Michael Löwy Bio-Bibliographical Sketch

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Michael Löwy Bio-Bibliographical Sketch Lubitz' TrotskyanaNet Michael Löwy Bio-Bibliographical Sketch Contents: Basic biographical data Biographical sketch Selective bibliography Basic biographical data Name: Michael Löwy Other names (by-names, pseud. etc.): Michael Lowy * Michel Löwy * Carlos Rossi Date and place of birth: May 6, 1938, São Paulo (Brazil) Nationality: Brazil ; French Occupations, careers, etc.: Professor (em.) of Sociology, scholar, writer, editor Time of activity in Trotskyist movement: 1968 - Biographical sketch -preliminary draft only- Prof. (em.) Dr. Michael Löwy1 is a distinguished and eminent French-Brazilian social scientist, Marx- ist philosopher and literary scholar. He was born in São Paulo (Brazil) on May 6, 1938 as a son of Kurt Löwy, a chemical engineer, and his wife Hedwig (b. Löwinger), a teacher. Both parents were German-speaking Jews from Vienna (Aus- tria) who had come to Brazil as immigrants in 1934. Michael Löwy has an elder brother, Peter, born in 1933. He was married first with Ilana Zelmanowicz from whom he got a daughter (b. 1975) and a son (b. 1977). In 1980, the couple parted in mutual agreement, and Michael Löwy married Eleni Varikas [Elenē Barika] (b. 1949), a historian from Greek origin who lectures at Université de Paris VIII. Löwy grew up in Brazil. After having finished his school education, he attended the Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Ciências Humanas at the Universidade de São Paulo, where Fernando Enrique Cardoso was one of his teachers and where in 1960 he earned a MA degree in social sciences. In 1961, Löwy, who already was fluent in several languages, was awarded a scholarship for France and went to Paris where he later permanently settled, becoming a French citizen. He studied sociology under the renowned Professor Lucien Goldmann (1913-1970) who enjoyed an international reputation as an outstanding Marxist philosopher. Goldmann's impact on Löwy was quite considerable 2. Gold- mann also supervised Löwy's thesis Révolution communiste et autoémancipation du prolétariat dans l'œuvre du jeune Marx by which in 1964 he earned the First Doctorate degree ("3ème cycle") from 1) His name is sometimes incorrectly spelled "Michel Lowy", "Michael Lowy" or "Michel Löwy". In Trotskyist publications, Löwy sometimes used the pen name "Carlos Rossi". He should not be confused with another “Michael Loewy”, associate professor of Eco - nomics at the University of South Florida (Tampe, Fla.) 2) "At the same time [in 1960/61] I discovered the writings of the French/Jewish/Romanian Marxist sociologist Lucien Goldmann which opened a new and broader intellectual horizon before my eyes. Fascinated by his brand of humanist Marxism (inspired by Georg Lukács), I decided to apply for a scholarship to study in Paris and to work on a PhD. with Goldmann." (Löwy, Michael: Transforming the world : an interview with Michael Löwy [by Terry Murphy], in: Against the Current, n.s. 9.1994 (4=52), p. 26. © by Wolfgang & Petra Lubitz 2004 — page 1 Lubitz' TrotskyanaNet Michael Löwy Bio-Bibliographical Sketch École Pratique des Hautes Études. Several years later, this work was published with title La théorie de la révolution chez le jeune Marx (Paris, Maspero, 1970) and was translated into several languages. Subsequently, Löwy spent some years in Israel earning his living by university jobs in Haifa and Jeru- salem and learnt Hebrew, before he became a lecturer at the university of Tel-Aviv. He left Tel-Aviv in 1968 and during the winter term 1968/69 functioned as assistant to Professor Peter Worsley (1924- 2013) and as lecturer in sociology at the University of Manchester (Britain). Löwy returned to Paris in 1969 to become assistant to Professor Nikos Poulantzas (1936-1979) at the Université de Paris VIII (Vincennes). At the same time, Löwy began to work on his habilitation thesis about György Lukács (1885-1971)and in 1976 eventually earned a PhD degree ("doctorat d'État") from the Université de Paris V; his thesis, supervised by Professor Louis-Vincent Thomas (1922- 1994), was titled L'évolution politique de Lukács 1909-1929 : contribution à une sociologie de l'intelligentsia révolutionnaire; in 1976 it was published by Presses Universitaires de France with title Pour une sociologie des intellectuels révolutionnaires : l'évolution politique de Lukács, 1909-1929. Löwy became Professor of Sociology and from 1978 until his retirement functioned as Research Director in Sociology at the Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique (CNRS), Paris. Furthermore, since 1981 he was a regular guest lecturer at the École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales (EHESS), Paris, and he has been a member of the Centre d’ Études Interdisciplinaires des Faits Reli- gieux, Paris. He has been holding seminars and guest lectures at a considerable number of universities in France, Germany, the United States, Brazil, Cuba and elsewhere, and frequently participated in in- numerable scholarly symposia and presented his research results in scientific conferences held in France, the United