which would produce fabric with a speciûed remuneration. Again the fabric mills were nothing more than subcontractors.ϕ ae system was called “the textile subcontractor system” (代紡代織). ae Textile committee might directly import cotton yarns from abroad, and allocated them to fabric mills. In ϕª, the share of cotton yarn import was estimated to be mª.;ì of the total supply in the domestic market.ª Under the system, the cotton yarn price was supposed to be under the control of the Textile committee. However, as shown in Figure E, cotton yarn prices rose dramatically aer June ϕª. Yarn-spinning mills were proûted from the price rise, fabric mills were adversely aòected. ae latter petitioned the government for prohibition of cotton cloth imports. ae TDPBMC thought that the price increase of cotton yarns was due to “unlaw- ful speculation” (不法人士操縱), and hence a series of control policies were taken to stabilized the price. Whenever a policy did not achieve the objective, a even stronger policy was implemented. As a result, toward the end of ϕÏ the whole textile industry, from cotton to fabrics, was under strict controls. During the time, government oõcials were extremely worried about any price rise, and regarded price control as an eòective solution. For example, K. Y. Yin who was the vice-director of the TDPBMC said that

Ï;Li (ªª), pp. •, E;. ÏÊLi (ªª), pp. E–E; Hsu (ªªm), p. ª. ϕLi (ªª), pp. E–E, •m–•. ªHuang (ϕE), pp. ;–Ê.

Ï US cents/pound

80 Cotton yarns

60 Cotton 40

20

1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 Figure ;: US Cotton and Cotton Prices Wholesale price deated by CPI. the price rise of cotton yarn was due to “deûciency in cotton yarn allocation system, ... the government has to control cotton yarn.”Ï In fact, cotton yarn price increase in mid-ϕª was a reecrtion of changes in de- mand and supply. First of all, the Textile committee only allocated cotton yarns to big fabric mills, small mills had to buy yarns from the market. Second, big mills received only about ªì of cotton yarns of its capacity on average, so it had to buy additional yarns from the market. As mentioned above, yarn-spinning mills got a certain amount of cotton as remuneration, and the cotton yarns produced from which could be freely sold in the market. When demand was high, price would be rise. Part of cotton yarns were imported from abroad. In ϕª, cotton yarn import was about mÏì of the total supply.Naturally, domestic cotton yarn price would be aòected by the world price. As shown in Figure ;, world cotton price increased dramatically around mid-ϕª. But about one year later, cotton yarn price started to fall. ae rise and fall of cotton yarn price in Taiwan was roughly consistent with the New York’s price, so it seemed clear that Taiwan’s price was aòected by the world market. In June ϕÏ, the TDPBMC announced that import applications for cotton fabrics would be temporarily suspended. As a result of the policy, supply of fabrics was reduced, which in turn led to an increase in demand for cotton yarns from domestic spinning mills, and the price of cotton yarn increased even more. Early in February ϕÏ, the CTC announced that the price of cloth was NT . dollar per yard. Household buyer had to show his Household registration card when purchasing cloth. In April, the Executive Yuan announced that all the exchange transactions had to be done through the BOT. Aer the policy change, unless importers got foreign exchange from the black market, it was impossible for the private sector to import cotton yarns.

ÏYin (ϕ), p. 。

Ïm On May , ϕÏ, a new Textile committee was established to replace the original one, and control policies were reenforced. Starting from June, spinning mills were re- munerated with cash instead of cottons. For a piece of cotton yarn (ªª pounds), the remuneration was NT Ï,Eªª dollars.Previously the subcontractor mills could sell the cotton yarns made from the remuneration cottons, now all the cotton yarns produced by the domestic ûrms were controlled of the CTC. On August Ï, the Provincial government decreed that the price ceiling for domes- tic and imported cotton yarns would be set by the government. In September, the TDPBMC passed a resolution to temporarily suspend applications for cotton yarn im- port from private sector, as a result the CTC also monopolized cotton yarn import. In November, it was decreed that in Taipei city one household could purchased at most  yards of white ûne cloth per year. aere were similar restriction in other cities of Tai- wan. At the second half of ϕ•, the textile market was a free market, import taxes were low or even nil. But by the end of ϕÏ, the market was under complete control by the government. Only the CTC could import cotton and cotton yarn, and the allocation of cottons and cotton yarns was controlled by the government, ae government set price ceilings on cotton yarns and clothes.It also reserved the right to buy ;ªì of the cotton yarns produced by spinning mills. Did the controls succeeded in stabilizing cotton yarn price? Figure E shows the price index of cotton yarn in April ϕ (Ï.•) was lower than that of August ϕª (Ï.ª), so it seemed that the control policies worked. But in fact, world cotton yarn price had already declined since mid-ϕÏ. Also the domestic market for cotton yarns had already reached saturation.m So even without the control policies the cotton yarn price should had declined at least in early ϕ. ae control policies taken in the early ϕªs were usually described as an import substitution policy, but actually most of the policies were aimed at controlling cotton yarn price. Aer ϕ, domestic cotton yarn price was lowered to the normal level, so control policies were removed gradually. However, three years later a similar control policy was launched by the government again.

4.3 De-control and Re-control Starting September ϕ, controls were gradually removed, cotton yarn produced by spinning mills was allowed to be freely sold in the market. ae main reason for de-

Li (ªª), p. ;Ï. mHuang (ϕE), p. Ê.

Ï control was that cotton price had been lower than the price ceiling. Also any control on cotton yarn price produced a proût re-distribution between spinners and fabric mills. Spinner welcomed higher cotton yarn price, but fabric mills would complain. aere was also a proût re-distribution problem within spinners and fabric mills.Large and eõcient spinners desired for more cottons. Similarly, large and eõcient fabric mills asked for more cotton yarns. Finally, the cost of control policy implementation was commonly shared by the spinning and fabric mills, this was yet another reason that some mills wanted to reduce or remove the controls. In December ϕ, fabric subcontractor system (代織制度) was abolished, fabric mills could sell its fabric in the market. In February ϕm, spinning subcontractor system (代紡制度) was also abolished. Spinners were allowed to import cottons, and then sold the produced cotton yarns in the market. However, the TDPBMC still set price ceil- ing. Finally in September ϕ,ESB abolished the price ceiling because market prices had been much lower. Another reason was that even if market price was higher than the price ceiling, there was actually no eòective enforcement mechanism to deal with the problem.E However, import of cotton yarn and cotton cloth remained prohibited. As can be seen from Figure E, cotton yarn price was relatively stable in ϕm and ϕ, but then it started to rise again in February ϕ. ae main reason for this round of price rise was that the government raised commodity tax and import tax, and also de-valued the NT dollar. Commodity tax rose from ì to Ïì in August ϕ, and import tax for cotton yarns was raised from ì to Ï;ì in ϕ. ae exchange rate for cotton import from the US aid program was Ï.E dollars previously, it was raised to .;Ê dollar in July ϕ. With de-valuation and tax rate hikes, it was reasonable for mills to raise cotton yarn price. But the government launched a new wave of price control. In February ϕ, the government asked spinning mills to submit their cotton yarns to the Textiles Associa- tion, which was asked to sell the yarns “in an equitable manner”. On July •, the CTC took over the job of allocation, but its new regulation that the fabric mills were required to pay deposit of ªì was heavily protested. In November, the deposit was reduced to ì. In the beginning of ϕE, cotton yarns price fell, and the regulations established in the previous year were removed. In March, spinning mills had accumulated too much inventory and asked the government for help. ae ESB asked the CTC to buy the in- ventory, but the CTC objected, and proposed instead that the system of cotton yarns

Li (ªª), pp. ÏmÏ–m. Li (ªª), pp. Ï–Ê. ELi (ªª), pp. •m–•.