States, Germany, Italy, Mexico, Brazil, Israel and so on. In 1984, he was awarded the Silver Medal of the CNRS as best social scientist. During the last 20 years, a special focus of his research interest was on the sociology of religion. His magnum opus in this field was his book Redemption and utopia (originally published in French and translated into several languages) in which he investigated into the genesis of religious and non-reli- gious eschatologies and of utopias and their differences in view of their liberation perspectives. Other main fields of Löwy's scholarly research work have been the sociology of knowledge, the theology of liberation, messianism and utopian thought, romanticism, Jewish-German culture, Marx and Marxism, Marxism and the national question, nationalism and internationalism, Trotsky’s theory of permanent revolution and the Third World, Latin American Trotskyism, utopian and idealist dimensions in Marx- ist and libertarian thought. He has been publishing a very considerable number of books (some to- gether with Robert Sayre, sociologist at Université de Paris VI), about the just mentioned subjects. Many of his books and articles have been translated into various (altogether more than 25) languages and thus have found international reception and audience. The number of his contributions to journals, collections, conference proceedings, encyclopaedias and other collective works is impressive and by far exceeds the number of his books. It is so to speak almost impossible to find out a bibliography about great thinkers, writers, social philosophers and critical Marxists of the 20th century without com- ing across Löwy's name, since he has been intensively dealing with and writing about such outstanding men and women of achievement as for example Max Weber, Hannah Arendt, Franz Kafka, György Lukács, Lucien Goldmann, Christa Wolf, José Carlos Mariátegui, Gustavo Gutiérrez, Gershom Scho - lem, Ernst Bloch, Rosa Luxemburg, Antonio Gramsci, Ernesto Che Guevara, Leon Trotsky, Ernest Mandel, and last not least Walter Benjamin. Löwy also functioned as supervisor/director of a number of dissertations, amongst them the thesis of Enzo Traverso who later published several renowned works about Marxism and the Jewish question and about the Holocaust. Regarding himself a socialist since 1954, Löwy in the early Sixties became a member of the Parti Socialiste Unifié (PSU) before in 1968 associating with the Fourth International (USFI) and becoming a member of its French section, the Ligue Communiste (LC, later renamed Ligue Communiste Révolu- tionnaire, LCR), actively participating in its discourse and contributing a considerable number of articles to its journals and bulletins as well as to many serial publications of the Fourth International and its various national sections. After the dissolution of the LCR, Löwy in 2009 became a member of © by Wolfgang & Petra Lubitz 2004 — page 2 Lubitz' TrotskyanaNet Michael Löwy Bio-Bibliographical Sketch the Nouveau Parti Anticapitaliste (NPA). Furthermore, Löwy has always been engaged in various solidarity and liberation movements in France and on an international scale; thus he has been giving his support and endorsement to the Brazilian Partido dos Trabalhadores (PT) and to various anti- globalist and anti-neoliberalist activities and networks such as ATTAC (Association pour la Taxation des Transactions Financières pour l'Aide aux Citoyens) and the World Social Forum. He can also be regarded as a convinced spokesman of the eco-socialist tendency within the spectrum of the far left; he was co-author of the International Eco-Socialist Manifesto and co-organizer of the First International Ecosocialist Meeting (Paris, 2007). For more biographical information about Löwy see for example the items listed in the last paragraph of our bio-bibliographical sketch, for instance the excellent sketch by Frédéric Thomas and the collec- tion "Cartographie de l'utopie" (Paris, 2011). You may also visit Michael Löwy's blog in the WWW ("Le blog de Michael Lowy") as well as the Wikipedia articles (in various languages) dealing with Löwy. “There is no automatic socialist future, no guaranteed progress and no ‘final crisis of capital- ism’ leading by itself to the proletarian utopia: the choice between socialism and barbarism is still open, and its outcome depends on each one of us” 3 Selective preliminary bibliography Some introductory remarks It goes without question that Michael Löwy is among the most productive contemporary Marxist/Trotskyist scholars and writers. We should like to emphasize that we do not at all claim 'completeness' with regard to our following Selective Bibliography. Although listing a veritable amount of literature, it must be said that un- doubtedly a considerable number of sources have not been considered here, for example many of the translations of Löwy's works, particularly translations into non-Western European languages. Other items may simply have escaped our attention, at least until now. Non-print media including all kinds of electronic resources have been omitted, too. Nevertheless it seems that there is no Löwy bibliography which could claim for more compre- hensiveness and density than ours.
Recommended publications
  • Lucas on the Relationship Between Theory and Ideology
    Discussion Paper No. 2010-28 | November 17, 2010 | http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2010-28 Lucas on the Relationship between Theory and Ideology Michel De Vroey IRES, University of Louvain Please cite the corresponding journal article: http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2011-4 Abstract This paper concerns a neglected aspect of Lucas’s work: his methodological writings, published and unpublished. Particular attention is paid to his views on the relationship between theory and ideology. I start by setting out Lucas’s non-standard conception of theory: to him, a theory and a model are the same thing. I also explore the different facets and implications of this conception. In the next two sections, I debate whether Lucas adheres to two methodological principles that I dub the ‘non-interference’ precept (the proposition that ideological viewpoints should not influence theory), and the ‘non-exploitation’ precept (that the models’ conclusions should not be transposed into policy recommendations, in so far as these conclusions are built into the models’ premises). The last part of the paper contains my assessment of Lucas’s ideas. First, I bring out the extent to which Lucas departs from the view held by most specialized methodologists. Second, I wonder whether the new classical revolution resulted from a political agenda. Third and finally, I claim that the tensions characterizing Lucas’s conception of theory follow from his having one foot in the neo- Walrasian and the other in the Marshallian–Friedmanian universe. JEL B22, B31, B41, E30 Keywords Lucas; new classical macroeconomics; methodology Correspondence Michel De Vroey, IRES, University of Louvain, Place Montesquieu 3, B- 3458 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium: e-mail: [email protected] A first version of this paper was presented at seminars given at the University of Toronto and the University of British Columbia.
    [Show full text]
  • Thesis W/ Corrections
    Renouncing the Le-: Working-class conserva7sm in France, 1930-1939 Joseph Starkey A Thesis submi+ed for the Degree of PhD at Cardiff University 2014 Abstract Histories of the working class in France have largely ignored the existence of working-class conservaGsm. This is parGcularly true of histories of the interwar period. Yet, there were an array of Catholic and right-wing groups during these years that endeavoured to bring workers within their orbit. Moreover, many workers judged that their interests were be+er served by these groups. This thesis explores the parGcipaGon of workers in Catholic and right-wing groups during the 1930s. What did these groups claim to offer workers within the wider context of their ideological goals? In which ways did conservaGve workers understand and express their interests, and why did they idenGfy the supposed ‘enemies of the leT’ as the best means of defending them? What was the daily experience of conservaGve workers like, and how did this experience contribute to the formaGon of ‘non-leT’ poliGcal idenGGes? These quesGons are addressed in a study of the largest Catholic and right-wing groups in France during the 1930s. This thesis argues that, during a period of leT-wing ascendancy, these groups made the recruitment of workers a top priority. To this end, they harnessed parGcular elements of mass poliGcal culture and adapted them to their own ideological ends. However, the ideology of these groups did not simply reflect the interests of the workers that supported them. This thesis argues that the interests of conservaGve workers were a raGonal and complex product of their own experience.
    [Show full text]
  • The Surreal Voice in Milan's Itinerant Poetics: Delio Tessa to Franco Loi
    City University of New York (CUNY) CUNY Academic Works Dissertations, Theses, and Capstone Projects CUNY Graduate Center 2-2021 The Surreal Voice in Milan's Itinerant Poetics: Delio Tessa to Franco Loi Jason Collins The Graduate Center, City University of New York How does access to this work benefit ou?y Let us know! More information about this work at: https://academicworks.cuny.edu/gc_etds/4143 Discover additional works at: https://academicworks.cuny.edu This work is made publicly available by the City University of New York (CUNY). Contact: [email protected] THE SURREALIST VOICE IN MILAN’S ITINERANT POETICS: DELIO TESSA TO FRANCO LOI by JASON M. COLLINS A dissertation submitted to the Graduate Faculty in Comparative Literature in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy, The City University of New York 2021 i © 2021 JASON M. COLLINS All Rights Reserved ii The Surreal Voice in Milan’s Itinerant Poetics: Delio Tessa to Franco Loi by Jason M. Collins This manuscript has been read and accepted for the Graduate Faculty in Comparative Literature in satisfaction of the dissertation requirement for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy _________________ ____________Paolo Fasoli___________ Date Chair of Examining Committee _________________ ____________Giancarlo Lombardi_____ Date Executive Officer Supervisory Committee Paolo Fasoli André Aciman Hermann Haller THE CITY UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK iii ABSTRACT The Surreal Voice in Milan’s Itinerant Poetics: Delio Tessa to Franco Loi by Jason M. Collins Advisor: Paolo Fasoli Over the course of Italy’s linguistic history, dialect literature has evolved a s a genre unto itself.