Ï allocation be removed. In July ϕ;, the allocation system was terminated.;

5 Export Expansion ae idea of promoting textile export was raised at least as early as in ϕm, the motivation was that there had been an excess supply of cotton yarn in the domestic market. ae initial proposal was to barter with for cotton suitable for ûne yarn and then with Pakistan for cotton suitable for coarse yarn. But an estimate of cost showed that for a piece of ûne cotton yarn exported, the government needed to subsidize NT m dollars. without subsidy, the export would lose money. In August ϕm, the price of cotton yarn in the domestic market was ,mªª dollars, so the subsidy was about Ï.ì of the export price.Ê

5.1 Tax Refund, devaluation and Low Interest Loans ae share of textile export to production was ª.Eì in ϕ. It increased to Ï.mEì in ϕÊ, and then Ê.Eì next year. What policy change was critical for the export expansion success? Why Taiwan was not able to export until late ϕªs? In ϕm, the Ministry of Economic Aòairs promoted an idea of exporting cotton yarn to South Korea. Table Ï was an estimate of the cost structure by spinners. Column  was calculated with the oõcial exchange rate of Ï.Eª dollars. To make a piece of cotton yarn, ;ª pounds of cotton was needed. ae import cost for one pound of cotton was NT .; dollar, or ª.mE US dollar by the oõcial exchange rate. In other words, the cost of cotton for one piece of cotton yarn was NT , dollar (import tax of ì not included). Processing charge (including wages) was NT Ï,mª dollars. Adding transport, insurance, and gross proût, the price of one piece of cotton yarn was NT ,mE; dollars, or US ª.;ªª dollar per pound.• In June ϕm, wholesale cotton yarn price in New York was US ª.Em• dollar, so exporter would lose money. Column  was an estimate using the oõcial exchange rate of Ï.Eª dollar. In ϕm, black market rate was E. dollar. Using this rate, the cotton yarn price would be lowered to US ª.•m dollar (column m), and exporters could make a proût. However, the estimate of cost excluded cotton import tax (ì), commodity tax (Ïì), and harbour duty (ì).mª If the above taxes were included, export price would be raised to ª.E; dollar, exporters still lost money. ae estimate shows clearly that de-valuation and tax refund will be

;Hsu (ªªm), pp. ÏE–m. ÊHsu (ªªm), pp. •Ê–••. •ae estimate was for export to South Korea.If the destination was the US, transport and insurance would be higher. mªCommodity tax was ì in ϕm, but increased to Ïì in August ϕ.

ÏE Table Ï:Cost structure of Cotton Yarn Export

Exchange rate Ò.G­ G.­ ­.­­ Cotton price , ,pÒ­ G,­ Processing charges Ò,p­ Ò,p­ Ò,p­ Packaging Ì­ Ì­ Ì­ Sea transport    Land transport ­ ­ ­ Insurance Ò Ò Ò Interest Ì­ ÒpG ­ Gross proût (ì) = p—  Total ,pG= G,ÌÒ Ì,GG Cotton yarn (US dollar/pound) ­.=­­ ­.—p ­.Ò

Source: Liu (җ), Lu (җp), Lu (җ), and Huang (җG). If import tax (ì), commodity tax (Òì), and harbour duty (ì) were added, cot- ton prices would become US ­.=ÌÒ dollar, ­.G= dollar, and ­.Gp dollar, respectively. an eòective policy for export expansion. In ϕEª, the exchange rate was depreciated to ª dollars. Column m shows that cotton yarn price became ª.Ï dollar if taxes were excluded.If taxes were included, export price would be raised to ª.Em dollar, so it was still proûtable to export. ae role of exchange rate and taxes can be explained by the following equation. Let p be the cost of cotton (in US dollar) for a piece of cotton yarn, and p the price of c n cotton yarn. Variable w is the sum of processing charge, transport, insurance, and gross proût (in NT dollar), t is the sum of taxes, and e is the exchange rate, then e p w t w t p ⋅ c + + p + . (Ï) n = e = c + e It is clear that both exchange rate and tax rate aòect the price of cotton yarn. Equation (Ï) can be rewritten as follows: p w t Ï n Ï + .() p = + p ⋅ e c c For Taiwan, p was determined by the world market.If the exchange rate e is higher c (the NT dollar de-valued), p would be lower, and Taiwan’s cotton yarn becomes more n competitive in the world market. It is also clear that the eòect of devaluation would be larger if the ratio w t p is ( + )~ c large. Using the data from input-output table, Scott (ϕ;•, p. mÊ) calculated the ratio of traded inputs to price, p p , was ª.;ª for Taiwan’s textile industry in ϕ;Ï. Alternatively, c~ n using the ûgures in column m of Table Ï, p p ª.;. c~ n =

Ï; % 20 Textile export to production

15 ratio

10 Refund to export (all industries) 5 Refund to export (cotton products)

1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 Figure Ê: Tax refund and export expansion Tax refund was ûscal year data, export was calendar data, the former was transformed into calendar data by simple average. Source: Refund to ex- port (all industries), Hsiao (ϕ•), p. Ïm•; refund to export (cotton prod- ucts), Lin (ϕE•), pp. ʕ, ϪE; textile export, Lin (ϕE•), p. Êm, textile pro- duction, Industry of Free China, various issues.