    [Show full text]
  • SIAC HOME Files/STALINISM TRADITION and the WORKING CLASS.Pdf
    Stalinism, Tradition, and the Working Class A response to comrades who honeymoon in the past DON MILLIGAN Mayday in London, 1928 2 The Dictatorship of the Proletariat There is one, only one, essential element in the Marxist critique of capitalism. It is very simple and very plain, but in it are focused all the many- faceted analyses of the capitalist order. It is this: there is a striking contradiction between the increasingly social character of the process of production and the anti-social character of capitalist property. [. ] This contradiction between the anti-social character of [private] property and the social character of our production is the source of all anarchy and irrationality in capitalism.1 Isaac Deutscher n the Marxist tradition ‘dictatorship’ means domination and, just to confuse matters, it also carries with it the Irather more conventional political meaning that refers to a state of lawless and arbitrary rule by a tyrant or an association of tyrants. In the former rather than the latter sense Marxists have always thought of capitalist society as ‘the dictatorship of the bourgeoisie’. After all, capitalist society is founded upon the defence of private property against all comers, and the state and legal system is organized to ensure that the most favourable social and political conditions for the businessman and the entrepreneur prevail. The state guarantees the right of the owners of private capital to employ workers to generate profits in order to finance a new round of private investment, and so on. Irrespective of whether or not the state or political form of capitalist rule is oligarchic, dictatorial, or democratic, Marxists in the past, and today, regard the bourgeois domination of society as ‘dictatorial’.
    [Show full text]
  • And Bernardo Bertolucci's 1900
    The “Betrayed Resistance” in Valentino Orsini’s Corbari (1970) and Bernardo Bertolucci’s 1900 (1976) Dominic Gavin The connections between Italian film and history have been the object of renewed attention in recent years. A number of studies have provided re-readings of Italian cinema, especially from the perspective of public memory. Charting the interrelations of cinema, the public use of history, and historiography, these studies include reevaluations of the cinema of the Resistance, the war film, the Holocaust and the Fascist dictatorship.1 The ongoing debates over Resistance memory in particular—the “never-ending liberation,” in the words of one historian—have provided a motive for reconsidering popular cultural productions as vehicles of collective perceptions of the past.2 If Italian film studies came relatively late to the issues of cinema and public memory, this approach has now become mainstream.3 In this essay, I am concerned with films on the Resistance during the 1970s. These belong to a wider grouping of contemporary cinematic productions that deal with the Fascist dictatorship and antifascism. These films raise a series of critical questions. How did the general film field contribute to the wider processing of historical memory, and how did it relate to political violence in Italy?4 To what extent did the work of Italian filmmakers participate in the “new discourse” of international cinema in the 1970s concerning the treatment of Nazism and the occupation,5 or to what extent were filmmakers engaged in reaffirming populist
    [Show full text]
  • The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: a Critique of Received Explanations
    The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: A Critique of Received Explanations Joseph T. Salerno or roughly the first three quarters of the nineteenth century, the "liberal school" thoroughly dominated economic thinking and teaching in F France.1 Adherents of the school were also to be found in the United States and Italy, and liberal doctrines exercised a profound influence on prominent German and British economists. Although its numbers and au- thority began to dwindle after the 1870s, the school remained active and influential in France well into the 1920s. Even after World War II, there were a few noteworthy French economists who could be considered intellectual descendants of the liberal tradition. Despite its great longevity and wide-ranging influence, the scientific con- tributions of the liberal school and their impact on the development of Eu- ropean and U.S. economic thought—particularly on those economists who are today recognized as the forerunners, founders, and early exponents of marginalist economics—have been belittled or simply ignored by most twen- tieth-century Anglo-American economists and historians of thought. A number of doctrinal scholars, including Joseph Schumpeter, have noted and attempted to explain the curious neglect of the school in the En- glish-language literature. In citing the school's "analytical sterility" or "indif- ference to pure theory" as a main cause of its neglect, however, their expla- nations have overlooked a salient fact: that many prominent contributors to economic analysis throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries expressed strong appreciation of or weighty intellectual debts to the purely theoretical contributions of the liberal school.