Tax also aòected export price. For Taiwan, all the cotton was imported. De-valuation would lower the price of cotton yarn in the world market, but price of cotton would in- crease, which in turn would increase the price of cotton yarn. However, if import tax and commodity taxes could be refunded to exporters, it would lower the export price of cotton yarn. ae ûrst tax refund aer World War II in Taiwan was applied to paper hat industry. In the beginning, only a portion of import tax could be refunded. In ϕ, the system was revised and tax oòsetting was allowed. In March ϕ, Economic Stability Board (ESB, 經安會) passed a resolution to extend tax refund to cotton yarn export. Besides exporters were qualiûed to apply for low- interest loans. But spinners were not interested because taxes had to be paid ûrst, refund would be given back only aer cotton yarns were exported. Similarly, low-interest loans would be provided only aer cotton yarns were exported. In ϕ, the government was preoccupied with controlling prices. In ϕE there was again an excess supply of cotton yarns, and the idea of promoting textile export was raised again. During the following two years, tax refund policies were revised several times, and ûnally in December ϕ•, an eòective tax refund and oòsetting policy was established, which covered import tax, defense surtax, commodity tax, and harbour duties. As shown in Figure Ê, the policy worked this time, and textile export started to grow. In the beginning, tax refund was for textile industry only, but later it was applied to all other export industries as well. In ϕÊ, the ratio of tax refund to export was .mì, it increased to .ì in ϕ•, and then Ê.ì in ϕEª. ae purpose of tax refund and oò- setting was intended to reduce of cost of export, but there was tremendous transaction

ÏÊ costs involved. In ϕEE, export processing zones and bonded factories and warehouses were established, which reduced the transaction cost of tax refund even further.mÏ Besides tax refund, other policies also help to reduce export cost, including de- valuation, low interest loans, and removal of import restrictions ae NT dollar de- valued from .Ê dollar in ϕÊ to mE.ªÊ in ϕ•, and then ª.ª in ϕEª. ae exchange rate stayed at this level until ϕ;, and then decreased to mÊ.ª. Staring July ϕ;, the BOT provided low interest rate to exporters. ae annual interest rate was E.ªì if the loan was paid back in US dollar, ÏÏ.ÊÊì if paid back in NT dollar. In contrast, black market interest rate was mm.Ïì in ϕÊ. Scott (ϕ;•, p. m;) thought that the most critical policy change during the late ϕªs was the removal of import allocation system. Import allocation system for cotton yarns had been removed in July ϕ;.m For cotton import, although spinner could now import cotton directly, the supply of foreign reserves were controlled by the BOT. ae alloca- tion was based on the criterion of capacity and production eõciency. Starting ϕ•, the allocation was based ûrst on export record, and then on capacity.mm

5.2 Comparative Advantage In Table Ï, the key component in processing charge was wage rate. ae policy change in the late ϕªs made low wage rate a comparative advantage for Taiwan. Scott (ϕ;•, pp. m;–Eª) compared manufacturing sector’s cost structure of Taiwan and the US around ϕ;ª. For textile industry, the share of wage cost was Ï.mì in the US, but only Ê.mì in Taiwan. He then listed hourly earnings for workers in textiles and electronics for Tai- wan and other countries, US was .; dollars, Japan Ï.ª dollar, and Taiwan ª.ª dollar. In other words, Taiwanese earnings was only ;.mì of the US, and ÏE.;ì of Japan. Figure • compared monthly wage in manufacturing of Japan and Taiwan. In ϕEª– ʪ, Taiwan’s monthly wage was .Êì of Japan. Apparently, wage ratio between two countries was aòected by the exchange rate. In ϕ, Taiwan’s monthly wage was •.E US dollars, it decreased to ÏÊ.• US dollars due to devaluation in the late ϕªs. To sum up, in the early postwar period Taiwan’s low wage rate was potentially its comparative advantage. However, the potential was far from a reality in the beginning. It was only aer the policy change in the late ϕªs, the potential was realized. ae labor- intensive industry was the most fast-growing export industry aer early ϕEªs. ais

mÏHowever, the zones were for “technology-intensive” ûrms only, and no cotton textiles or cotton gar- ments ûrms were allowed into the zones. See Scott (ϕ;•), pp. mm•. mHsu (ªªm), pp. ÏE–m。 mmHsu (ªªm), p. Ê;.

ϕ US$ 5000

1000 Japan

100 Taiwan

10

1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Figure •: Male wage rate in manufacturing For Taiwan, export exchange rate for private sector was used in conversion. Source: Taiwan, Mizoguchi (ªªÊ), p. ÊÊ. ae original data was daily wage rate, monthly wage was assumed to be  times of daily wage rate.Japan, http: //www.stat.go.jp/english/data/chouki/19.htm, ϕ-m;-a. reected the fact that Taiwan’s comparative advantage was low wage rate.m It should be pointed out that although Taiwan’s wage rate was low, Taiwanese workers were relatively well-educated. ais was helpful when Taiwan began to moved into technology-intensive industries.m

5.3 Export Expansion and Capital Formation Figure Ϫ compares the export ratio of Taiwan, Japan, and the world average. During ϕÏ–Eª, Taiwan’s export ratio was •.ì, probably lower than the world average if data were available.It started to rise in the early ϕEªs, and the average rose to ª.Eì in ϕEÏ–;ª. In ϕʪ, Taiwan’s export ratio was Ï.mì, while the world average was ϕ.ì. Comparing Figure Ϫ and Figure Ï above, export ratio went up with the GDP growth beginning in the early ϕEªs, leading to the widely-held view that it was a export-led growth. Following the successful expansion of exports, private ûxed formation increased. Figure ÏÏ shows ûxed investment to GDP ratio from ϕÏ to ϕʪ. In the ϕªs, the ratio was about Eì, it started to increase in the early ϕEªs, and reached Ïì in ϕ;. Two other factors should have been helpful. One was the Statute for Encouraging Investment passed by the in ϕEª. ae other was that , a small island near Fujien province, was attacked and blockaded by the Communist China on August m, ϕÊ. But the KMT government with the help of the US successfully fought back, and

mLin (ϕ;m), p. Ïmª;Ranis (ϕ;•), pp. mE–m;. mScott (ϕ;•), p. mEÏ.

ª %

60 Taiwan

40

World average 20

Japan

1951 1956 1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 2006 2011 Figure Ϫ:Export to GDP ratio

Source: DGBAS and World Bank.

% 15

10

5

1951 1955 1959 1963 1967 1971 1975 1979 Figure ÏÏ: Private Fixed Investment to GDP Ratio

Source: DGBAS. the Communist China removed the blockade in the beginning of October. ae end of blockade enhanced the long-term stability prospect of Taiwan and the motive for investment. Notwithstanding, if the products of textile industry could be sold only in the domestic market, the incentive to invest could not be high. When the government adopted tax refund and devaluation policy, it also raised im- port tax and commodity tax for textiles including cotton, cotton yarn, and cotton cloth. ais reected the idea of K. Y. Yin, who said in ϕ that “Taiwan’s textile industry can not compete with Japan. Without protections, the industry would be ravaged.”mE Little (ϕ;•, p. ;) pointed out that “the eòect of the new policies was not to create laissez- faire conditions for the whole of the industry .... aey created a kind of dual economy in which only exports ... could be manufactured under virtually free trade conditions.” According to Hsing (ϕ•m), the dual system was continued until at least the early ϕʪs.

mEYin (ϕm).

Ï 6 Japanese Colonization and the US Aid

Little (ϕ;•, p. ;) pointed out that the dual economy policy was soon copied by South Korea and other developing countries. South Korea was a successful case of develop- ment, but most of the others were not. Did these countries forget to do something? Or there were other necessary conditions for growth missing in these countries?