    [Show full text]
  • 14707176.Pdf
    I c/66-14 AN ESSAY ON REVISIONISM IN THE ITALIAN COMMUNIST PARTY Giorgio Galli Massachusetts Institute of Technology Center for International Studies International Communism Project The following essay explores the evolution of Italian Communist re- visionism. In general when we speak of "revisionism" in the Italian Communist Party (PCI) we usually refer to the question of whether the conquest of power is possible and of what strategy the Party puts forward in order to achieve it: the classical questions, in short, which were at the center of the first great revisionist debate in the Second International. Extensive comparisons have therefore been made between Italian "revisionism" and its classical antecedents. But first a brief review of the PCI's attitude toward the Italian Con- stitution may be illuminating. At a particularly signi icant moment in its recent history, the Eighth Congress of December 1956, the PCI approved the "Elements for a Policy Declaration" which regards the Italian Constitution that went into effect in January 1948, as an "important victory on the Italian road to Socialism," and illustrates one fundamental aspect of it in the follow- ing manner: As far as private property is concerned, it is guaranteed by law, 'with the aim of safeguarding its social function and making it accessible to all,' and it is precisely for this reason that the Constitution lays down limits for it and even provides for expro- priation, with compensation, for 'reasons of general interest.' It is not, therefore, unreasonable to state that the Republican Constitution . sets up some of the conditions which may, when they are put into effect .
    [Show full text]
  • Firmin Oulès and the “New Lausanne School”
    Firmin Oulès and the "New Lausanne School" David Sarech (University of Lausanne, Ph.D. Student) In this paper I will present Firmin Oulès’ “harmonized economics” and interrogate the relationship between state and market in his thought. “Harmonized economics” were conceived as the continuation of Léon Walras’ theory. The key concept of the first Lausanne school is the notion of equilibrium. Indeed, Walras forged it in order to “scientifically” demonstrate the superiority of a competition-based economy. However, the mathematical approach he chose, as well as his disdain for the orthodox economy of his time, led him to be misunderstood and he did not receive the recognition he was expecting. Thus the concept of general equilibrium would be forgotten until the mid 1950’s when it would become the core of microeconomics. However, as recent studies in history of economic thought have shown, the concept of equilibrium in Walras’ thought has to be understood in a broader context than a purely economical one. Indeed, the main goal of Walras was to bring an answer to “the social question”. Contrary to Marx, he did not think of it as being a problem of profit distribution between labor and capital. Instead he thought the goal of the economist was to create an economic system were everyone would be able to exert its inner abilities and in which inequalities would be based solely on merit. The incentive created by private property and profit-seeking being the groundwork of a flourishing economy, the equilibrium had to be understood as a tool to establish this idealistic society.
    [Show full text]
  • Durham E-Theses
    Durham E-Theses English Folk under the Red Flag: The Impact of Alan Bush's `Workers' Music' on 20th Century Britain's Left-Wing Music Scene ROBINSON, ALICE,MERIEL How to cite: ROBINSON, ALICE,MERIEL (2021) English Folk under the Red Flag: The Impact of Alan Bush's `Workers' Music' on 20th Century Britain's Left-Wing Music Scene , Durham theses, Durham University. Available at Durham E-Theses Online: http://etheses.dur.ac.uk/13924/ Use policy The full-text may be used and/or reproduced, and given to third parties in any format or medium, without prior permission or charge, for personal research or study, educational, or not-for-prot purposes provided that: • a full bibliographic reference is made to the original source • a link is made to the metadata record in Durham E-Theses • the full-text is not changed in any way The full-text must not be sold in any format or medium without the formal permission of the copyright holders. Please consult the full Durham E-Theses policy for further details. Academic Support Oce, Durham University, University Oce, Old Elvet, Durham DH1 3HP e-mail: [email protected] Tel: +44 0191 334 6107 http://etheses.dur.ac.uk 2 English Folk under the Red Flag: The Impact of Alan Bush’s ‘Workers’ Music’ on 20 th Century Britain’s Left-Wing Music Scene Alice Robinson Abstract Workers’ music: songs to fight injustice, inequality and establish the rights of the working classes. This was a new, radical genre of music which communist composer, Alan Bush, envisioned in 1930s Britain.