6.1 Institutions Acemoglu and Robinson (ªªÊ, p. ) study the high growths of postwar Taiwan, Sin- gapore, South Korea, and China since ϕʪs, and argue that institution was the key for growth. ae role of institutions in economic growth had been emphasized by early growth economists. For example, North (ϕ•ª, p. E;) pointed that “[w]ith insecure property rights, poorly enforced laws, barriers to entry, and monopolistic restrictions, the proût-maximization ûrms will tend to have ... little capital.” Aer Taiwan was ceded to Japan in Ïʕ, the colonial government endeavored to establish new institutions and to construct modern infrastructure. One of the most important results was the creation of a modern land property rights system. In ÏʕÊ, an island-wide land census was started, and a sequence of tasks was implemented including identiûcation of land property rights, land measurement, buy-out of the ta-tsu land rights, and ûnally adjusting land tax rates. Aer the land census was completed in ϕª, the colonial government started a land registration system which established a modern land property rights system in Taiwan.m; Yanaihara (ϕ•) argued that aer the land census was completed, the land property rights were well-deûned, and land transactions were much secured. In contrast to the late Ch’ing dynasty when land rights were only loosely deûned, and enforcement was weak, land litigation cases aer the reform should be much lower, and there would be much more land transactions. Figure Ï shows the percentage of land litigation and me- diation cases. Besides the cases related to land, other categories include money, human relationship, food and so on. From Ïʕ• to ϕª, while the total of the cases had a long- term growing trend, with ,ªE cases in ϕªª, and Ê,ÏÏE cases in ϕª, the percentage of cases related to land showed a clear downward trend aer ϕª. An established institution could be abolished later. For example, aer World War II, North Korea abolished private property rights. ae Communist China also abolished private property rights aer ϕ•.mÊ ae abolishment of private property rights pro- duced adverse eòects for both countries. Fortunately, Taiwan private property rights

m;Wu (ªÏ). mÊBut private property was a legal right again in ªª;.

 % 40

35

30 mediation (ûnal) 25

20

15

10 litigation (ûrst instance and ûnal) 5

1899 1902 1905 1908 1911 1914 1917 1920 1923 1926 1929 1932 1935 1938 1941 Figure Ï: Percentage of land litigation and mediation

ais diagram shows the percentage of land litigation and mediation cases to the total cases. Source: Wu (ªÏ), ûgure ;. remained intact aer the KMT government retreated to Taiwan. In contrast, land right institution in the Philippines was still rather backward today.m• Is this the reason that the Philippines did not grow as fast as Taiwan during the postwar period? ais is a question worthy of further exploration in the future.

6.2 US Aid to Taiwan From ϕE to ϕE;, Taiwan received US economic aid of Ï,;EÊ.m million US dollars, and military aid of ,mÊ. million dollars.ª For comparison, Taiwan’s GDP was mªÊ. mil- lion US dollars in ϕÏ. What was the role of the US aid in the postwar high growth of Taiwan?Scott (ϕ;•, pp. mE•–;Ê) reviewed the literature, and concluded that US aid was not the only, or even the main, important factor. It is impossible to clearly deûne what is meant by “important factor”, but as we have discussed in section  above, during the ûrst half of the ϕªs, in anticipations that the Communist China was going to attack, Taiwan was in a precarious situation. It was only aer the US aid was announced on June ;, ϕª, the political situation became stabilized. Without the US aid, Taiwan had to defend herself on her own. Even if she could survive the attack, defense spending would crowd out economic expenditures, and tax rate would be much higher. For the central government, defense spending was ʕ.ì of total expenditures in ϕª, and the ratio of budget deûcit to total spending was as high as .ì. During the later period of hyperination (ϕÊ–•) budget deûcit was the main cause of money supply increase. Without the US aid, budget deûcit would be diõcult to reduce, and ination would be a persistent problem diõcult to get rid of.

m•Vargas (ªªm), p. •. ªHo (ϕ;Ê), p. ÏϪ.

m Aer price became relatively stable in the early ϕªs, the US aid funds were directed to economic development, and the main focus was on capital formation. Capital assis- tance, funds going into ûxed assets, formed about four-ûhs of all project aid.Ï Alter- natively, the allocation of aid funds could be divided into four categories: infrastructure (m;.mì), agriculture (Ï.ì), human resources (.•ì), and industry (Ï.mì). Among the funds dedicated to infrastructure, about EÊ.ì was allocated to Taiwan Power Com- pany. Even with such a big input from the US aid, there were sometimes electricity shortage problems. ais showed clearly how the US aid had helped the industrial de- velopment. Finally, as shown in Figure  above, percentage of production from state enterprises was over ʪì in ϕE, but decreased to about ªì in ϕ;ª. ae export expansion in the beginning of the ϕEªs was brought out by private enterprises.Jacoby (ϕEE, p. ÏmÊ) was surprised that only Eì of all aid funds went to private enterprises. But he also argued that “US aid helped to create a booming private sector of Taiwan’s economy indirectly.”m

7 Concluding Remarks

Regarding Taiwan’s economic development in the ϕªs and ϕEªs, many researchers thought that the import substitution policy in the beginning laid the foundation for the export expansion later. For example, Lin (ϕ;m, pp. ÏE–E) argued that without the protection policies installed during the import substitution period, export expansion during the late ϕªs could not be developed. One argument for protection was that it took time to learn new technology. ais argument did not apply to Taiwan’s textile industry, however. Most of the spinning mills and fabric mills were moved to Taiwan from the mainland China in ϕ•, and the owners of the mills were familiar with the textile technology before coming to Taiwan. Also as discussed in section , the control policies imposed in the early and the middle of the ϕªs were intended to control the price of cotton yarns. aey did not help the development of textile technology, and was of no use to promote export either. In his speech in May ϕ, Yin (ϕ, p. ) said that the purpose of textile devel- opment was to conserve foreign exchange. However, there was no mention of export expansion at all. When the government pursued the important substitution in the early ϕªs, export expansion was not even considered as a policy option. It was only when textile market had reached saturation, the government started to explore the possibility

ÏJacoby (ϕEE), p. Ï. Jacoby (ϕEE), pp. ª, Ï;E–;Ê. mJacoby (ϕEE), pp. Ïm–m.

 of export. As we have shown above, the important policies for export expansion were tax refund, de-valuation, low interest loans, and removal of import restrictions.If these policies were implemented earlier, there was no reason why Taiwan’s high growth would not be started earlier.

References Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (ªªÊ), “ae Role of Institutions in Growth and Development,” Working Paper,Commision on Growth and Development. Chen, Rong-Fu (ϕm), Historical Statistics of Finance in Taiwan (台灣之金融史料), Tai- wan: Bank of Taiwan. (ϕE), Finance and Foreign Trade of Taiwan, Ïʕ–ϕ (六十年來台灣之金融與 貿易), Taipei: Sanseido. Cumings,Bruce (ϕ•ª), ae Origins of Korean War, vol. , New Jersey: Princeton Uni- versity Press. Ho, Samuel P.S. (ϕ;Ê), Economic Development of Taiwan, ÏÊEª-ϕ;ª, New Haven: Yale University Press. Hsiao,Fong-Hsiung (ϕ•), ae Industrial Policy and Development in Taiwan (我國產 業政策與產業發展), Taipei: Far Eastern Economic Reserch. Hsing, Mo-Huan (ϕ;Ï), “Taiwan,” in John H. Power, Gerardo P. Sicat, and Mo-Huan Hsing (eds.), ae Philippines and Taiwan, London: Oxford University Press, Ïm– mª•. (ϕ•m), “On Taiwan’s Long-term Industrial Development (再論臺灣工業長期發 展政策),” in Mo-Huan Hsing (ed.), On Taiwan’s Economic Policy, Taipei: San-Min, ;•–•Ï. Hsu, Hui-Shang (ªªm), “Cotton Textile Industrial Policy, ϕ•–ϕÊ (進口替代時期台灣 的棉紡織政策, ϕ•–ϕÊ),” MA thesis, Department of History, National ChengChi University. Hu, Hsiang-Ling (ϕ), “ae Evoluation of Taiwan’s Foreign Exchange Management (臺灣管理外匯辦法之演變),” Bank of Taiwan Quarterly, E, Ï–. Huang,Dong-Zi (ϕE), “Cotton Industry in Taiwan (臺灣之棉紡工業),” Bank of Taiwan Quarterly, ;, Ï–mm. Jacoby, Neil (ϕEE), U.S. Aid to Taiwan, New York:Fredric A.Prager Publishers. Jarman, Robert L. (ed.) (ϕ•;), Taiwan: Political and Economic Reports: ÏÊEÏ–Ï•Eª, Ϫ vols., Slough, U.K.:Archive Editions Limited. Li, Yue-Sheung (ªª), “A Study on Taiwan’s Cotton Textile Industry, ϕ•–ϕm (臺 灣棉紡織業政策之研究, ϕ•–ϕm),” MA thesis, Department of History, National Chengchi University. Lin, Bang-Chong (ϕE•), “Taiwan’s Cotton Yarn Industry (臺灣之棉紡工業),” Bank of Taiwan Quarterly, ª, ;E–Ï.