    [Show full text]
  • Adam Smith and the Austrian School of Economics: the Problem of Diamonds and Water
    Stefan Poier 1st year Part-time Doctoral Studies Adam Smith and the Austrian School of Economics: The Problem of Diamonds and Water Keywords: Adam Smith, Austrian School of Economics, Value Paradox, Marginal Utility, Decision Making Introduction When end of 2017 Leonardo da Vinci's painting "Salvator Mundi" was auctioned off for over $450 million, it was nearly three times as expensive as the second most expensive painting, a Picasso, and it could have compensated for the state deficit of Lithuania. An absurdly high sum for a piece of wood and oil paint. How do you explain such a price? Neither the amount of time spent working on it, nor the benefits from this work alone could justify it. Why do we often pay high prices for goods with little use, but low prices for things that are sometimes partially vital? Generations of economists and philosophers have tried to resolve this apparent paradox. An explanation for this price is - quite simply - an individual’s willingness to pay this price. The prestige gain of owning one of only fifteen paintings of the probably most important artist and universal scholar of all time can already provide an enormous increase in status. It is the scarcity, the uniqueness of the artwork, which justified the high increase in utility or satisfaction. If there were any number of similar works, no one would pay more than the utility value for it. This – today rational – economic inference was not always granted. It is based on the recognition that the benefits of consumption of a good decreases with the amount consumed (and thus with the saturation of the consumer).
    [Show full text]
  • Schools of Economic Thought (Pdf)
    SCHOOLS OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT A BRIEF HISTORY OF ECONOMICS This isn't really essential to know, but may satisfy the curiosity of many. Mercantilism Economics is said to begin with Adam Smith in 1776. Prior to that, nobody thought of economics, or markets, as an object of study. It is not that they didn't pay attention to economic matters, it is simply that they didn't think of it in any systematic or coherent manner. It was all just off-the-cuff intuition and policy proposals by a myriad of merchants, government officials & journalists, principally in Britain. It is common to denote the period before 1776 as "Mercantilism". It wasn't a coherent school of thought, but a hodge-podge of varying ideas about improving tax revenues, the value & movements of gold and how nations competed for international commerce & colonies. Mostly protectionist, 'war-minded', and all haphazardly argued. (the principal features of the Mercantilist school are discussed in our "Gains from Trade" handout). There was some opposition to Mercantilist doctrines, notably among French and Scottish thinkers (e.g. Pierre de Boisguilbert, Francois Quesnay, Jacques Turgot and David Hume) Classical School The Enlightenment era (mid-1700s) in Europe brought a new spirit of scientific inquiry. Thinkers began looking to apply scientific principles not only to the physical world, but also to human society. In the same spirit that Sir Isaac Newton 'discovered' the "law of gravity" to explain the interaction of natural forces and decipher how the physical world operates, Enlightenment thinkers began trying to discover the "laws" of human interaction, to explain how human society operates.
    [Show full text]
  • Austrian Economic Thought: Its Evolution and Its Contribution to Consumer Behavior
    A Great Revolution in Economics –Vienna 1871 and after Austrian economic thought: its evolution and its contribution to consumer behavior Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen A great REVOLUTION In economics —VIENNA 1871 and after AUSTRIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT: ITS EVOLUTION AND ITS CONTRIBUTION TO CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen The letter type on the cover is of Arnold Böcklin (Basel 1827-1901 Fiesole). It is a typical example of the Art Nouveau (Jugendstil) style—the fashionable style of art in Vienna at the end of the 19th century (the time older Austrianism came in full swing). In a sense, Böcklin’s work represents the essence of Austrianism: “Never was he interested in the accidental; he wanted the everlasting”. Cereales Foundation, publisher Wageningen University P.O. Box 357, 6700 AJ Wageningen, The Netherlands E [email protected] Printed by Grafisch Service Centrum Van Gils B.V. Cover design by Hans Weggen (Art Director Cereales) © 2001 Lazaros Th. Houmanidis and Auke R. Leen ISBN 90-805724-3-8 In the memory of our beloved colleague JACOB JAN KRABBE PREFACE A Great Revolution in Economics—Vienna 1871 and after is about the revolution in economic thought that started in Vienna in the last quarter of the nineteenth century. After a time of trying to save the objective value theory the time was there for a new awakening of economic thought. In Vienna, for the first time by the 1871 publication of Menger’s Grundsätze, value become subjective, and the market a process with a sovereign consumer. This book is about this awakening that proved to be more than a plaisanterie viennoise.
    [Show full text]