 Lin,Ching-yuan (ϕ;m), Industrialization in Taiwan, ϕE–;, New York: Praeger. Little, Ian M. D. (ϕ;•), “An Economic Reconnaissance,” in Walter Galenson (ed.), Eco- nomic Growth and Structural Change in Taiwan, Ithaca: Cornell University Press, Ê–ª;. Liu, Wen-Terng (ϕ), “A Report on Economic Mission to South Korea (赴韓經濟訪問 團紡織部份報告書),” Textile Industry, no. ª, –•. Lu, Ler-San (ϕm), “ae Cost of Cotton Yarn Export (紗布外銷的成本問題),” Textile Industry, no. Ê, ÏÏ–Ï. (ϕ), “ae Cost and Loss of Cotton Yarn Export (棉紗的外銷成本及虧損的問 題),” Textile Industry, no. Ï, E–Ê. Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki (ªªÊ), Asian Long-term Economic Statistics I: Taiwan (アジア長 期經濟統計 I: 臺灣), Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shinposha. North,Douglass C. (ϕ•ª), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, New York: Cambridge University Press. Ranis, Gustav (ϕ;•), “Industrial Development,” in Walter Galenson (ed.), Economic Growth and Structural Change in Taiwan, Ithaca: Cornell University Press, ªE–E. Scott, Maurice (ϕ;•), “Foreign Trade,” in Walter Galenson (ed.), Economic Growth and Structural Change in Taiwan, Ithaca: Cornell University Press, mªÊ–mÊm. Shih, Kuan-Sen, Jen-Hsing Chou, and Jen Su (ϕEÏ), “A Study on Taiwan’s Trade and Foreign Exchange (臺灣貿易外匯之研究),” Bank of Taiwan Quarterly, ª,Êm–Ï. Taiwan Provincial Government (ϕ;Ï), Statistical Abstract of Taiwan Province, Republic of China, ϕE–ϕE;, Nantou:Bureau of Accounting and Statistics, Taiwan Provincial Government. Vargas,Alberto (ªªm), “ae Philippines Country Brief: Property Rights and Land Mar- kets,” Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin—Madison. Wu, Tsong-Min (ϕ•), “Taiwan’s Post-World War II Hyperination,” in Kuo-Su Liang (ed.), Taiwan Economic Development, Taipei:China Times. (ϕ•;), “ae ’s Economic Policies Regarding Taiwan: ϕ–ϕ•,” Taiwan Economic Review, , Ï–. (ªª), “Taiwan’s Per Capita GDP in Long-term Development,” Taiwan Eco- nomic Review, m, •m–mª. (ªÏ), “A Study on Taiwan’s Land Rights Reform During the Early Japanese Colonial Period,” working paper, National Taiwan University. Wu, Tsong-Min and Yin-Feng Kuo (ϕ•Ï), “An Empirical Study on Taiwan’s Ination and Money Growth: ϕª;–ϕÊE,” Taiwan Economic Review, ϕ, m–;Ï. Yanaihara, Tadao (ϕ•), Taiwan Under Imperialism (帝國主義下の台灣), Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten. Yin, K. Y. (ϕ), “A Review on the Textile Industry Development (發展本省紡織工業 問題的檢討),” Textile Industry (紡織界), no. , May E, ϕ, –.

E Yin, K. Y. (ϕm), “Controls of Taiwan’s Textiles for the Past Year (一年來台灣花紗布的 管制工作),” Textile Industry (紡織界), joing issue of mm/m, January ϕm,Ê.

;